JOURNAL

OF ECONOMIC

52, 423-432 (1990)

THEORY

uilibrium

Cycling MS

Department

with

Small

BENHABIB

of Economics, New York Unioersity, New York, New York 10003 AND

Department

of

Economics, Nortk2%resrevnUniwrsity, Illinois 60208

Evanston.

Received July 21, 1989; revised March 5, 1990

A misinterpretation of turnpike theorems suggests that persistent cyclic behavior in optimal growth models is only possible with large discount rates. This paper shows that for any positive discount rate there exists a large family of standard Cobb-Douglas technologies with three sectors which have optimal growth paths of persistent cycles. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: 020, 023, 100. % 1990 Academic Press. Inc.

The possibility of persistent cycles in intertemporal equiidbrium mo with or without infinitely lived agents, has already been establi Nevertheless, the misperception exists that sus;h cycles are incompatible with long-lived agents and low discount rates.’ This in part is due to a misinterpretation of turnpike theorems, which, in optimal growth contexts, state that given a technology and the preference of an infinitely lived rep sentative agent, there exists a suficiently low discount rate for which path converges to a steady state. The recent elegant results *This research was conducted while the second author was at the AT&T Bell Laboratories. We thank the C.V. Starr Center at New York University for research facilities and technical assistance. We are also indebted to Doug Shuman for technacai assistance and computer work. ] See for example Woodford [12]. 0022-0531190 $3.00 Copqrighi c, 1990 by Academic Press. !nc. Ail rl@h!s of reproduction 1x1 any lwm reserved

424

BENHABIB AND RUSTICHINI

Boldrin and Montrucchio [4] in discrete time and Montrucchio [9] in continuous time, on the other hand, show that any differentiable difference equation (differential equation, in continuous time) can be shown to correspond to the policy function of some well-behaved concave dynamic program with a sufficiently large discount rate. Paradoxically, these results may also have contributed to the misperception that a large amount of discounting is necessary to obtain cyclic trajectories. The early work of Cass and Shell [6] and Brock and Scheinkman [S], however, makes it clear that there is a trade-off between the level of discounting and the “curvature” of preferences plus technology in establishing turnpike theorems. The counterpart of the turnpike theorems can also be established by exploiting this trade-off: for any given positive discount rate there exists a “large” family of “nice” technologies that can generate persistent cycles as optimal growth paths. This paper, generalizing the method by which Benhabib and Nishimura [3] constructed examples of persistent cycles, formally establishes this result in Theorem 1 below. What is meant by “large” families is made precise. “Nice” technologies refer to classical Cobb-Douglas production functions with constant returns to scale and non-joint production. We should note that an issue not addressed in Boldrin and Montrucchio [4] and Montrucchio [9] is whether the concave programs that can generate cyclic or chaotic trajectories are compatible with constant returns to scale and non-joint production functions.’ In the last section we discuss how the results can be extended via perturbation to non-linear utility functions and non-constant returns to scale. We also note that the results of this paper can easily be extended to discrete time models (like the one in Benhabib and Nishimura [2]) by using similar methods.

2. CYCLES IN NEOCLASSICAL GROWTH We shall consider three Cobb-Douglas y,=b,

fj k?,

production i=o,

1, 2,

MODELS

functions, defined as (1)

j=O

2 olji= 1

(constant returns),

(2)

j=O

2 Also, the situation is more complicated under different formulations: cycles can obtain in models with heterogeneous agents (see, e.g., Becker and Foias [l]) or when delays are present (e.g., Rustichini [lo]), or stability can obtain in some special cases (e.g., Scheinkman 111)).

EQUILIBRIUM

425

CYCLING

where y, is the consumption good; y,, y2 are the capital goods; & is the labor input to the ith good; kji is the jth input to the ith good. VJe refer ts this family of production functions as a three sector Cobb--Douglas technology. Maximizing yO, subject to y,, y2 given, and to i

i

koi= 1,

kji=kj,

i==O

i=O

yields yo=z(yl, yZ, k,, kz, 1). We rewrite this asy,=c= T(y,, yz,kl, kzf, where the lower case letters indicate per capita values. T d&nes the efficiency frontier. We can now define an Q Max subject to

!-0 OcIT(.vl, y2, k,, kz) ~-‘~-~“bjt, Ii;= yi-

gk,,

i = B, 2;

(4)

k,(O): k,(O) given.

The maximization is with respect to the paths yk and yZ, where ;~~(a)3 0, i= 1,2, and T(yr, y2, k,, k2) 3 0. Here r - g is the discount rate and g is the depreciation rate plus the population growth rate; we assume Y- g > 0. Simple assumptions assure that (k,, k2) will be bounded. We now collect some preliminary results which will be used in the proof of the main theorem. The proof itself will result from an application of HopE’s bifurcation rem. For a statement and discussion of this t and m From the Pontryagin Maximum Principle the necessary conditions f5r

ki= yi-

gki

jJi= -Tk,+rpj.

(61 t,‘7: !

Let TkP= wi > 0, T-+.,= -qi < 0. Under mild conditions, this problem has a steady state (s.s.), denoted by (k*, y*). tion, a unique interior steady state will exist. In the neighborhood of the s.s. we will assume (it will be true for our technology) that T-V,< 0 (T strictly concave in y, and also in k (not jointly)). Also, Max, H implies q, = -T,; = pi: since the maximum is interior. Furthermore, - TJy, k) = p, is invertible so that y = y(k, p) (outputs are ~~~~ue~~ determines by factors and relative prices). Furthermore, Tk = G(y(k, p), kj = wjk, p). (Since

426

BENHABIB

factor prices are determined above as

AND

RUSTICHlNI

by (k, p)). We therefore rewrite (6) and (7) I;-=Akp)-gk

(6’)

@= -w(k, p) + rp.

(7’)

We now linearize the system given by (6’) and (7’) around the steady state. Let

be the input coefficient matrix with aij the ith input to thejth good, aoj the labor input to thejth good, ai, the ith input to consumption good. At the steady state,

[WO> WI

a00 a., I 1

(price = cost conditions)

= II12 PI

A

ao.

(full employment Differentiating we get

(9) and substituting [ay/ak]=

conditions).

(8) (9)

for c from one of the equations in (9),

[A -(a.o~ao.)/a,]-i,

(10)

Here we use the fact that input coefficients remain fixed, since p is fixed. Similarly, using Shepards’ lemma, [i3w/dp]‘=

[A-

[a.,~a,.)/a,]-‘=

[dy/dk].

where ’ denotes transposition. Note that aw/dk=O, as is known from the factor price equalization literature. Let B= [a., .ao,)/aoo]. Then linearizing around the steady state we derive J=

B-‘-gZ 0

wm -(By’+rZ

where Z is the identity matrix. Roots -(B)‘-’ + rZ. To apply Hopf’s Theorem, we have to construct a Cobb-Douglas technology [I-(B’)-’ + rl]. B-’ is derived from the

I’

of J are roots of B-l-

(11) gZ,

show that for any r > g, we can with pure imaginary roots for input coefficient matrix implied

EQUILIBRIUM

427

CYCLING

by r via the non-substitution theorem. We first show that for any pair given by r and the steady state per unit coefficient matrix, we can define a unique Cobb-Douglas technology. More precisely, once we define

we have the following lemma. (For any matrix A we denote by 1, the dominant eigenvalue of A, and by A 3 0 the component-wise inequality aG 3 0 for every i and j.) LEMMA 1. For any given r > 0 and steady state per unit input matrix a such that vi, < 1, there exist a unique set of S.S. prices po, p and a unique Cobb-Doaglglas technology associated with it. Furthermore, given r > g, the steady state is unique.

Braof of Lemma 1. Since at the S.S. wi = rpi, i = I, 2, setting w0 = I we have p = ao. + rpA, and therefore p = a, [I- rA ] -I. Also p. = a,* + rpa .*) assuming of course [I- rA] -I > 0, or equivalently that r/Z, < 1: this condition will have to be satisfied in our construction of the matrix A. We have therefore that, for any pair (Y, A), a vector p of prices and a vector u’ of factor costs are determined. We now proceed to determine the coefficients (bk, ayii) in the production functions:

From cost minimization

we derive

wOaQi=~lj=E!2;

“oa,,~2i=

wlali

w2azi

Mli

@Oi 1 -

clgi-

qj

and therefore, solving for IX?,

Clearly aoi, ali, aoi + aIi are all in the interval (0, 1). From the steady state condition y = gk we now determine the vector (hi), i = 0, 1; 2. This concludes the proof of Lemma 1. Lemma 1 shows that we can completely parametrize our economy by the triple ((v, A), g), where a has to satisfy some rest~~ct~~ns (which will be discussed soon B.

428

BENHABIB

AND

RUSTICHINI

THEOREM 1. For every positive discount rate 6* = r - g> 0 and every representative agent with linear instantaneous utility function, there exists an eight-parameter family of 3-sector Cobb-Douglas technologies (with nonjoint production and constant returns to scale (CRS)), such that for every open neighborhood N of S*, and any choice of technology from the above family and some 6 EN, the associated optimal growth problem has nonconstant cycles in stocks, prices and outputs. The Cobb-Douglas economies which satisfy this condition are determined by a set of 8 parameters, which contains an open set.

Remark 1. It is known that for economies with one capital good there can be no cycles, and at least three capital goods are necessary in our construction. For economies with a larger number of capital goods the existence of periodic solutions is an obvious consequence of this result. In those cases the Cobb-Douglas technologies giving rise to cycles would constitute a family of more than eight parameters. Remark 2. For any given 6, the family of eight parameters describes the economy for which the matrix J, defined in (11) above, has purely imaginary roots. The theorem states that for any open set (in the nine parameter space) around this economy there exists an economy with periodic cycles, In fact, more can be said. Recall that (see Chow and Hale [7]) a Hopf bifurcation can be critical, subcritical, or supercritical. In a critical bifurcation we have a continuum of periodic cycles at the bifurcation point: for any initial condition the optimal trajectory is periodic, provided the feasibility constraints are satisfied. The cycles disappear for any other value of the parameters. A critical bifurcation is a very exceptional case: this situation occurs, for instance, if the differential equation system (the system (6’), (7’), m our case) is linear. Such critical bifurcations can be ruled out provided the derivative of a certain bifurcation function, evaluated at the bifurcation point, is non-zero. (See Golubitsky and Schaeffer [IS, Theorem 3.21.) If the bifurcation is not critical, then the proof of the theorem shows that there exists an open set, in the nine dimensional parameter space, of economies with periodic cycles. Notice that in our case any of the eight parameters can be chosen to be a bifurcation parameter; and we only need the bifurcation to be non-critical with respect to one of them. Proof of Theorem 1. As we mentioned in the introduction, the theorem will follow from the Hopf Bifurcation Theorem. In terms of the notation used above, we need to prove that we can determine a matrix a such that the corresponding matrix - (B’) - ’ + rl has a pair of purely imaginary non zero roots. Denote B-

[A-a.o~ao./aool

(13)

EQUILIBRIUM

429

CYCLING

and define a subset of the B matrices, for any given r > 0, as

where bi, are the elements of the inverse of - -’ + rB has a pair of pure imaginary roots. Note that, because of Eqs. (12), (13), for every vector ( there is a uniquely determined associated matrix A and vice claim that for any Y> 0 there exists a vect (r) and (ii) there exists a Cobb ecall first that for any (B, a.,, a,. , aoo) the matrix and a are related by a02

a0, %+-

--I with elements bii

adO1 am

-

671 Fz.+e.ma- a2, sol D aoo

=b6,,622-61262,* In view of Lemma I, we now only nee t we can choose the elements b, of B and aoo, a,, a0 so tha foollowing conditions are satisfied: (I ) (2) (3) (4)

A is non-negative; the row sums of 2 are less than or equal to one; A,r< 1; 6,, + r;,, = 2r, (b,, - I;,,)’ - 46;,,1;,, b-0.

The following (i)

simple three step procedure will prove our claim.

Choose 6,, = b, 6,, = 2r - b, with b any number in

(ii) Choose b,,, 6,, such that sign b,, = -sign 6,!; let and lb211 >&2. Note that condition

(4) is satisfied for any choice of 6, described above.

(iii) Any choice of a 10, a20, am such that aIOa02/a00> 612/O, an al > 0 for i, j = 0, 1, 2, will ensure that condition (1) is satisfied. Now no that for aij= 0, i, j= 0, 1,2, the inequality (3) is satisfied if 2r2 -c D. If satisfies this condition, a choice of ratios aiOaO,,/amsmall enough will ensure that condition 642/52/?-13

(3) and condition

(2) above are satisfied.

430

BENHABIB AND RUSTICHINI

To summarize: inequalities Otb<2r,

1!&<0,

any choice of the parameters which satisfy the system of 6,>0

for qf21,

aieUoj/aoo
u,>O,

i,j=O,

1,2;

aloao21aoo > b2/D, D > 2r2 for a properly chosen E, will imply that conditions (1) to (4) above are satisfied. The above system will be satisfied for a non-empty open set of parameters. One last remark now concludes the proof of Theorem 1. The “positive speed” crossing condition is proved as in Benhabib and Nishimura [13, A41.

3. NON-LINEAR

UTILITY

One last misconception might be left: that the Hopf bifurcation described above depends crucially on linear utility or on the constant returns to scale condition. We now proceed to show that this is not the case. In the optimal growth problem (4) above replace the instantaneous utility of the representative consumer with a neoclassical utility function U (U is concave and C2 in the interior of the positive real line). The space of utility functions is endowed with the C2 topology. The Maximum Principle now gives k= y-gk 4= -U’(T)

(14) T,+rq

(15)

U’(T) T,=q,

(16)

where as above c = T( y, k). Denoting

we may rewrite Eq. (15) as 4 = -U’(T)(T, we derive

+ rp), differentiating

cj = U”(T) tp + U’$.

Substituting

for I!, and using Eq. (15) we derive

U”(T,y,+T,)(y-qk)+[U”T,y,+U’]p=U’(-w+rp).

Eq. (16) (18)

EQUILXBRIUM CYCLING

436

enoting (T, yk + T,)( y - gk) E Q, U”TY yp + U’ s R we derive U” P= --w+rp+u’

R

i

I+ (jrJl,,~l)R [w-q?]

-

U’ U’ $ U”R :i

= -w + rp + (U”/U’) S(y, k).

(19)

From Eq. (17) we can write the optimal investment as a function of p and k, and we are left with the two equations

P =

-w(y(k

PI,

P) + rp + (u’flW

KvW,

pi

k-j.

(19)

Note that (19) is a perturbation of (7’). When U”/U’ is small, the perturbation is small. We now show that for a perturbation small enough the Kopf bifurcation is preserved. Denote xU - (k,, p u) as the steady state corresponding to any U. Let E- -U”/U’, evaluated at the steady state consumption, and denote by J. the vector of parameters used in Lemma 2 above. Linearization of the equations (14) and (19) gives a matrix E(i, xv, E) = C(l, xii) - &(I,

x,)),

where C(A., x0) is the J matrix in (11) above; note that the coeffkients of these matrices vary continuously in U. In the previous section we have seen that as A.varies between two values, i., and A,, say, one of the eigenvalues of C(A, x0) crosses the imaginary axis Now Rouche’s theorem yields the same conclusion for any neoclassical utility function, provided E is small enough. A similar argument shows that the Wopf bifurcation exists in t non-constant returns to scale (again, in the case of small deviations fr the bomoge~eity of degree one) that preserves the concavi problem.

REFERENCES 1. R. BECKER AND C. FOIAS, A characterization of Ramsey equilibrium, J. Con. Theory (19873, 173-184. 2. 5. BENHABIB AND K. NXSHIMURA, Competitive cycles, J. Ecoti. Theory 35 (19&S), 284-306. 3. J. BENHABIB AND K. NISHIMURA, The Hopf bifurcation and the existence and stability of closed orbits in multisector models of optimal economic growth, J. Econ. Theory 21 (19791, 421-444. 4. M. BOLDRIN AND L. MONTRUCCHIO, On the indeterminacy of capital accumulation paths, J. Econ. Theory 40 (1986), 26-39. 5. W. BROCK AND 3. A. SCHEINKMAN, Global asymptotic stability of optimal control systems with applications to the theory of economic growth, J. &on. Theqv 12 (1976), 164-190.

432

BENHABIB AND RUSTICHINI

6. D. CASS AND K. SHELL, The structure and stability of competitive dynamical systems, J. Econ. Theory 12 (1976), 31-70. 7. S. N. CHOW AND J. K. HALE, “Methods of Bifurcation Theory,” Springer-Verlag, Berlin/ New York, 1982. 8. M. GOLUBITSKY AND D. J. SCHAEZFFER, “Singularities and Groups in Bifurcation Theory,” Vol. 1, Springer-Verlag, Berlin/New York, 1985. 9. L. MONTRUCCHIO, Dynamical systems that solve continuous time concave optimization problems: Anything goes, University of Torino, preprint, 1988. 10. A. RUSTICHINI, Hopf bifurcation for functional differential equations of mixed type, J. Dynam. Differential Equations 1 (1989), 145-177. 11. J. SCHEINKMAN, Stability of separable Hamiltonians and investment theory, Reo. Econ. Stud. 45 (1978), 559-570. 12. M. WOODFORD, Imperfect financial intermediation and complex dynamics, in “Chaos, Sunspots and Nonlinearity,” (W. B arnett, J. Geweke, and K. Shell, Eds.), Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, UK, 1987.

uilibrium Cycling with Small

This in part is due to a mis- ... program with a sufficiently large discount rate. .... be the input coefficient matrix with aij the ith input to thejth good, aoj the.

564KB Sizes 0 Downloads 244 Views

Recommend Documents

Cycling Etiquette
Call “approaching rider” as you get close. n. Slow a bit to allow buffer space; communicate “rider up, slowing” to your group; groups must only pass as a single ...

November 27th 2016 - USA Cycling
Nov 27, 2016 - Race held under USA Cycling Event Permit 2016-3288. Host Club Slimenundgrossen supports KCA and will donate. $2.00 of every entry fee.

BEGINNING RACER PROGRAM - USA Cycling
novice riders seeking to learn. This series is a fund-raiser for the GS Andiamo Junior Cycling. Development Program, which is dedicated to building the next ...

Sutton cycling guide.pdf
Waddon. The. Wrythe. Beddington. Hackbridge. Beddington. Corner. Banstead. Downs. Belmont. East. Ewell. Carshalton. Beeches. SUTTON. Cheam Nonsuch.

BEGINNING RACER PROGRAM - USA Cycling
Location: Redlands Sports Complex, 1790 N Dearborn St. Redlands, CA 92374 https://www.google.com/maps/place/Redlands+Sports+Complex/@34.0789524 ...

cambridge cycling club - Walden Velo
Membership No. 1st claim club ... Via PayPal to [email protected]. 3. OR send ... Website support Newsletter Articles ... Names, telephone numbers and e-mail addresses may be given to other members of the club. Tick this.

cambridge cycling club - Walden Velo
Walden Velo application for membership. Name. Address. Telephone. E Mail. Date of Birth ... Please enter the amount enclosed(or sent to our account). FIRST.

Cycling Romania_cycling development_Sofia_23Mar_v2.pdf ...
Retrying... Cycling Romania_cycling development_Sofia_23Mar_v2.pdf. Cycling Romania_cycling development_Sofia_23Mar_v2.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with.Missing:

cambridge cycling club - Walden Velo
Walden Velo application for membership. Name. Address. Telephone. E Mail. Date of Birth. Postcode ... Then post membership form to. Claire Powell 9 Fair ...

lW@UILIBRIUM pK* OF CARBAZOLE STUDIED BY ...
We have, therefore, searched for an alternative acid-base reaction where the reverse reaction rate is appreciable compared with the forward reaction rate and, moreover, can be changed systematically by the addition of the acid form of the added base.

November 27th 2016 - USA Cycling
Nov 27, 2016 - Course Open for Warm Up 9:00 am – 10:15am. Men Masters 40+ ... More series information available at www.facebook.com/kccoookiecross.

Cycling Lake Ginninderra.pdf
Sign in. Loading… Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying.

Cycling development in Serbia.pdf
Sign in. Loading… Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect ...

Motor Cycling 1957.pdf
Sign in. Page. 1. /. 3. Loading… Page 1 of 3. Page 1 of 3. Page 2 of 3. Page 2 of 3. Page 3 of 3. Page 3 of 3. Motor Cycling 1957.pdf. Motor Cycling 1957.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying Motor Cycling 1957.pdf. Page 1 o

ASA Adjudication on Cycling Scotland - Advertising Standards ...
Jan 31, 2014 - ASA Adjudication on Cycling Scotland - Advertising Standards Authority.pdf. ASA Adjudication on Cycling Scotland - Advertising Standards ...

Park County Youth Cycling Application
Do you take any medications which could affect your ability to ride safely? ❑Yes | ❑No. Do you have any medical conditions which could affect your riding skills? ❑Yes | ❑No. Details: HEALTH DISCLOSURE. Contact's Name: Relationship: Phone Numb

MINIMAL SUBMANIFOLDS WITH SMALL TOTAL ...
Keomkyo Seo. Abstract. Let M be an n-dimensional complete minimal submanifold in Rnюp. Lei Ni proved that if M has sufficiently small total scalar curvature, ...

Cycling Infrastructure Design Dept Transport Oct 08(1).pdf ...
Cycling Infrastructure Design Dept Transport Oct 08(1).pdf. Cycling Infrastructure Design Dept Transport Oct 08(1).pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In.