Testing Revealed Preferences for Homotheticity with Two-Good Experiments: Supplementary Material Jan Heufer



∗ TU Dortmund University, Department of Economics and Social Science, 44221 Dortmund, Germany. E-mail: [email protected]. Tel.: +49 231 755-7223. Fax: +49 231 755-3027.

1

1

An Illustration of the Homothetic Efficiency Index

The homothetic efficiency index in the paper is defined as   HE = min 1, min {mij } , i,j∈{1,...,n}

where

pi zj pj zi . wi wj The observation-wise partial index is defined as   ˜ HE(i) = min 1, min {mij } . mij =

j∈{1,...,n}

The index is based on the fact that homotheticity implies that income expansion paths are rays through the origin. That implies that if z2 is demanded when facing the budget B(p2 , w2 ), then the demand on the budget B(p2 , s w2 ), with s ∈ R+ , is s z2 . Then if z1 ∈ B(p2 , s w2 ), z1 must not be preferred to s z2 . Figure 1 illustrates the idea. Given that z2 is demanded on B(p2 , w2 ), 2 1 ([p z ]/w2 )z2 is demanded on B(p2 , ([p2 z1 ]/w2 )w2 ) = B(p2 , p2 z1 ). Thus, if the consumer had homothetic preferences, ([p2 z1 ]/w2 )z2 would give at least the same utility as z1 . But at prices p1 , where z1 was demanded at expenditure w1 , ([p2 z1 ]/w2 )z2 was  also affordable;  in fact, the consumer could have purchased it at expenditure (p2 z1 )/w2 p1 z2 < w1 .

2

The Power of a Test

Bronars (1987) suggested a Monte Carlo approach to determine the power the test has against random behaviour. The approximate power of the test is the percentage of random choices which violated GARP. For the simple case of just two observation, Bronars showed analytically that the probability of a violation of GARP, given random choice, is highest when two intersecting budgets are nearly parallel such that the length (or area) of a budget lying inside the other budget is large relative to the rest of the budget. Knowing the corresponding conditions for HARP would make it easier for researchers to design powerful budget combinations. The following proposition will be helpful: Proposition 1. The following conditions are equivalent: (1) The set {(zi , pi , wi )}ni=1 satisfies HARP; (2) The set {(z, p, w) : τ ≥ 0 and [z = τ zi , p = pi , w = τ wi ] for some i ∈ {0, 1, . . . , n}} satisfies GARP. Proof of Proposition 1. Generate a new observation (ˆ zi , p ˆ i , w) ˆ = (τ zi , pi , τ wi ) for some τ > 0. 2

y

z1

z2 

p2 z1 w2



z2 x

(a) y

z1  h 2 1 i h 1 2 i p z B p1 , pwz2 w1

z2

x

(b)

Figure 1: Illustration of the homothetic efficiency index.

3

y

Y

L2 L1

X1

X2

x

Figure 2: The probability of observing a violation of HARP.

If τ ≥ ti,j , then τ zi H 0 zj . Using Eq. (1) in the paper, this implies that ti,j zi and therefore τ zi is revealed preferred to zj via a chain of bundles: k k,` k ` m,j m ti,k zi R z R zj for some sequence of indices k, `, . . . , m.  z , t z R z , . . ., t   zi (GARP) for all Thus not zj P 0 ti,j zi (HARP) is equivalent to not zj P 0ˆ ˆ zi = τ zi with τ > ti,j .    If τ < ti,j , then not τ zi H 0 zj and not ˆ zi R zj . Thus neither HARP nor GARP impose a condition on the relation between ˆ zi and zj . Proposition 1 implies that a set of budgets which is powerful for a GARP test will also be powerful for a test for homotheticity. Additionally, the budgets for a HARP test do not even have to intersect; it is sufficient for the budgets to have similar slopes. Figure 2 illustrates this: Conditional on the observation on the budget with the steepest slope, the probability of a violation of HARP, given random choice, will be higher when this budget is paired with another budget with a similar slope. This is because homotheticity implies that the choice on the other budgets is made to the lower right side of the indicated expansion line, and the ratio ||Li Y ||/||Li Xi || decreases as the slope decreases.

3 3.1

More Details on the Data Analysis Robustness Check for Parametric Estimations

Andreoni and Miller (2002) excluded three subjects from the parametric analysis in which they estimated a CES utility function. These subjects had AEIs below the 95% threshold. They found that 62 of the 142 subjects in the sessions with eight budgets strongly fitted a prototypical utility function. The remainder was used for the estimation, except for the three subjects with low efficiency (i.e., 77 subjects from the eight budgets sessions where used). As all subjects

4

who strongly fit a prototypical utility function satisfy PHARP, this means that 48 out of 77 subjects (= 61.04%) which were used for the estimation violate PHARP. However, most of them have rather high levels of homothetic efficiency, as indicated in Figure 1.(a) in the main part of the paper.

3.2

Gender Differences

Table 1 shows the consistency with WGARP and PHARP in Andreoni and Vesterlund’s (2001; also Andreoni and Miller 2002) data by gender of subjects. Note that the PHARP implies but is not implied by the WGARP. It is interesting to note that, at the 5% significance level, male subjects are significantly less likely than female subjects to violate the PHARP (χ2 = 5.175, p = 0.0229), but not WGARP (χ2 = 2.782, p = 0.0953). Andreoni and Vesterlund’s finding that male subjects are more price sensitive than women might explain this result to some extent. Note that homotheticity implies that the slope of rays through the origin and a demand bundle increases in the price ratio. Suppose two subjects try to maximise well behaved homothetic utility functions, but make minor errors in specifying their demand. Furthermore, suppose that the first subject mostly specifies demand near the 45◦ line (i.e., she is not price sensitive), while the second subject specifies demand near one of the two axes for extreme price ratios and around the 45◦ line for price ratios near 1. Then the slope of the rays are all similar for the first subject, but they can be quite different for the second subject. While in both cases minor errors can lead to a violation of HARP, this is more likely to happen to the first subject. Thus, some subjects may be somewhat more ‘violation-prone’ than others. The fact that female subject violate WGARP more frequently than male subjects alone cannot explain the difference in the PHARP-violations, as a χ2 test shows that the difference in WGARP-violations is not significant. Furthermore, if female subjects had homothetic preferences and would only make minor errors in specifying demand, this would show in the distribution of the homothetic efficiency index, which then should be close to one for female subjects. This is not the case: Figure 3 shows the distribution of the HE of those subjects who violate PHARP. The distribution is quite similar for both genders, with more male subjects having a HE greater than .95 than female subjects. Two of the three subjects which were excluded in the parametric analysis because of their low efficiency level were female. Excluding the three subjects for the analysis of gender differences in homothetic efficiency changes the results slightly, but the difference remains significant (χ2 = 4.334, p = 0.0374).

5

pharp

sex

wgarp

all

satisfied

violated

satisfied

violated

male

67

28

89

6

95

female

24

23

40

7

47

91

51

129

13

142

all

Table 1: Subjects who satisfy PHARP and WGARP in the dictator game of Andreoni and Vesterlund (2001) and Andreoni and Miller (2002).

.25

.20

fraction

.15

.10

.05

HE .5

.6

.7

.8

.9

1

Figure 3: shows the distribution for male, for female subjects. Distribution of the homothetic efficiency index for subjects which violate PHARP.

3.3

Observation-Wise Homothetic Efficiency

˜ Figure 4 shows the distribution of the HE(i) in the experimental data and the random choice sets. It does show that the low HE values of both subjects and random choice sets are mainly due to a small fraction of individual choices. But it also reveals that in the FKM and CFGK data the majority of individual choices exhibit homothetic inefficiency. For the AM data, which only shows the ˜ for those subjects which violate PHARP, many values are 1 or close to HE(i) 1, but still many observations exhibit inefficiency. Also note that here many random choices have a HE level of 1.

6

.5

fraction

.4

.3

.2

.1

HE .1

.2

.3

.4

.5

.6

.7

.8

.9

1

.6

.7

.8

.9

1

.6

.7

.8

.9

1

(a)

fraction

.3

.2

.1

HE .1

.2

.3

.4

.5

(b)

fraction

.3

.2

.1

HE .1

.2

.3

.4

.5

(c)

Figure 4: shows the distribution for random choices, for actual subjects. Dis˜ tribution of the HE(i) and the Monte-Carlo results for the data of (a) Andreoni and Vesterlund (2001) and Andreoni and Miller (2002), (b) Fisman et al. (2007), (c) Choi et al. (2007a). The dashed lines indicates the HE which exceeds the HE of 95% of the data sets in the Monte Carlo simulation.

7

References Andreoni, J. and Miller, J. (2002): “Giving According to GARP: An Experimental Test of the Consistency of Preferences for Altruism,” Econometrica 70(2):737–753. Andreoni, J. and Vesterlund, L. (2001): “Which is the Fair Sex? Gender Differences in Altruism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(1):293–312. Bronars, S. G. (1987): “The Power of Nonparametric Tests of Preference Maximization,” Econometrica 55(3):693–698. Choi, S., Fisman, R., Gale, D., and Kariv, S. (2007a): “Consistency and Heterogeneity of Individual Behavior under Uncertainty,” American Economic Review 97(5):1921–1938. Fisman, R., Kariv, S., and Markovits, D. (2007): “Individual Preferences for Giving,” American Economic Review 97(5):1858–1876.

8

Supplementary Material

Jan Heufer ∗. *TU Dortmund University, Department of Economics and Social Science, 44221 Dortmund,. Germany. .... 3 More Details on the Data Analysis.

301KB Sizes 1 Downloads 380 Views

Recommend Documents

Supplementary Material
gaze fixation point is detected by an eye tracker. ∗indicates equal contribution. (a) Random ... 1) confirms quanti- tatively our intuition, that the location of the hands are in- deed important for learning about hand-object interactions. Based on

Supplementary Material - Arkivoc
General Papers. ARKIVOC 2015 (vii) S1-S13. Page S3. ©ARKAT-USA, Inc. δ /ppm. 1. H Assignment. 8.60 (brs, 1H). 5.35 (t, J = 7.3 Hz, 1H). 5.08 (t, J = 6.1 Hz, ...

Supplementary Material
By the definition of conjunctive pattern, since S does not satisfy pc, then S ... Then there exists at least one instance of p o in S: {I1,I2,...,Im},. I1 ∈ I(p c. 1 ,S),...,Im ∈ I(p c m,S), such that ∀t1 ∈. I1,..., ∀tm ∈ Im,t1 < t2 < ...

Supplementary Material
and Business Cycles Conference, the Bank of Canada 2014 Fellowship ..... CGH exhibited an upward trend in the frequency of sales that could explain why they find ...... 12Fox and Sayed (2016) use the IRI scanner dataset to document the ...

Supplementary Material
The data are provided a for 10 subsectors, which I aggregate up to three sectors as follows. ... CAN Canada ...... Structural change in an open economy. Journal ...

Supplementary Material
SVK Slovakia. CYP Cyprus. ITA. Italy. SVN Slovenia. CZE Czech Republic JPN Japan. SWE Sweden. DEU Germany. KOR South Korea. TUR Turkey. DNK Denmark. LTU Lithuania. TWN Taiwan. ESP Spain. LUX Luxembourg. USA United States. EST Estonia. LVA Latvia. RoW

Efficient Repeated Implementation: Supplementary Material
strategy bi except that at (ht,θt) it reports z + 1. Note from the definition of mechanism g∗ and the transition rules of R∗ that such a deviation at (ht,θt) does not ...

Supplementary Material for
Aug 3, 2016 - alternatives are “autocracy and risk-sharing” and “democracy and investment.” In other words, the .... whether seizing power. A coup is .... Our main sources are Galasso (1976), Stearns (2001), and Ortu (2005). References.

Supplementary Online Material
Branstetter, M.G. (2009) The ant genus Stenamma Westwood (Hymenoptera: Formicidae) redefined, with a description of a new genus Propodilobus. Zootaxa,.

Supplementary Material for
Fujitsu Research & Development Center Co., Ltd, Beijing, China. {wangzhengxiang,rjliu}@cn.fujitsu.com. Abstract. This supplementary material provides the ...

Electronic supplementary material
Jun 22, 2009 - ... of two Hill functions (a-b) with sufficiently distant midpoints is equivalent to the Hill function with the largest midpoint (c). Namely: Hill(x, K 1) · Hill(x, K 2) ≈ Hill(x, K 2) where K 1

Supplementary Material - HEC Montréal
... the ONS website: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/datasets-and-tables/index.html. .... sitivity of sales to the unemployment rate for independent stores and chains.

Supplementary Material for
Sep 25, 2015 - Using archived and field-collected worker bumble bees, we tested for temporal changes in the tongue ... (Niwot Ridge Long Term Ecological Research Site, 40°3.567'N, 105°37.000'W), and by. P. A. Byron (17) ... these transects did not

Supplementary Material for ``Observations on ...
Nov 19, 2017 - C.2 Steady State in a Perturbed Environment. In this subsection we formally adapt the definitions of a consistent signal profile and of a steady state to perturbed environments. Let f((1−ϵ)·σ+ϵ·λ) : OS → OS be the mapping bet

Supplementary Material Methods Tables
αF was added (25nM final) to exponentially growing MATa bar1Δ cells in YPD (OD600 ≈ 0.3) and the culture incubated for two hours at. 30oC. >95% G1 arrest, as indicated by cells with small buds (schmoo formation), was confirmed by microscopy. Cell

Supplementary Material: Adaptive Consensus ADMM ...
inequalities together. We conclude. (Bvk+1 − Bvk)T (λk+1 − λk) ≥ 0. (S3). 1.2. Proof of ..... matrix Di ∈ Rni×d with ni samples and d features using a standard ...

Price Selection – Supplementary Material
†Email: Departamento de Economia, Pontifıcia Universidade Católica do Rio de .... and-tables/index.html, the Statistics Canada's Consumer Price Research ...

Electronic Supplementary Material- Optimizing ...
3Data Science Laboratory, Institute for Scientific Interchange (ISI), Turin, Italy. 4Istituto ..... The entropy function introduced in Equation 1 of the main text evaluates the level of frag- ..... In the case of a deterministic spreading, we recover

Price Selection – Supplementary Material
trade and search frictions in the goods market. An equilibrium pins down a unique relative price distribution G(p−1 | S−1) but does not pin down price changes. This distribution is invariant to monetary shocks. Hence there is full monetary neutra

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL FOR “WEAK MONOTONICITY ...
This representation is convenient for domains with complete orders. 1 .... check dominant-strategy implementability of many classical social choice rules. In.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL FOR “WEAK MONOTONICITY ...
This representation is convenient for domains with complete orders. 1 ... v = (0,v2,0), v2 > 0, would want to deviate and misreport their type so as to get 3.

1 Supplementary online material: additional results ...
weakly higher winning frequencies for A and C in comparison to D. The corresponding tests reject the .... tives over the course of the experiment for PV elections.

Supplementary material for “Complementary inputs and ...
Aug 2, 2017 - statement of Theorem 2, and then complete the proof. ...... Jones, 1984), spaces of square-integrable functions (Harrison and Kreps, 1979; ...

Supplementary material to Mathematical models of ...
Mathematical models of the VEGF receptor and its role in cancer therapy ... restrict ourselves to the system of equations for the first moments (q1(t)) and for the ...