Unemployment Insurance Take-up Rates in an Equilibrium Search Model∗ Stephane Auray† David L. Fuller‡ Damba Lkhagvasuren

§

May 16, 2013

Abstract In the US unemployment insurance system, only a fraction of those eligible for benefits actually collect them. We argue this empirical fact can be explained by the equilibrium interaction between workers and firms. Firms finance UI benefits via a payroll tax and are heterogeneous with respect to their specific tax rate, which is experience rated. In equilibrium, low tax firms offer workers an alternative UI scheme featuring a faster job arrival rate and a higher wage upon match formation. We find that a move to a 100% collection rate, obtained by removing experience rating in firm taxes, implies a 53% increase in benefit expenditures and a 0.33% welfare gain in consumption equivalent terms. Average search effort decreases, but the unemployment rate and duration decrease as vacancy creation increases. The latter effect results from a change in the composition of employment, as firms become more likely to encounter higher productivity matches. Keywords: unemployment insurance, take-up, matching frictions, search JEL classification: E61, J32, J64, J65



We thank Pierre Cahuc, Yongsung Chang, Francis Kramarz, Philip Jung, Ludo Visschers and Steve Williamson, conference participants at the 5th Ensai Economic day, Rennes, 2012, the Search and Matching conference in Cyprus, 2012, and seminar participants at CREST for their helpful comments. We also thank Wenjing Zhao for excellent research assistance. This paper was written while David Fuller was visiting Ensai, and he would like to thank them for their hospitality. † CREST-Ensai, EQUIPPE (EA 4018), Universit´es Lille Nord de France (ULCO), France, GREDI and CIRPEE, Canada; [email protected] ‡ Department of Economics, Concordia University and CIREQ; [email protected] § Department of Economics, Concordia University and CIREQ; [email protected]

1

1

Introduction The unemployed not collecting benefits they are eligible for may represent the most

important issue regarding the provision of unemployment insurance. We find the “take-up rate” (the fraction of eligible unemployed collecting benefits) averaged 63% from 1989 − 2011. At these take-up rates, the “unclaimed” benefits typically exceed the extended benefit programs in the U.S. that have recently received increasing attention, and in some years the unclaimed benefits actually exceed those paid. The relatively low take-up rates have persisted despite reductions in the costs to applying for benefits, a fact unexplained by traditional theories of take-up rates. In this paper, we develop a theory to explain these facts at the macro-level, and analyze the effects of changes in the unemployment insurance system when the take-up rate responds endogenously. Traditional theories of the take-up decision assume an explicit application cost. It could be the specifics of the administrative procedures, or lack of anonymity, i.e. a “stigma” attached to collecting benefits. While these theories certainly account for some aspects of the take-up decision, application costs in the U.S. have decreased over time. For example, in 1988 94% of initial unemployment insurance claims were filed in person, while in 2009, 85% were filed via phone and internet. Moreover, observed replacement rates and potential benefit durations show no evidence of changes in benefit generosity over time (see Figures 1(a) and 1(b) for details). Given the decrease in application costs, under the traditional theory one expects to see a corresponding increase in the take-up rate. We find, however, that outside of cyclical variations, the take-up rate has remained relatively constant since 1989. We calculate the take-up rate for 1989 − 2011 following a method similar to Blank and Card (1991), using CPS data along with detailed, state-level eligibility criteria. On average, for the period from 1989 − 2011 (the period we calibrate to), the take-up rate is 63%.

2

We develop an alternative theory based on the equilibrium interaction between workers and firms. Specifically, we use a search model with matching frictions, in the class considered by Pissarides (2000). Workers are risk averse, heterogenous in productivity, and exert variable search effort looking for a job. Firms post vacancies and search/advertise for workers to fill them. We allow for heterogenous firms paying different taxes to finance unemployment benefits. This feature captures the “experience rating” in US system, where a firms’ tax rate depends on the experience it has sending workers to collect unemployment benefits. Since firms finance the benefits of their workers, their costs are reduced when fewer workers collect benefits. In our model, the cost of collecting unemployment benefits is endogenously determined by firm and worker decisions. The economy is segmented into two markets, one for workers who collect benefits and one for those who do not. If separated, workers decide whether to collect benefits. That is, they decide which market to search in. Firms in the market with collectors have a higher tax rate, and as a result open fewer vacancies. In equilibrium, workers choosing to search in the non-collecting market receive job offers more frequently relative to those in the collecting market. Wages are determined by Nash Bargaining, and given the experience rated taxes, workers collecting benefits receive lower wage offers relative to an equivalent worker who does not collect. The unemployment benefits in our model represent a stylized version of the US system. Workers receive a constant fraction of their previous wage, up to a maximum benefit amount. We also allow for a “two-tiered” benefit system, similar to Fredriksson and Holmund (2001) and Albrecht and Vroman (2005), where with a Poisson arrival rate a worker collecting benefits may lose them. In equilibrium, the market effectively offers the worker two possible unemployment insurance schemes. The first is determined by the government, but financed by firms. It offers relatively high consumption smoothing during the unemployment spell. The second scheme 3

is offered by firms with the lowest tax rate, who have never sent a worker to collect benefits. This scheme does not directly provide consumption insurance while unemployed, but offers a faster job arrival rate and a higher wage offer when one does arrive. In general, given the aforementioned benefit structure, for both very low and very high productivity workers, the market provided scheme may be more appealing. In our model economy, we then explore whether this endogenous mechanism is quantitatively feasible for the take-up rates observed in the U.S. Our results suggest the model performs well in matching observed take-up rates and other key moments in the data. Using the baseline parametrization, we perform the following counterfactual. Suppose that firm taxes are no longer experience rated, so that all firms pay the same tax rate. Then, the take-up rate goes to 100% as the market UI scheme is no longer offered. The move to 100% take-up has several interesting implications. First, total benefit expenditures increase by 53%. On average, from 1989 − 2011, the UI program in the U.S. paid $51 billion in unemployment benefits (in 2011 dollars), implying an additional $27 billion in unemployment benefits per year. Over the entire period, this amounts to an additional $624 billion in benefit expenditures. We also examine the impact on equilibrium from the move to the 100% take-up rate model. The unemployment rate decreases from 6.0% in the baseline model (the average unemployment rate during the 1989 − 2011 period) to 5.35%. Moreover the average duration of unemployment decreases from 18 weeks to 15. The existing literature on the effects of unemployment benefits on these moments predicts a much different result. According to the standard theory, more unemployed collecting benefits implies reduced search effort, and as a result a higher unemployment rate and average duration of unemployment (Davidson and Woodbury (1998) and Wang and Williamson (2002) are two examples where unemployment insurance policies are considered in models with take-up rates less than 1, but in these papers the take-up rate is exogenous, and thus invariant to changes in policy.) Indeed, as 4

the standard theory predicts, search intensity in our model decreases when the take-up rate increases to 100%. In equilibrium, however, vacancy creation increases, offsetting the effects of reduced search effort. Why do firms create more vacancies when faced with reduced search effort among the unemployed? While search effort decreases on average, the variance of search effort increases. Specifically, there is more variation in search effort by productivity at the higher levels of productivity. This implies that the endogenous distribution of agents across productivity changes, and firms are more likely to match with a relatively high productivity agent. This effect increases the expected value of a vacancy, and the free-entry condition implies that vacancy creation increases. Even after accounting for the lower average search effort, the firm effects imply that the unemployment rate and average duration of unemployment decrease. Moreover, the move to a 100% take-up rate increases welfare by around 0.33% in consumption equivalent terms. While the welfare of the unemployed does increase, the majority of the welfare gains arise from an increase in the welfare of the employed. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we present the data, our procedure for estimating the take-up rate, and provide a discussion of how the data supports our modeling choices. Next, Section 3 describes the model, while Section 4 presents the calibration, empirical results, and policy experiments. Finally, we conclude in Section 6.

5

“I did not want to do this as I did not want the negative impression of the VEC (Virginia Employment Commission) checking with employers while they were considering my application. I did not want the risk of seeming like a bad candidate and hurting my chances of being accepted.” Matthew Egerton on why he did not collect UI benefits, Huffington Post, December 2012

2

Evidence on take-up rates This section has three purposes. First, we explain some features of the unemployment

insurance system in the U.S. relevant for our analysis. Second, we present data that support our attempt to model alternative costs to applying for unemployment benefits. Finally, we detail our estimation of the take-up rate, and explore the key features of our estimates.

2.1

Unemployment Insurance System in the U.S.

The costs imposed on firms by workers who collect benefits represents the key element of our theory. The specifics of the U.S. unemployment insurance system help illuminate these costs. These costs arise from the administrative procedures related to a worker who files a claim for benefits, and the tax rates imposed on firms to finance the benefits. When a worker files a claim for unemployment benefits, the UI authority in that U.S. state then contacts the worker’s previous employer(s) to verify the relevant information. For example, they verify the wages claimed by the worker to determine eligibility and calculate the proper benefit. They also have to verify that the nature of the separation is proper, since certain separations render the worker ineligible for benefits (we discuss these criteria below in Section 2.3). Disagreements between the worker and the firm the case may move to the legal system to resolve the dispute. Thus, even before paying taxes, the administrative costs 6

related to a worker filing a claim for benefits may be substantial. The payroll tax levied on firms to finance benefits is experienced rated. Firms pay a tax rate that is positively correlated with their contribution to insured unemployment in their particular U.S. state. For example, a firm that has never separated from a worker who collects benefits pays a lower tax rate than a firm that has frequent layoffs collecting benefits. Note, for the firm’s tax rate, it does not matter how frequently they separate from workers, but how frequently they separate from workers who collect benefits. The precise nature of this experience rating depends on the U.S. state, with both the tax rates and the taxable wage base varying across states. In 2010 for example, the smallest taxable wage base was $7000 (several states) and the maximum was $37, 300 in Washington. The experience rated taxes are subject to maximum and minimum amounts. In 2010 the lowest minimum tax rate was 0% (several states) and the highest maximum rate was 13.5576% in Pennsylvania. In this paper, we examine how this experience rating affects the hiring decisions of firms. It remains possible, however, that the aforementioned experience rating also affects firm layoff decisions. Feldstein (1976) and Topel (1983) both examine how the partial experience rating in the U.S. affects firm separation decisions. For example, a firm may find it beneficial to reduce the hours worked as opposed to a layoff to economize on unemployment insurance taxes. While in our model we assume separations are exogenous, an interesting direction for further research is to incorporate this dimension into our analysis of take-up decisions.

2.2

Filing methods for initial claim

If there do exist explicit costs to applying for unemployment benefits, these should manifest themselves in the specifics of the application process. Examining data on the initial filing method represents one way to determine how the costs to applying may have changed over time. Such data is available from a program called BAM (Benefit Accuracy Measurement) run by the U.S. Department of Labor. BAM selects a random sample of UI 7

1

0.5

24.5

In Person Claims Phone and Internet Claims

0.9

Replacement Rate Potential Benefit Duration

0.6 0.5 0.4

0.45

24

0.3

Potential Benefit Duration

0.7 Replacment Rate

Filing Method (% of total)

0.8

0.2 0.1 0

1990

1995

2000 Year

2005

0.4 1988

2010

(a) Filing Methods

1990

1992

1994

1996 1998 Year

2000

2002

2004

23.5 2006

(b) Benefit Generosity

recipients/applicants and audits each case to examine the accuracy of paid claims, as well as the appropriateness of any benefit denials. Among the many variables of interest in the BAM data, the audit determines the method used for filing the initial claim. In Figure 1(a) we present this data from 1988 − 2009. There exist five possible initial filing methods. These include, in person, mail (including e-mail), telephone, employer filed claim, and internet claim. Figure 1(a) plots the fraction of agents who file in person, compared to the fraction filing by phone and/or internet (the other filing methods account for a small fraction of the total).1 The graph indicates that there has been a large shift in how unemployment benefit applications are filed in the U.S.; in person claims and phone and internet claims have switched as the dominant method. This change has almost certainly had an effect on the explicit application costs of applying for UI. First, since an in person application is typically no longer required, at a minimum, the time associated with filing a claim has been dramatically reduced. Second, applying via phone or internet makes the process more anonymous, which reduces any negative stigma associated with applying for benefits. One could also argue that changes in the generosity of benefits may affect the take-up 1

Prior to 2002, there were no internet claims observed, so this represents a recent phenomenon.

8

rate. That is, although application costs have decreased, benefits may be less generous. In Figure 1(b) we plot the average replacement ratio and potential benefit duration (average across US states) over time. These averages are for individuals who collected benefits. There is some cyclical behavior, but otherwise it appears that the generosity of the US system has been relatively constant over the period from 1988 − 2010. Given these facts, if indeed explicit application costs explain the majority of the takeup decision, we should observe an increase in the take-up rate as these costs have clearly decreased, with no change in benefit generosity. We argue the take-up rate has remained relatively constant, and below we present the details of our calculations.

2.3

Take-up rate estimates

While many statistics and data on the labor market are readily available for public use, there exists little information on take-up rates of unemployment insurance. There is data on the characteristics of the insured unemployed, as well as data on the ratio of insured unemployed to total unemployed (hereafter IUR). The IUR series is the ratio of insured unemployed (those collecting benefits) to total unemployment. While this provides some characterization of the take-up rate, the IUR does not control for eligibility. For example, there exist limits on the duration one may collect benefits for (typically 26 weeks); as a result, the IUR includes individuals who are not eligible to collect because they have been unemployed for longer than 26 weeks. Moreover, each state has specific eligibility criteria, further complicating the calculation of take-up rates since each state must be considered separately. To calculate the take-up rate, we first find the fraction of unemployed agents who are currently eligible to collect, and then take the ratio to insured unemployed to total eligible unemployed. We follow a method similar to Blank and Card (1991). Specifically, we use data from the March Supplement of the CPS (Current Population Survey) along with the specific eligibility 9

1 TUR IUR MNE,Dur MNE

0.9

0.8

0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

Figure 1: Take-up Rates by Eligibility Criteria criteria of each state, for each year from 1989 − 2011.2 Eligibility depends primarily on three factors, and Figure 1 displays our estimate of the take-up rate, IUR, and the contribution of each of the three eligibility criteria. The line labeled IUR plots the insured to total unemployment ratio from 1989 − 2011, and the line labeled TUR plots our estimate of the take-up rate. We now explain our approach to estimating each of the three primary eligibility categories. First, there exist monetary eligibility requirements. These require an agent to have accumulated a sufficient amount of earnings in a specified “base-period,” or worked a minimum number of weeks.3 To estimate monetary eligibility, we use the earnings information contained in the March CPS. The line labeled MNE in Figure 1 displays the increase in the take-up rate from the IUR when only monetary eligibility requirements are imposed. The nature of the separation leading to the spell of unemployment represents the second element of eligibility criteria. Specifically, in most states, agents who quit their previous 2

Both Blank and Card (1991) and Anderson and Meyer (1997) provide estimates of the take-up rate prior to 1989. 3 The base-period differs across states. Many use a year, while others use two quarters. The base-period is used both to determine monetary eligibility and to calculate the specific benefit an agent is entitled to.

10

job, or were fired for cause, are not eligible to collect benefits.4 This criteria is intended to limit benefits to only those individuals who have lost their job through no fault of their own. In the CPS data, we can eliminate quits; however, we can not determine whether or not the agent was fired for cause. In addition, the total unemployed in the CPS contain re-entrants (those who had previously left the labor-force, but are now re-entering), and new entrants (those never previously in the labor force). Since these later two groups are clearly not eligible to collect benefits, we exclude them. Finally, eligibility for benefits depends on the length of the unemployment spell. All states have a maximum potential duration of benefits, which typically limits benefits to 26 weeks. There are some exceptions to this rule, as some states allow for 30 weeks of benefits, and in times of high unemployment, eligibility may be extended through the Federal-State Extended Compensation Program, and we account for these where applicable. In addition to the maximum length of benefits, many states also have a minimum waiting period, typically 1 week. Since the CPS contains information on the agent’s length of unemployment spells, we are able to control for this criteria. In Figure 1, the line labeled MNE-Dur displays the take-up rate when only the aforementioned duration criteria are removed, and eligibility is determined by the monetary and separation requirements. Overall, Figure 1 displays that the monetary and duration criteria contribute the most to the difference between the take-up rate and IUR, and the separation criteria less so. Another interesting feature displayed in Figure 1 is the cyclical nature of these data. Figure 2 plots our estimate of the take-up rate from 1989−2011, along with the corresponding average duration of unemployment in March of each year. The left-hand y-axis plots the take-up rate, and the right hand y-axis the average duration of unemployment. There are two interesting features of this graph. First, there is a clear cyclical dimension to the 4

Georgia is an exception, and does allow job leavers (quits) to collect benefits, but they face an increased waiting period before eligible.

11

1

40

0.9 35 0.8

0.7

0.5

25

0.4

Average Duration

Take−up Rate

30 0.6

20 0.3

0.2 15 0.1

0 1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

10 2015

Year

Figure 2: Take-up Rates and Average Duration of Unemployment take-up rate, as its movements track very closely the movements in the average duration of unemployment. Second, outside of these cyclical variations, the take-up rate appears to have remained relatively constant, or may have slightly declined.

3

Model

3.1

Setup

The economy consists of a unit-measure of infinitely-lived, risk-averse agents, and a large measure of risk-neutral firms. Time is continuous and goes on forever, and agents and firms both discount the future at rate r > 0. Each agent has an endowment of one unit of time. Agents have preferences over consumption and leisure, with per-period utility function given by h(c, `), where c represents consumption and ` is leisure. Let hc and h` denote the partial derivatives of h with respect to its first and second arguments, respectively. Agents are heterogenous with respect to their permanent productivity y. Let Y denote the set of all productivity levels. Let F be the distribution of agents over Y. Firms are 12

composed of a single job, either filled or vacant, and discount future profits at rate r. Vacant firms are free to enter and pay a flow cost, κ > 0, to advertise a vacancy. Vacant firms produce no output. The flow output of a firm with a filled job is given by productivity of its employee y. Workers vary the intensity with which they search for a match. Specifically, an unemployed worker exerts search effort s ∈ [0, 1] looking for a firm; therefore, leisure is ` = 1 − s. While employed, a worker supplies labor inelastically, spending sw hours of the time endowment working. Unemployment benefits are financed by lump-sum taxes levied on firms. These taxes are experienced rated in the following manner. All firms contribute a payroll tax, but firms that hire workers who collect benefits pay higher taxes relative to firms that hire agents who do not collect benefits. We model this feature by segmenting the labor market into two “types” of firms: firms that hire collectors and firms that do not. Since ultimately the decision to collect or not depends on the worker’s permanent productivity, a collector works and searches in that sector for life. An alternative to assuming segmented markets (an approach we used in an earlier version of this paper) is to assume homogenous firms and vacancies, but allow the firm to vary its advertising intensity searching for collectors vs. non-collectors. This does not affect the results, but assuming segmented markets allows the key mechanisms to be more transparent.

3.1.1

Matching technology and frictions

There exists a matching function describing the number of matches formed between the v vacancies and u unemployed workers in each of the two sectors of the economy. Denote the average search intensity of the unemployed in sector j ∈ {1, 3} by s¯j . Further let Sj ≡ s¯j uj denote the “efficiency units” the unemployed workers searching in sector j. The matching function is given by m(S, v), which gives the number of matches between 13

the S efficiency units of unemployed searchers and v vacancies. We assume standard properties, i.e. m, is continuous, strictly increasing, strictly concave (with respect to each of its arguments), and exhibits constant returns to scale. Furthermore, m(0, ·) = m(·, 0) = 0 and vj denote the vacancy to unemployment ratio in sector m(∞, ·) = m(·, ∞) = ∞. Let θj = uj j ∈ {1, 3}. Given this matching technology, a vacancy is filled (by a worker in sector j ∈ {1, 3}) with Poisson arrival rate aj m(Sj /vj , 1). Similarly, an unemployed worker with collection status j and search intensity sj (y) finds a job according to a Poisson process with arrival rate sj (y)m(1, vj /Sj ). Let qj = m(Sj /vj , 1) and pj = m(1, vj /Sj ) for j ∈ {1, 3}. Filled jobs receive negative idiosyncratic productivity shocks rendering the match unprofitable with a Poisson arrival rate λ. Given the aforementioned technology, matching is random. When a firm meets a worker and a vacancy is filled, it is filled by a worker drawn randomly from the population. The firm does not direct its search. Since search intensity is variable and endogenous, however, the population of unemployed agents across y is endogenous. Thus, the probability that upon meeting, a firm randomly matches with a worker of productivity y, is endogenously determined in equilibrium.

3.2

Value functions

This section details the Bellman equations describing the behavior of workers and firms and the mechanism of the wage determination. Unemployed agents can be in one of three possible states. The states are differentiated based on whether or not the agent collects unemployment benefits. First, upon being separated from an employer, the agent decides whether to enter unemployment state i = 1 or i = 3, where i = 1 denotes unemployed collecting benefits, while i = 3 denotes unemployed not collecting benefits. That is, the worker decides which sector of the economy to search in. 14

Finally, if collecting benefits, we assume that with Poisson arrival rate δ, benefit eligibility ends, and the agent enters state i = 2. This feature captures the empirical fact that in the U.S., unemployment benefits are paid for a fixed period of time, while maintaining a stationary environment. Let ui (y) denote the number of unemployed workers of productivity y in state i ∈ {1, 2, 3}. Let ej (y) denote the total number of employed workers of productivity y working in market j ∈ {1, 3}.

3.2.1

Workers

Let Ui (y) denote the expected value of searching for a job to an unemployed worker of productivity y who is in state i ∈ {1, 2, 3}. Let W (y) denote the expected lifetime utility of employment to a worker of productivity y. Below, zi (y) denotes the flow income/consumption of an unemployed worker in state i ∈ {1, 2, 3}, and w(y) denotes the wage. Wages are determined via Nash Bargaining between the worker and firm. In equilibrium there exists a one-to-one mapping of productivity to wages. Given this, the value functions are given by:

rU1 (y) = max {h(z1 (y), 1 − s) + p1 s (W (y) − U1 (y)) + δ (U2 (y) − U1 (y))}

(1)

rU2 (y) = max {h(z2 (y), 1 − s) + p1 s (W (y) − U2 (y))}

(2)

rU3 (y) = max {h(z3 (y), 1 − s) + p3 s (W (y) − U3 (y))}

(3)

rW (y) = h(w(y), 1 − sw ) + λ (max{U1 (y), U3 (y)} − W (y)) .

(4)

s

s

s

Equation (1) says that an unemployed agent collecting benefits receives instantaneous flow utility h(z1 (y), 1 − s) from unemployment compensation and the utility cost of search effort s. With arrival rate p1 s the worker matches with a firm and transitions to employment, while at rate δ unemployment benefits expire, and the agent transitions to state i = 2. Equation (2) and (3) have similar interpretations for an agent who has exhausted benefits and one who never collected, respectively. Finally, equation (4) states that, given the productivity15

specific wage w(y), an employed agent receives instantaneous flow utility h(w(y), 1 − sw ). With Poisson arrival rate λ, the job dissolves and the agent then decides whether or not to collect unemployment benefits. Notice, since productivity is permanent, in the steady state, if a worker prefers to enter sector j ∈ {1, 3} she always prefers this sector. Thus, there are effectively two employed value functions, each with a distinct wage function, wj (y):

rW1 (y) = h(w1 (y), 1 − sw ) + λ (U1 (y) − W1 (y))

(5)

rW3 (y) = h(w3 (y), 1 − sw ) + λ (U3 (y) − W3 (y))

(6)

Indeed, in equilibrium, workers in sector j = 3 (i.e. non-collectors) receive higher wages for a given y that workers in sector j = 1 (collectors). This represents one aspect of the market provided UI scheme. The flow income of an unemployed worker collecting benefits is modelled using the key features of the U.S. system. This system involves payments that are a constant fraction of the previous wage, for a fixed length of time. An agent’s unemployment benefit is given by bw1 (y), where b is the replacement rate. We also model the feature of the U.S. system by restricting the benefits subject to a maximum amount denoted by B. Then, the actual unemployment benefit of the agent is given by min{bw1 (y), B}. All unemployed workers, regardless of collection status, earn a base level of income, given by gwi (y), i ∈ {1, 3}, where g < b.5 The consumption of an unemployed agent is summarized by the following function:

zi (y) =

   gw1 (y) + min{bw1 (y), B} if i = 1,

(7)

if i ∈ {2, 3}.

  gwi (y) 5

Depending on the specific utility function, it may be necessary to set g to a positive number. There are several possible ways to interpret this value. A natural interpretation of non-market income is home production. Another possibility is that g serves as a proxy for other assets or savings. The main idea is that for positive g, an agent’s total consumption while not employed is not equal to only UI benefits if collecting.

16

3.2.2

Firms

Denote by Vj the value of a vacancy and Jj the value of a matched firm in sector j ∈ {1, 3}. Further, let Y1 ⊂ Y denote the subset of productivity levels where workers collect benefits and Y3 ⊂ Y (Y3 = Y \ Y1 ) denote the subset of productivity levels where workers do not collect benefits. Then, a firm’s vacancy creation is captured by Z rVj = −κ + qj

(Jj (y) − Vj ) dψj (y)}

(8)

Yj

where ψj (y) is the endogenous distribution across y of the unemployed population in sector j. Notice, since workers exert search effort si (y), i ∈ {1, 2, 3}, and this depends on y, in equilibrium the job finding rate for an unemployed worker may differ by productivity. The firm pays per-period lump sum payroll taxes τj that are experience rated; therefore, τ1 > τ3 . Specifically, we assume that τ3 is fixed at some level. Then, τ1 is determined based on the total UI expenditures in equilibrium. The Bellman equations describing the value of a matched firm in sector j are:

rJj (y) = y − w − τj + λ (Vj − Jj (y))

3.2.3

(9)

Wages

Upon meeting and deciding to form a match, wages are determined by the generalized Nash Bargaining solution between workers and firms. Letting β ∈ (0, 1) denote the worker’s bargaining power, the wage for an agent of productivity y ∈ Yj for j ∈ {1, 3} is determined by: max (Wj (y; wj ) − Uj (y))β (Jj (y; wj ) − Vj )1−β wj

17

(10)

We also assume that wages can be re-negotiated at any time, so that the threat value of an agent who collects benefits is U1 (y), regardless of whether or not benefits have expired.

3.3

Behavior of workers and firms

In the remainder of the section, we characterize the equilibrium of the model economy. Toward this end, the F.O.C. of equation 10 is given by,

Wj (y) − Ui (y) =

β (Jj (y) − Vj ) hc (wj (y), 1 − sw ). 1−β

(11)

Let si (y) be the optimal choice of search effort for an unemployed worker with productivity y. Using the F.O.C. in the agent’s problem with respect to s,

pi (Wj (y) − Ui (y)) = h` (zi (y), 1 − si (y)).

(12)

Furthermore, using the free-entry condition for firms, Vj = 0, (9)to solve for Jj , and plugging into (8) gives k = qj

Z Yj

y − wj (y) − τj dψj (y) r+λ

(13)

Given the decision rules for effort in (12), the Bellman equations for unemployed workers are simplified to the following:

rU1 (y) = h(z1 (y), 1 − s1 (y)) + s1 (y)h` (z1 (y), 1 − s1 (y)) + δ (U2 (y) − U1 (y))

(14)

rU2 (y) = h(z2 (y), 1 − s2 (y)) + s2 (y)h` (z2 (y), 1 − s2 (y))

(15)

rU3 (y) = h(z3 (y), 1 − s3 (y)) + s3 (y)h` (z3 (y), 1 − s3 (y)).

(16)

Using these equations, the following must hold for an unemployed agent who is currently

18

collecting benefits:

W1 (y) − U1 (y) =

1 n h(w1 (y), 1 − sw ) − r + λ  r h(z1 (y), 1 − s1 (y)) + s(y)h` (z1 (y), 1 − s1 (y)) − r+δ o δ  h(z2 (y), 1 − s2 (y)) + s2 (y)h` (z2 (y), 1 − s2 (y)) . r+δ

(17)

Combining (4), (15), and (17), for an agent who has exhausted benefits, λ  h(z1 (y), 1 − s1 (y)) + r+δ  r+λ+δ s1 (y)h` (z1 (y), 1 − s(y)) − × r+δ  

(r + λ)(W1 (y) − U2 (y)) = h(w1 (y), 1 − sw ) +

h(z2 (y), 1 − s2 (y)) + s2 (y)h` (z2 (y), 1 − s2 (y)) .

(18)

Finally, for a non-collector, using (4) and (16) we have

(r +λ)(W3 (y)−U3 (y)) = h(w3 (y), 1−sw )−h(z3 (y), 1−s3 (y))−s(y)h` (z3 (y), 1−s3 (y)). (19)

Combining (17) and (19) with the Nash F.O.C. in (11) determines wj (y), and combining (17)-(19) with (12) determines the optimal search intensity si (y) for each i. 3.3.1

Endogenous segmentation by productivity

To determine equilibrium, we also need to determine the set Y1 . This can be characterized by U1 (y) and U3 (y) crossing either once or twice (of course they need not cross for every parametrization). Figure 3 plots the difference U3 (y) − U1 (y) across y for our baseline calibration. Let y0 and y1 denote these crossing points, i.e. U1 (y0 ) = U3 (y0 ) and U1 (y1 ) = U3 (y1 ). The difference U3 (y) − U1 (y) starts increasing at the value of y where the maximum benefit level begins to bind. Once the maximum benefit binds, as y (and thus w(y)) increases,

19

2.5

2

1.5

1

rV (y)−rV (y)

1

3

0.5

0

−0.5

−1

−1.5 0

10

20

30

40 50 60 Productivity, y

70

80

90

100

Figure 3: Determination of Y1 the replacement rate is decreasing, and eventually becomes low enough that the benefits of not collecting (higher job arrival rate and higher wage) outweigh the benefits of collecting. Thus, for productivity values below y0 and above y1 (i.e., when U1 (y) < U3 (y)) agents do not collect benefits, while for intermediate productivity values, agents do collect. So, Y1 = {y ∈ Y|y0 < y < y1 }. Given the sets Y1 and Y3 , we define the take-up rate similarly to our calculation in the data. That is, the take-up rate is the ratio of unemployed collecting to total unemployed:

T UR =

u1 u1 + u2 + u3

where ui , i ∈ {1, 2, 3} is the measure of unemployed workers in each state i.

20

3.3.2

Labor market flows and stocks

Our description of equilibrium also requires the flow equations associated with the measures {u1 , u2 , u3 , e1 , e3 }. Each labor market has flow into and out of the various employment states. For the market of collectors, we have the following flow equations.

λe1 (y) = p1 u1 (y)s1 (y) + p1 u2 (y)s2 (y), ∀y ∈ Y1

(20)

δu1 (y) = p1 s2 (y)u2 (y), ∀y ∈ Y1

(21)

e1 (y) + u1 (y) + u2 (y) = f (y), ∀y ∈ Y1 ,

(22)

where f denotes the p.d.f of F . Equation (20) states that the flows into and out of insured employment remain equal. The flows of agents who have exhausted benefits is governed by equation (21), and equation Z (22) ensures the total number of agents searching in this market is dF (y). Given these Y1

flows, we now determine the endogenous distribution of unemployed agents over productivity, ψ1 (y). The density function for this distribution is given by:

ψ1 (y) =

u1 (y) + u2 (y) u1 + u2

(23)

Z where ui =

ui (y)dF (y), i = 1, 2. Y1

We also have flow equations in the market of non-collectors. Under our specification of preferences and flow income/consumption, since agents in this market do not collect UI benefits, the difference W3 (y) − U3 (y) remains constant across y. From equation 12 this implies that effort for agents in this market remains constant across y. Thus, the flows in and out of employment are also constant across y, and we need only determine µe,3 and µu,3 ,

21

which do not vary across y.

λe3 = p3 s3 u3 Z e3 + u3 = dF (y)

(24) (25)

Y3

Equation (24) equalizes the flows into and out of employment in this market, and (25) ensures consistency of the fraction of agents searching in this market. Since the measure of agents is constant across y, the distribution of agents across y in this market is simply given by F (y); i.e. ψ3 (y) = F (y), ∀y ∈ Y3 . We now summarize the equilibrium conditions.

3.3.3

Equilibrium

Definition 1 An equilibrium consists of functions {w1 (y), w3 (y), s1 (y), s2 (y), s3 (y)}, measures of workers {u1 , u2 , u3 , e1 , e3 }, quantities {q1 , q3 , S1 , S3 , τ } and subsets {Y1 , Y3 } such that 1. Given equations (17)-(19), (a) qj satisfies (13), (b) the function wj satisfies (11) for j ∈ {1, 3}, and (c) the function si (y), satisfies (12) for each i; 2. {u1 , u2 , u3 , e1 , e3 } satisfy (20)-(25); 3. Subsets {Y1 , Y3 } and total search intensities {S1 , S2 } are consistent with individuals’ behavior: 1 S1 = u1 + u2

Z (u1 (y)s1 (y) + u2 (y)s2 (y))dy, Y1

22

(26)

Z s3 (y)dy = s3

S3 =

(27)

Y3

and, 4. τ satisfies the government’s budget constraint: Z

Z min{bw1 (y), B}u1 (y)dy = τ1

Y1

e1 (y)dy + τ3 e3

(28)

Y1

where the L.H.S. gives total benefits paid, the R.H.S. total revenue collected from firms.

4

Empirical analysis In this section, we present a quantitative analysis of the aforementioned model and equi-

librium. The goal in this section is to evaluate how well the endogenous mechanism explains observed take-up rates. Our calibration focuses on the time period from 1989 − 2011.

4.1

Calibration

The model described in Section 3 leaves the following parameters to be determined: β, r, b, B, d, λ, δ, κ, F (y), τ1 /τ3 (ratio of taxes in collecting and non-collecting sectors), and functional forms for the matching function m and the utility function h.

4.1.1

Preferences

The time period is set to one quarter, so a per-annum risk-free interest rate of 0.04 implies r = 0.01. The utility function is given by

h(c, `) =

(c`γ )1−φ − 1 1−φ

23

(29)

For the coefficient of relative risk aversion, we use a standard value of 1.0, which falls within the range considered in Hansen and Imrohoroglu (1992) and the existing RBC literature.

4.1.2

Matching technology, separation, and search costs

For the matching function, m, we use the standard constant returns to scale form given by m(Sj , vj ) = Sjη v1−η where j ∈ {1, 3}.6 As in Fredriksson and Holmund (2001), we j use a value of 0.5 for β; furthermore, we set η = β. The job separation rate is set to λ = 0.031, consistent with Shimer (2005). We then set the utility parameter on leisure, γ to match the unemployment rate during the 1989 − 2011 period, 6.0%. This implies a value of γ = 0.49. We set the marginal cost of advertising k = 4.176, which is set to match the average unemployment duration of 18.1 weeks, or 1.39 quarters, from 1989 − 2011. Table 1: Parameters r φ β η λ b B g δ k γ σ τ1 τ3

0.01 1.0 0.5 0.5 0.031 0.48 1.23 0.4 0.5 4.1760 0.49 1/3.96 2.55

Discount rate Coefficient of relative risk aversion Bargaining parameter Elasticity of matching function Job separation rate Replacement rate, UI, non-binding Maximum UI benefit Minimum consumption rate Length of unemployment benefits Marginal cost of vacancy advertising Utility parameter Scale parameter of F (y) Experience rating

An equivalent alternative, used by others including Shimer (2005), is m(S, A) = m0 S η v1−η where S/v is normalized to 1, and m0 is chosen to target the number of matches. 6

24

4.1.3

U.S. unemployment insurance system

Our model in Section 3 specifies a stylized, but relatively detailed version of the U.S. unemployment insurance system. The next step in our calibration is to determine the relevant parameters describing this system. To do so, we need to find three values: b, the basic replacement rate; B the maximum benefit level; and δ, the arrival rate of benefit expiry. While the March CPS Supplement does contain some information about the actual amount of benefits collected, given the incomplete nature of the earnings information, any calculations of replacement rates is likely to be relatively inaccurate. Moreover, there exist many idiosyncrasies among states regarding unemployment insurance laws, regulations, and benefit calculations; as a result, difficulties arise determining the actual replacement rate for a given state, let alone for the overall U.S. economy. To circumvent these difficulties, we use data from BAM (Benefit Accuracy Measurement) from to directly calculate the replacement rate, maximum benefit amount, and potential duration of benefits. Since the data are from careful audits of unemployment claims, the earnings and benefit information is more complete and accurate for this task than the CPS data. For the U.S. overall, we calculate the average benefit duration is 24 weeks and the average replacement rate is 0.45 (see Section 2.2 for the details of these calculations). These are similar to the commonly used 26 week duration and 0.50 replacement rate. To match the 24 week potential duration of benefits, we set δ = 0.5417 (this implies average potential duration of 1/0.5417 = 1.8462 quarters). We find that for those agents receiving below the maximum benefit, the replacement rate is b = 0.48, and we thus set b accordingly. Further, we find that on average 23% of those collecting UI benefits are receiving the maximum benefit level in their respective state. To set the maximum benefit, we target the average replacement rate among those receiving the maximum benefit, which is 0.36. We target these two moments with the maximum benefit level and the distribution of productivity F (y). For the latter, we assume an exponential distribution, so that F (y) = 1 − exp(−y/σ), 25

where σ > 0. To match the fraction of agents collecting who receive the maximum benefit amount, we set σ = 1/3.96 = 0.2525. Accordingly, we set the maximum benefit to B = 1.23 to match the average replacement rate among this group. To calibrate the fraction g, which is the fraction of previous wages an unemployed worker consumes when not receiving unemployment benefits. We set g = 0.4, which implies an unemployed worker collecting benefits consumes 88% of their employed consumption. This is roughly consistent with the estimates in Gruber (1997). Finally, we set taxes to both balance the government’s budget constraint, and to match the target take-up rate, 63%. Specifically, we use the ratio of taxes in the two sectors, τ1 /τ3 to target the take-up rate. When this ratio approaches 1, the experience rating of firms disappears, while the economy moves towards perfect experience rating when the ratio approaches ∞. We only target the ratio as firms in the non-collecting sector never send workers to insured unemployment; in the US system, these firms pay the minimum tax rate. We find a ratio of 2.55 matches the observed take-up rate, and we then set τ1 to balance the budget. Table 1 lists the parameters and their values.

4.2

Results Table 2: Calibration Results Moment Model Unemployment rate 6.0% Unemployment duration 1.40 (18.18 weeks) Take-up rate 0.62 Replacement rate, binding benefit 0.38 Fraction with binding benefit 0.237 Standard deviation of log wages 0.691

Data 6.0% 1.39 (18.1) 0.63 0.36 0.23 0.801

Table 2 presents the results from our calibration. There are several interesting features of the results that we now explore in more detail. First, the model performs well matching 26

the observed moments of the U.S. economy. While we do not directly target the standard deviation of log wages, the model’s predictions are quite close to the data. Next, consider the differences between the government provided UI scheme (62% of the unemployed are collecting such benefits) and the market scheme. A faster job arrival rate represents the essential feature of the market provided UI scheme. Indeed, in the noncollecting market, the vacancy to unemployment ratio is θ3 = 0.926, compared to θ1 = 0.783 in the collecting market. In the non-collecting market, this implies an average job arrival rate of 0.805, or an average unemployment duration of 1.24 quarters. Similarly, for the collecting market, the job arrival rate is 0.668, for an average unemployment duration of 1.5 quarters.

5

Policy analysis This section analyzes the implications of a take-up rate below 100%. To determine the

impact, we perform the following counterfactual. Suppose we remove the firm experience rating; thus, all firms pay the same taxes. This implies we move to a single sector economy, and the take-up rate becomes 100%, as the market UI scheme is no longer available. There are several implications of this change. First, the total expenditures on UI increase by 53%. With a take-up rate of 62%, one expects an increase in benefit expenditures of around 38%. Notice, however, the additional collectors in our model are primarily those entitled to the maximum benefit amount. From 1989 − 2011 the average UI expenditures per year was $51 billion (in 2011 dollars), implying an additional $27 billion in unemployment benefits per year. Over the entire period, this amounts to an additional $624 billion in benefit expenditures. Table 3 compares the key features of equilibrium in each of the two economies. Despite the increase in benefit expenditures, the equilibrium unemployment rate decreases from 6.0% to 5.35%, and the average duration of unemployment decreases from 1.39 to 1.21 quarters.

27

Table 3: Counterfactual: 100% Take-up Economy Moment Unemployment rate Unemployment duration Take-up rate Vacancies, v

Baseline Model 6.0% 1.40 (18.18 weeks) 0.62 4.97%

100% Take-up Model 5.35% 1.21 (15.73) 1 6.43%

How do these moments decrease when more unemployed workers collect benefits? Standard theory predicts that an increase in unemployment benefits increases both the unemployment rate and the average duration of unemployment, as unemployed workers exert less search effort looking for employment. Indeed, in our model, the move to a 100% take-up rate does decrease average search effort, by 3%. The composition of employment changes, however, affecting the vacancy creation decisions of firms. Specifically, in the 100% take-up rate economy, vacancy creation increases by 29%. Recall, equilibrium vacancy creation is determined by the free-entry condition in equation (13). If the value of a filled vacancy (the RHS of (13) ) increases, then vacancy creation increases. In the 100% take-up economy, the distribution of unemployed agents across y, i.e. the distribution φ(y), changes. While average search effort decreases, when everyone collects, higher productivity workers arrive faster for the firm. Since firm profits increase with productivity, this has the aforementioned effect on the value of a filled vacancy, and thus on vacancy creation. To understand this effect, we examine how search effort differs in the two economies. Figure 4 plots search effort across y for unemployed workers currently collecting benefits. When receiving the basic replacement rate, search effort remains constant across y, since the difference between employed and unemployed consumption is constant. Once the maximum benefit amount binds, search effort begins to increase with y, as the value of employment increases faster than the value of unemployment. 28

0.7

Search effort, s1(y)

0.68

0.66

0.64

0.62

0.6

0.58 0

5

10

15 Productivity, y

20

25

30

Figure 4: Search effort, collectors For relatively high values of y, unemployed workers choose not to collect benefits. For these agents, unemployed consumption is always a constant fraction of employed consumption, implying constant search effort across y. Since search effort remains constant across y in the non-collecting market, the distribution of the unemployed across y is identical to the population distribution F (y) (over the relevant range of y). In comparison, in the collecting market for higher productivities search effort increases with y. As a result, the distribution of the unemployed across y, φ1 (y), is not the same as the population distribution, as unemployed workers exit unemployment at different rates across y. Figure 5 displays the change in search effort moving from the baseline economy to the 100% take-up rate version.7 In the baseline economy, for intermediate values of productivity, search effort coincides with that in Figure 4; i.e. s1 (y). Once the critical value of y is reached (above which the unemployed prefer not to collect), search effort jumps to the higher level, s3 , and remains constant as y increases. Moving to the 100% take-up economy, search effort decreases for each y. Notice, however, that it monotonically increases, even in the range 7 Note, in this figure, we have omitted the lower range of productivity where the unemployed do not collect benefits. In this range search effort is constant, at the same level as the other non-collectors in the baseline economy.

29

of y where the unemployed were previously not collecting benefits. The latter fact explains why vacancy creation increases in the counterfactual. Now, firms are relatively more likely to match with a higher productivity worker. This increases the expected value of a filled vacancy, and free-entry implies vacancies must increase. 0.74 0.72 0.7

Search effort

0.68 0.66 0.64 0.62 0.6

Baseline economy 100% Take−up economy

0.58

0

5

10

15 Productivity, y

20

25

30

Figure 5: Search effort comparison: baseline vs. 100% take-up

5.1

Welfare

To further understand the implications of the counterfactual move to a 100% take-up economy, we also analyze how it affects welfare. In this comparison, we use the following welfare function: Z W = Y

n u1 (y)h(z1 (y), 1 − s1 (y)) + u2 (y)h(z2 (y), 1 − s2 (y)) + u3 (y)h(z3 (y), 1 − s3 (y)) + o e1 (y)h(w1 (y), 1 − sw ) + e3 (y)h(w3 (y), 1 − sw ) dy − (u1 + u2 )θ1 k − u3 θ3 k (30)

Total welfare is the sum of flow utility among the unemployed and employed at each y, net of the total vacancy creation costs.

30

Table 4: Welfare Comparison Welfare component Baseline Model Unemployed flow utility −0.0186 Employed flow utility 0.4318 Vacancy creation costs 0.1984 Total Welfare 0.2148

100% Take-up Model −0.0063 0.7999 0.2457 0.5479

To measure the welfare gain in consumption equivalent terms, we use exp [r(WC − WB )]− 1, where WC denotes the total welfare from equation (30) for the 100% take-up economy, and WB for the baseline economy. The numbers in Table 4 imply a welfare gain of 0.33% in consumption equivalent terms. While there exists some gain in the flow utility of the unemployed in a 100% take-up economy, these are relatively small, Table 4 indicates that the majority of the welfare gains occur in the flow utility to employed workers. Again, this occurs via two channels. First, the employment rate is higher in the 100% take-up economy. Second, the change in the composition of employment implies more employment at higher levels of productivity (and thus higher wages). Based on these welfare calculations, the experience rating feature of UI finance in our baseline economy implies an “externality” relative to the 100% take-up economy. These taxes create incentives for relatively high productivity workers to forgo the government UI scheme in favor of the market scheme. Removing the experience rating feature changes these incentives and all unemployed workers collect benefits. Then, the maximum benefit feature in the current U.S. system “corrects” the externality. It adds a constant amount of consumption to the relatively high productivity unemployed. This implies an increasing marginal gain to employment, causing search effort to increase faster with productivity. Since the distribution of employed workers across y is endogenously determined, this increase in the slope of s with respect to y increases the rate at which firms match with high productivity workers. In the baseline economy, workers do not internalize this equilibrium effect when deciding whether 31

or not to collect UI benefits.

8

The results regarding the move to a 100% take-up rate economy are not particularly dependent on our modelling of the take-up decision. That is, these same results would obtain even in a model with a simple utility cost to applying for benefits. What matters for these results is that higher wage (productivity) workers are the ones not collecting benefits they are eligible for, and that they are bound by a maximum benefit amount when they do collect (a feature of the current U.S. system). Having unemployed consumption a constant fraction of employed consumption (for non-collectors) represents the other key assumption for these results. It does not particularly matter what the fraction is, just that it remains constant, even as the wage increases. When these workers start collecting benefits, this constant fraction no longer obtains, since the maximum benefit is constant.

6

Conclusion We develop a model to explain unemployment insurance take-up rates with endogenous

application costs. The model is calibrated to U.S. data, and performs well matching observed take-up rates, which we estimate from CPS data. Specifically, we find the endogenous mechanism, driven by variable firm vacancy advertising, represents a plausible explanation for take-up rates below 100%. In this economy, a counterfactual move to an economy with no experience rating implies a 100% take-up rate. In the counterfactual economy, benefit expenditures increase, but the unemployment rate and average duration of unemployment decrease, and welfare increases. These effects occur as the composition of employment is endogenously determined, and a 100% take-up rate implies firms match with higher productivity workers at a faster rate.

8

Of course, our analysis ignores the effects of experience rating on firm separation decisions as in Feldstein (1976). Including such affects represents an interesting direction for future research.

32

References Albrecht, J., Vroman, S., 2005. Equilibrium search with time-varying unemployment benefits. The Economic Journal 115, 631–648. Anderson, P., Meyer, B., 1997. Unemployment insurance takeup rates and the after-tax value of benefits. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 913–937. Blank, R., Card, D., 1991. Recent trends in insured and unisured unemployment: Is there an explanation? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 1157–1189. Davidson, C., Woodbury, S., 1998. The optimal dole with risk aversion and job destruction. Working paper, Michigan State University. Feldstein, M., 1976. Temporary layoffs in the theory of unemployment. Journal of Political Economy 84, 937–958. Fredriksson, P., Holmund, B., 2001. Optimal unemployment insurance in search equilibrium. Journal of Labor Economics 19, 370–399. Gruber, J., 1997. The consumption smoothing benefits of unemployment insurance. The American Economic Review 87, 192–205. Hansen, G., Imrohoroglu, A., 1992. The role of unemployment insurance in an economy with liquidity constraints and moral hazard. Journal of Political Economy 100, 118–142. Pissarides, C. A., 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Shimer, R., 2005. The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies. American Economic Review 95, 25–49. Topel, R. H., 1983. On layoffs and unemployment insurance. American Economic Review 83, 541–559. 33

Wang, C., Williamson, S., 2002. Moral hazard, optimal unemployment insurance, and experience rating. Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 1337–1371.

34

Unemployment Insurance Take-up Rates in an ...

May 16, 2013 - e-mail), telephone, employer filed claim, and internet claim. ..... basic replacement rate; B the maximum benefit level; and δ, the arrival rate of ...

323KB Sizes 0 Downloads 198 Views

Recommend Documents

Unemployment Insurance Take-up Rates in an ...
May 16, 2013 - Firms post vacancies and search/advertise for workers to fill them. .... e-mail), telephone, employer filed claim, and internet claim. .... and in times of high unemployment, eligibility may be extended through the Federal-State.

Regional Unemployment Rates in an Agglomeration ...
Web supplement file for this work is available on the following Web site: .... labor, Ai is the matching efficiency, and Li is the labor force, with the subscript i ...

Efficient Unemployment Insurance
Nov 4, 2010 - In absence of UI: 1. Risk-averse workers seek lower wage jobs with less unemployment. ... Models with optimal UI in the presence of asymmetric information ... production technology f : (0, ∞) → (0, ∞) requires one worker and.

Insurance Rates-CAPS.pdf
Coverage: EE Only EE+Spouse EE+Children EE+Family Coverage: EE Only EE+Spouse EE+Children EE+Family. Medical 668.00 1,336.00 1,016.00 1,570.00 ...

Risk-based Selection in Unemployment Insurance: Evidence ... - LSE
Sep 4, 2017 - even when adverse selection is present, the government may do ... We first exploit Swedish employment protection regulation to isolate exogenous variation in .... This means that workers get divided into groups, defined by ...

Unemployment Insurance and Labor Reallocation!
Sorbonne. Email: franck.malherbet@uni%bocconi.it, Address: Via Salasco 5, 20136 Milano,. Italy. ..... mass of the unemployed workers or the mass of vacant jobs is nil. The instan% .... will choose the sector in which they will be best off.

Risk-based Selection in Unemployment Insurance: Evidence ... - LSE
Sep 4, 2017 - over the unemployment spell or over the business cyles. .... compare their unemployment risk to infra-marginal buyers of the same insurance plan. ...... affecting UI contracts used in the positive correlation test of Section 3.2.

Unemployment Insurance and Cultural Transmission
An online appendix contains all the proofs which are not included in the .... benefits to which they are not entitled, I just run a probit regression where 1 stands for ... The business cycle coeffi cient is negative and significant. This implies ...

The Role of Caseworkers in Unemployment Insurance
of unemployment benefits, the contribution period extends up to 22 months. ...... (2010b): “Unemployed and their Caseworkers: Should they be friends or foes?

Optimal Life Cycle Unemployment Insurance
incentive to search for a job as well their ability to cope with unemployment risk ... Income and Program Participation (SIPP) to analyze how the unemployment ...

EDD Announces Online, Mobile Unemployment Insurance Services
Jun 4, 2015 - the new UI Online MobileSM site, a website that is optimized for use on smartphones and tablet computers. Claimants will be able to access UI.

Unintended Consequences of Unemployment Insurance
20% for Social Security and 8% towards workers' seniority account (FGTS). Firing costs are also ... According to several media reports, President. 3 ... between a firm and a worker and contains information on monthly wage, age, gen- der, race ...

Unemployment insurance with hidden savings
Furthermore, Kocherlakota [9] shows that when the disutility function is linear, the agent's problem is severely non-convex and the first-order condition cannot be.

Optimal Life Cycle Unemployment Insurance
whose insightful suggestions have contributed to significantly improving the paper. ..... full analysis of the extended model is in the Online Appendix, where we ..... change over the business cycle due to changing composition in the pool of the ...

Unemployment Insurance and Workers' Mobility
contrast, all agents, whether employed or not, have the same probability of being ... creases the labour supply in the risky sector, firms get matched with a worker ...

Optimal Unemployment Insurance Hugo A. Hopenhayn
Sep 20, 2007 - ... contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed ..... lem would be purely one of efficient risk sharing in which the princi- ...... may be required to first logon via your library web site to access JSTOR.

Unemployment Insurance Fraud and Optimal Monitoring - University of ...
participants at the Workshop on Macroeconomic Applications of Dynamic Games and ... date because the unemployed worker's pre-monitoring consumption is ...

Results on EDD efforts to clear Unemployment Insurance processing ...
Oct 2, 2013 - new internal system is fully functional and has provided automation to help our staff clear the backlog. The backlog included certifications for ...

Worker Turnover and Unemployment Insurance Online ...
Mar 25, 2017 - Otherwise, the expected productivity in the first period amounts to πy, and match quality is learned at the beginning of the second period. If it turns out to be bad, the match is terminated and the worker produces z at home. Otherwis