Urban crime and residential decisions

Urban Crime and Residential Decisions: Evidence from Chicago Anthony Tokman Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

October 2017

The opinions expressed herein are those of the author and do not reflect . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the. Federal . . . . . Reserve . . . . . .System. . . . . . .. Tokman

Urban crime and residential decisions

1 / 23

. .

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Introduction

Introduction I

Urban crime in the U.S. played a large part in the “urban flight” of the second half of the 20th century.

I

Using detailed data on crime, commutes, and location characteristics, we can estimate the effect of crime on residential decisions within cities and metro areas.

I

For the city of Chicago, I find that a 10% increase in the violent crime rate in a particular location is associated with a 1.8% reduction in population.

I

City-wide, a 10% increase in violent crime can reduce population by between 0.7 and 2.6%, depending on geographic distribution. . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

2 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Introduction

Related literature

I

Urban economics and theory: Alonso (1966), Mills (1967), Muth (1969), McFadden (1974), Eaton and Kortum (2002), Lucas and Rossi-Hansberg (2002), Ahlfeldt, Redding, Sturm, and Wolf (2015)

I

Crime, amenity, and urban decline: Thaler (1978), Roback (1982), Cullen and Levitt (1999), Glaeser and Gyourko (2005), Baum-Snow (2007), Pope and Pope (2012)

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

3 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Model

Model overview

I

Locations in city are indexed i = 1, . . . , N; each location has both residential and workplace characteristics, which can be endogenous or exogenous.

I

Each commuter o chooses a residence location i and workplace location j as well as consumption of housing and a final good.

I

We then derive a gravity equation that gives the commuting flow from i to j.

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

4 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Model Commuter’s problem

Commuter’s problem I

Commuter o’s utility (if he chooses to live in i and work in j) is uijo = I I I

I I I

Bi Ej β 1−β zijo . q h dij ijo ijo

(1)

Bi is the residential amenity of i (exogenous) Ej is the workplace amenity of j (exogenous) dij = e κtij is the cost of commuting between i and j (exogenous) qijo is consumption of the final good hijo is consumption of housing zijo is a stochastic term that follows a Fréchet distribution with shape parameter θ . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

5 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Model Commuter’s problem

Commuter’s problem I

Indirect utility of living in i and working in j is (to a constant) uijo =

Bi Ej wj zijo dij ri1−β

,

where ri is price of housing at i and wj is wage paid at j. I

It can be shown (following Eaton and Kortum, 2002) that the probability πij that a resident lives in i and works in j is given by ( )θ Bi Ej wj πij ∝ . (2) dij ri1−β . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

6 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Model Housing equilibrium

Housing equilibrium I

If location i has housing stock Hi , the market clearing condition is (1 − β)wiR ri = LRi . Hi

(3)

where LRi is number of commuters living in i and wiR is average wage of commuters living in i. I

In the long run, housing stock can grow (or contract), but for now I focus on the short-run case with fixed Hi . Model with housing growth

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

7 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Model Comparative statics

Comparative statics I

How do changes in amenity affect residential population?

I

From the gravity equation it can be shown that the change π ˆRi ∗ in the residential population of location i ∗ is given by π ˆRi ∗ = ∑ i

(Bˆi ∗ rˆiβ−1 )θ ∗ , πRi (Bˆi rˆβ−1 )θ i

where the hat denotes fractional change (ˆ x ≡ x1 /x0 ). I

In the fixed-housing stock case, rˆi = π ˆRi , so the above becomes Bˆ ζ∗ π ˆRi ∗ = ∑ i ζ , πRi Bˆ i

where ζ = θ/(1 + θ(1 − β)). Tokman

(4)

i

. . .

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

8 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Estimation and data Gravity estimation

Gravity estimation

I

The empirical gravity equation (substituting dij = e κtij ) can be written as ln πij = ϕ + ρi + µj − θκtij + ϵij , (5) where ϕ is the normalization constant, ρi = θ ln(Bi /ri1−β ) is the residential FE, µj = θ ln(Ej wj ) is the workplace FE, tij is the commuting time, and ϵij is an error term.

I

Once ri and parameters are known, we can back out Bi and regress on crime rates and controls.

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

9 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Estimation and data Data

Gravity data I

I apply the gravity model to the Chicago metro, which I define to include seven counties: Cook, Lake, Kane, Will, McHenry, DuPage in Illinois and Lake in Indiana. I

This is smaller than the official MSA designation, but still captures over 97% of commutes into Cook County.

I

I use the census tract as the unit of location.

I

All data are from the period 2011-2015.

I

Commuting flows Lij are from the U.S. Census Bureau’s Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics (LEHD) Origin-Destination Employment Statistics (LODES) database.

I

I use OpenStreetMap to calculate car travel times tij between centroids of all pairs of census tracts. . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

10 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Estimation and data Data

Housing and tract data I I

Housing costs ri are room- and age-adjusted tract-level median housing values, as reported in the 2011-2015 ACS. Residential amenity data come from both the ACS and the City of Chicago. I

Amenity controls are: ease of access to public transit (“L”, Metra, and bus), test scores of local public high schools∗ , fraction of the population with a bachelor’s degree∗ , share of park land, density of grocery stores∗ , distance to the Loop (to capture effects beyond commuting), and distance to Lake Michigan.

∗ These controls may be endogenous to crime and are excluded in some of . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. the regressions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. Tokman

Urban crime and residential decisions

11 / 23

. .

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Estimation and data Data

Crime data and rates I

Data on all reported crimes are provided by the City of Chicago.

I

I focus on non-domestic violent and property crimes committed during the 2011-15 period of interest.

I

Naively, the crime rate is given by the number of incidents divided by the population; however, this neglects to account for differences in daytime and nighttime populations.

I

A more nuanced formula is crime rate =

# daytime crimes # nighttime crimes + , daytime pop. nighttime pop.

where the daytime population can be found by adjusting the residential (“nighttime”) population by commuting flows. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . .

Tokman

.

. . . .

. . . .

Urban crime and residential decisions

. . . .

. . ..

12 / 23

. .

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Estimation and data Data

Crime rates

Violent Homicide Assault & battery Robbery Sexual assault Street Non-street Property

Total 110,321 2,124 44,170 57,844 6,093 75,941 34,290 495,151

Mean 1043 19 409 565 52 718 326 4546

25th 346 0 122 182 20 221 122 2386

50th 659 7 257 349 37 455 201 3579

75th 1475 25 551 769 72 991 448 5627

Mean and quantiles are weighted by population, using simple crime rates. Totals are over 5-year period. . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

13 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Estimation and data Data

Crime rates

From left to right: total violent crime rates, homicide rates, assault & battery rates, and property crime rates. . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

14 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Estimation and data Data

Parameters

I

I set the housing expenditure share (1 − β) to 0.31, consistent with the median expenditure on rent in the Chicago metro area in the 2011-15 ACS.

I

I set the commuting cost parameter (κ) to 0.015, which is the value Ahlfeldt et al. (2015) found for Berlin.

I

θ will be given by the gravity regression.

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

15 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Results Gravity

Gravity I

I

I ignore location pairs (56% of the total) that have no commuting flow; the regression on the remaining pairs (N = 1.9 million) has R 2 = 0.651. The regression gives θκ = 0.038 ⇒ θ = 2.55. I

I

When restricting sample to location pairs in Chicago proper, I back out θ = 3.75 (less heterogeneity).

It follows that ζ = 1.42. I

This means that a 1% rise in amenity in one location leads to a 1.4% increase in population at that location.

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

16 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Results Amenity regressions

Amenity regressions Violent and property crimes ln(Amenity) (1) ln(Violent)

(2)

−0.267∗∗∗ (0.009)

(4)

(5)

−0.355∗∗∗ −0.130∗∗∗ (0.014) (0.011) −0.306∗∗∗ 0.201∗∗∗ (0.020) (0.024)

ln(Property)

Controls Observations Adjusted R2

(3)

Exog 781 0.653

Exog 781 0.398

Exog 781 0.681

All 781 0.762

(6) −0.144∗∗∗ (0.018)

−0.131∗∗∗ (0.015)

0.024 (0.024)

All 781 0.742

All 781 0.762

∗ p<0.1; ∗∗ p<0.05; ∗∗∗ p<0.01.

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

17 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Results Amenity regressions

Amenity regressions Violent crimes by type ln(Amenity) ln(Homicide)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

−0.137∗∗∗ (0.006)

−0.034∗∗∗ (0.007)

−0.042∗∗∗ (0.006)

−0.011 (0.007)

ln(Assault)

−0.187∗∗∗ (0.018)

−0.069∗∗∗ (0.017)

ln(Robbery)

−0.051∗∗∗ (0.016)

−0.063∗∗∗ (0.014)

0.033∗∗∗ (0.011)

0.013 (0.009)

ln(Sexual assault) Controls Observations Adjusted R2

Exog 781 0.552

Exog 781 0.687

All 781 0.733

All 781 0.762

∗ p<0.1; ∗∗ p<0.05; ∗∗∗ p<0.01. . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

18 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Results Amenity regressions

Amenity regressions Violent crimes, street and non-street ln(Amenity) (1)

(2)

−0.257∗∗∗ (0.019)

−0.136∗∗∗ (0.017)

ln(Non-street)

0.0004 (0.019)

0.007 (0.016)

Controls? Observations Adjusted R2

Exog 781 0.669

All 781 0.766

ln(Street)

∗ p<0.1; ∗∗ p<0.05; ∗∗∗ p<0.01.

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

19 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Results The effect of violent crime

The effect of violent crime I

Violent crime alone can explain 43% of the variation in residential amenity (over exogenous controls).

I

A conservative estimate (excluding endogenous controls) is that a 10% increase in the total violent crime rate (at one location) decreases amenity by 1.3% and residential population by 1.8%. Measuring effects of city-wide changes in crime must take into account “multilateral resistance” term.

I

I

I

Population change in one location might be driven by amenity changes in other locations. City-wide effect of a 10% violent crime increase can range between 0.7 and 2.6% population decline. . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

20 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Results The effect of violent crime

West Side story I

What would happen if violent crime on the West Side were brought down to 750 per 100,000 (near the city median)?

Violent crime rates before (left) and after (right) intervention. . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Tokman

.

. . . .

. . . .

Urban crime and residential decisions

. . . . .. . . . . . . . .. .

21 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Results The effect of violent crime

West Side story I

Experiment 1: Only allow within-city migration. I

I

Experiment 2: Only allow within-metro migration. I

I

West Side population grows by 53,300 (11.1%), Chicago population unchanged West Side population grows by 62,200 (12.9%), Chicago population grows by 45,500 (1.7%)

Experiment 3: Allow migration into metro. I

I

West Side population grows by 66,300 (13.8%), Chicago population grows by 66,300 (2.4%) Assuming an amenity elasticity of 0.26 with respect to violent crime, this number rises to 150,000 . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

22 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Conclusion

Further work

I

Add agglomeration effects, which make amenity partly endogenous to population.

I

Calculate θ separately (to not rely on outside estimates of κ).

I

Counterfactuals increasing suburb-city commute times to, e.g, measure effect of interstates (Baum-Snow, 2007).

I

Separate out low/medium/high-income commuters (different responses to crime).

I

Panel data approach.

. . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

23 / 23

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Extra Goodies Dynamic housing stock

Dynamic housing stock I

Suppose the cost of building an additional unit of housing in location i, ci , is an increasing power function of existing housing stock: ci = ηi Hiαi , where ηi > 0 and αi > 0 can depend on location.

I

In a competitive construction market, at equilibrium Hi′

( =

ri′ ηi

)1/αi ,

where Hi′ is the new equilibrium housing stock and ri′ is the new equilibrium housing price. . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

1/2

. . . .

.

Urban crime and residential decisions Extra Goodies Dynamic housing stock

Dynamic housing stock I

Combined with the market-clearing condition, this gives ( )αi /(αi +1) 1/α ri = (1 − β)wiR ηi LRi .

I

In this case the change in population is given by π ˆRi = ∑ r

Bˆiςi πRr Bˆrςi

,

where now ςi = θ/(1 + γi θ(1 − β)), γi = αi /(αi + 1) (or γi = 1 in the fixed-housing case). . . .

Tokman

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .

Urban crime and residential decisions

2/2

. . . .

.

Urban Crime and Residential Decisions

residential decisions within cities and metro areas. ▷ For the city of Chicago, I find that a 10% increase in the violent crime rate in a particular location is associated with a. 1.8% reduction in population. ▷ City-wide, a 10% increase in violent crime can reduce population by between 0.7 and 2.6%, depending on geographic.

2MB Sizes 1 Downloads 286 Views

Recommend Documents

Urban Crime and Residential Decisions: Evidence from ...
urban decline more generally, while Baum-Snow (2007) lends strong support to the influential theory that ..... this extended sample, I include seven counties, six in Illinois (Cook, Lake, Kane, Will, McHenry,. DuPage) and one in .... tracts (especial

Demand and Supply for Residential Housing in Urban ...
the demand for total stock of a consumer durable good such as automobiles and ... interest rate are small and less frequent as compared with the changes in the ... changes in the commercial bank mortgage rates with the rate for 5 years and .... Table

Crime, Urban Flight, and the Consequences for Cities ...
Nov 8, 2007 - crime implies that higher crime rates outside the city tend to ... Unlike the correlational estimation tech- .... high-school degree (- 10%) relative to high-school dropouts .... The complete set of regressors from table 2 me also inclu

Do Liquor Stores Increase Crime and Urban Decay ...
Financial support from the Center for Labor Economics, Institute of Business and .... This suggests that property crimes are 'mobile' and are sensitive ...... compare the estimated percent change in property crime density in areas within 0.1 miles.

Natural gas residential and
Feb 8, 2016 - Natural gas residential and business rebate programs continue in 2016. Dayton ... “Energy efficient products and services deliver substantial.

Natural gas residential and
Feb 8, 2016 - Natural gas residential and business rebate programs continue in 2016 ... Vectren will continue to offer its gas customers energy efficiency ...

Gas and electric residential and
Feb 8, 2016 - Gas and electric residential and business rebate programs continue in ... in the energy needs of our customers, and Vectren is committed to.

Gas and electric residential and
Feb 8, 2016 - Vectren's energy efficiency programs achieve record energy ... Gas and electric residential and business rebate programs continue in 2016.

Residential Bldg
1 pad certification due at submittal or finish floor elevation certificate due prior to ... 2 pre-engineered truss drawings with hangar hardware called out if used. 5.

Genes and Crime
boy in those programs and risk stigma- tizing him as a violent ... system, asserts Roger D. Masters, a po- ..... and cognitive measures, the degree of prediction ...

Statistics and Decisions
The standard version of statistical decision theory is formulated along. Bayesian lines: all ... Bayesian analog to a point estimate in frequentist analysis. priors.

Architectural Working Drawings: Residential and ...
Title : [PDF BOOK] Architectural Working Drawings: q. Residential and ... Using the Computer for Architectural Design and Drafting. Architectural Drafting ...

Harmony Residential C/O FirstService Residential -
Jun 23, 2015 - ST CLOUD FL 34773 Other - Storage ... The Harmony Residential Board of Directors is dedicated to protecting the investments made in your ...

Residential Movers.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Residential ...Missing:

Harmony Residential C/O FirstService Residential -
Jun 23, 2015 - ST CLOUD FL 34773 Other - Storage. Inspection Date: June 23, 2015 ... Please remove potted plants/personal items from walkways, front ...

Residential Electrician.pdf
electrical service panel. cheap electrician. electrician san diego. electrical work. my electrician. electrician charges. household electrician. car electrician near me. professional electrician. getting your electrical license. electrician requireme

Urban librarians - Presentation - The Urban Librarians Conference
Page 2. Dangerous. Librarianship. Urban Librarians Conference. April 7, 2017 - Brooklyn, NY. Page 3. Whatever you do for me but without me, you do against ...

Urban Roots Farm Manager - Urban Roots Austin
Jul 18, 2014 - Website: http://www.urbanrootsatx.org ... programming we engage hundreds of volunteers through team-building farm work days, provide ...