Economics Letters 67 (2000) 93–98 www.elsevier.com / locate / econbase

Supervision and effort in an intertemporal efficiency wage model: the role of the Solow condition ˜ Ricardo Faria* Joao School of Finance and Economics, University of Technology Sydney, PO Box 123, Broadway, Sydney, NSW 2007, Australia Received 30 June 1999; accepted 21 September 1999

Abstract The Solow condition is examined in an intertemporal model that blends the shirking and the turnover models of efficiency wages with managerial supervision. It is shown that the Solow condition does not hold when shirking and turnover costs are considered. The Solow condition can be a possible outcome when managerial productivity offsets shirking and turnover costs.  2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. Keywords: Labor–Management relations; Efficiency wages; Unemployment; Turnover JEL classification: J50; J41; J63; J64

1. Introduction Efficiency wage models have been developed to explain involuntary unemployment. Firms may benefit from paying their workers more than the market clearing wage, thus generating involuntary unemployment. Among the efficiency wage models, the shirking and the turnover cost models are the most well known and cited. According to the shirking model (e.g., Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984), firms pay efficiency wages in order to reduce workers’ shirking. High wages make the workers fear to lose their jobs if they are caught shirking. In the turnover cost model (e.g., Salop, 1979), workers who quit have to be replaced, which makes the firms incur search, recruitment and training costs. So firms have an incentive to minimize these costs. One such device is to set the wage at a level which inhibits turnover. One of the standard results of the efficient wage models is due to Solow (1979). The Solow condition, as it became known, states that an optimizing firm sets its wage at the level which the *Tel.: 161-2-9514-7782; fax: 161-2-9514-7711. E-mail address: [email protected] (J.R. Faria) 0165-1765 / 00 / $ – see front matter PII: S0165-1765( 99 )00239-6

 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved.

J.R. Faria / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 93 – 98

94

elasticity of work effort with respect to the real wage is unity. However, this result came under attack. Akerlof and Yellen (1986) point out that an effort-wage elasticity of unity is quite high. If this elasticity is never that high, ‘‘then there cannot be an equilibrium with unemployment in an efficiency wage model’’ (Akerlof and Yellen, 1986, p. 14). As the Solow model does not contemplate shirking, workers who do not work hard do not waste firm’s output since additional workers can be hired. If additional costs related to low-effort labor are taken into consideration, this will result in an equilibrium effort-wage elasticity lower than unity. On the other hand, efficiency wages have often been used to explain the pattern of interindustry wages (e.g. Krueger and Summers, 1988). One empirical regularity that they sought to explain is that industries with greater productivity per employee pay their workers more (e.g. Katz and Summers, 1989). Mehta (1998) proposed a model in which supervisors monitor and coordinate their subordinates. However managers are constrained to make tradeoffs in these activities. Therefore ‘‘if the productivity of supervisors increases, then other things being equal, they will want to coordinate more and monitor less. Consequently, to maintain effort, they will pay more. Similarly, an increase in the productivity of workers makes supervisors want to employ more of them. Other things being equal, they will now want to monitor each worker less and pay more’’ (Mehta, 1998, p. 153). This paper presents a model that combines the shirking and turnover costs models with managerial supervision in an intertemporal optimizing framework. The model encompasses Marti (1997) and Mehta (1998) analysis into an intertemporal optimization framework developed along the lines of Lin and Lai (1994). The results show that when managerial productivity is not considered, and shirking and turnover costs are taken into account, the Solow condition is not valid. Furthermore, when managerial productivity is considered and offsets shirking and turnover costs, then the Solow condition can be a possible outcome.

2. The Model Following Mehta (1998), the representative firm has a production function that depends on the product of managers and workers:

d (s) y 5 S(1 2 Mg(s))sN 1 V ]] e(w)sN s

(1)

the first term on the right-hand side (RHS) stands for the net contribution that supervisors make to directly increasing output. Where S is the productivity of supervisors, M is the difficult of monitoring, g(s) is the extensive monitoring (assumed to be a convex function, g9.0, g0.0), and s is the span of control of each supervisor. There are N identical teams with s workers, so the total number of workers is n 5 Ns. The second term in the RHS is the net output of workers and depends on the productivity of workers (V ). The function d (s) indicates how output of the s workers in the productive unit, who work for one supervisor, varies with s (ds . 0; dss , 0). Workers’ effort (e) is assumed to be an increasing function of the relative wage (w), e w . 0. The relative wage is defined as the difference between the wage paid by the firm (w F ) and the reservation wage (w R ): w 5 w F 2 w R . In the above production function it is implicitly assumed that the probability of detection of shirking is equal to one. It is also assumed that the representative firm is a monopolistic competitor in the goods market. The

J.R. Faria / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 93 – 98

95

firm chooses three variables to maximize the discounted profit over an infinite horizon. It uses the span of control (s), the number of hired workers (h) and the relative wage (w) as control variables in the problem below: `

Max h,w,s

E [ p( y)y 2 wn 2 c(N) 2 t(h) 2 sx]exp(2rt) dt

(2)

0 ?

s.t. n 5 h 2 q(w)n

(3)

The term in the brackets in Eq. (2) captures the training costs, t (h),th . 0, when h . 0, and the search costs (s x), where x is the search effort to hire new workers and s is the unit cost of search. In order to hire, the firm must expend search effort, where u 5 h /x, is the number of hires per unit of search. u is a measure of search effectiveness of the firm. u is assumed to be an increasing function of the relative wage (u 5 u (w), uw . 0). The function c( N) is a convex cost of coordination function. Eq. (3) describes the time variation of employed workers. It depends on the difference between the number of hired workers and the workers who decide to quit from the firm. Where q(w) is the quit rate, which is assumed to be a decreasing function of the relative wage (qw , 0). If managers are not productive (S 5 0) and there are no coordination costs (c(N) 5 0), and the quit rate (q) and search effectiveness (u ) are independent of the relative wage, we have the shirking model; and if (S 5 0, c(N) 5 0), and the effort of workers is independent of the relative wage, we have a version of the turnover cost model (Marti, 1997). When q, u and e are independent of the relative wage and S and c(N) are different from zero, we have a dynamic version of Mehta (1998) model. Therefore, the model above combines the shirking and the turnover cost model with the managerial supervision model in an intertemporal optimization framework. The current value Hamiltonian function, H, is written as: n sh H 5 p( y)y 2 wn 2 c ] 2 t (h) 2 ]] 1 l[h 2 q(w)n] s u (w)

SD

Introducing (1) into the Hamiltonian, the first order conditions of this problem are:

s l 5 th 1 ] u

(4)

n y s p( y)(1 1 c ) 5 c n ]2 5 0 s

(5)

s huw (1 1 c )p( y)y w 5 n(1 1 lqw ) 2 ]] nu 2

(6)

F

? cn l 5 l(r 1 q) 2 (1 1 c )p( y)y n 2 w 2 ] s

where dp y c 5 ] ]. dy p

G

(7)

J.R. Faria / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 93 – 98

96

Considering the steady state: ?

n 5 0 ⇒ q(w)n 5 h and by using (4) and (6) in (7) when l~ 50, we have:

F

1 1 (th 1 s /u )qw 2 s quw /u 2 w e w ] 5 ]]]]]]]]]] e 1 1 c n /ws 1 (th 1 s /u )(r 1 q) /w

GF

S(1 2 Mg(s)) 1 1 ]]]] V (d (s) /s)e

G

(8)

From (8) we can discuss the Solow condition.

3. The Solow condition Consider first a model without managerial supervision, i.e., S50 and c(N) 5 c n 5 0. Eq. (8) reduces to 2 w 1 1 qw (th 1 s /u ) 2 [(s quw ) /u ] e w ] 5 ]]]]]]]]]] e h1 1 (th 1 s /u )[(r 1 q) /w]j

(9)

As it is assumed that the number of hired workers, h, is positive, then: th . 0; and taking into consideration that: uw . 0, and qw , 0, it follows that the numerator is less than unity and the denominator is greater than unity in Eq. (9). Therefore the wage-elasticity of effort is less than unity: w ew ] , 1 e From (9), three special situations can be analysed. First, if the voluntary quitting rate does not vary with the relative wage (qw 5 0), Eq. (9) reduces to: 1 2 [(s quw ) /u 2 ] w e w ] 5 ]]]]]]]] e 1 1 (th 1 s /u )[(r 1 q) /w]

(10)

which is still less than unity. The second case is related to the situation in which the search effectiveness of the firm does not depend on the relative wage (uw 5 0): 1 1 qw (c h 1 s /u ) w e w ] 5 ]]]]]]]] e 1 1 (th 1 s /u )[(r 1 q) /w]

(11)

which is also less than unity. As seen above, our optimization problem reduces to a shirking model when uw 5 0, and qw 5 0. Then combining (11) and (10) yields: w 1 e w ] 5 ]]]]]]]] e 1 1 (th 1 s /u )[(r 1 q) /w]

(12)

J.R. Faria / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 93 – 98

97

so, as in Akerlof and Yellen (1986), when shirking is taken into consideration, the effort-wage elasticity is less than unity, and the Solow conditions do not hold. The third situation occurs when the training costs are absent (t (h) 5 th 5 0). From Eq. (9) we have: 2 w 1 1 qw s /u 2 [(s quw ) /u ] e w ] 5 ]]]]]]]] e 1 1 s /u [(r 1 q) /w]

(13)

which is less than unity. The three situations above show that the Solow condition is invalid when shirking and turnover costs are taken into account. Returning to Eq. (8), the Solow condition can be verified if and only if:

F

GF

G

1 1 c n /ws 1 (th 1 s /u )(r 1 q) /w S(1 2 Mg(s)) w e w ] 5 1⇔ ]]]] 5 ]]]]]]]]]] 21.0 e V (d (s) /s)e 1 1 (th 1 s /u )qw 2 s quw /u 2

(14)

condition (14) is the heart of the paper. On the one hand it asserts that the Solow condition depends critically on the rate of productivity of managers and workers (S /V ). If this rate is high, ceteris ` paribus, the Solow condition can be verified. That is, if the managers have high productivity vis-a-vis workers, they can overcome the problems generated by shirking and turnover costs. On the other hand, giving (S /V ), and considering the span of control of each supervisor (s), the extensive monitoring ( g(s)), and output of a team under one supervisor (d (s)), it is easy to see that an increase in the variable s is associated with a decrease in the left-hand side of (14). That means that an increase in the number of people to be monitored by the manager decreases his efficiency. Both results are quite appealing since managers are employed, among other things, to reduce shirking and turnover costs. Therefore, when managerial productivity is considered, it can offset the former effect of shirking and turnovers costs in order to guarantee that the Solow condition holds 1 .

4. Concluding remarks This paper blends the shirking and the turnover models of efficiency wage with managerial supervision into an intertemporal optimization framework. It is shown that the Solow condition does not hold when shirking and turnover costs are considered. The Solow condition can be a possible outcome when managerial productivity offsets shirking and turnover costs.

Acknowledgements I would like to thank, without implicating, Joaquim Andrade, Francisco G. Carneiro, Sophia Delipalla, Andy Dickerson, Khaled Hussein and one anonymous referee for useful comments. 1

Notice that these considerations hold true not only for the Solow condition. One can show the elasticity of work effort with respect to the real wage is greater than one as well.

98

J.R. Faria / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 93 – 98

References Akerlof, G.A., Yellen, J.L., 1986. Efficiency Wage Models of Labor Market, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Katz, L.F., Summers, L.H. 1989. Industry rents: evidence and implications, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 209–275. Krueger, A.B., Summers, L.H., 1988. Efficiency wages and the inter-industry wage structure. Econometrica 56, 259–294. Lin, C.-C., Lai, C.-C., 1994. The turnover costs and the Solow condition in an efficiency wage model with intertemporal optimization. Economics Letters 45, 501–505. Marti, C., 1997. Efficiency wages: combining the shirking and turnover cost models. Economics Letters 57, 327–330. Mehta, S.R., 1998. The law of one price and a theory of the firm: a Ricardian perspective on interindustry wages. RAND Journal of Economics 29, 137–156. Salop, S., 1979. A model of natural rate of unemployment. American Economic Review 69, 117–125. Shapiro, C., Stiglitz, J.E., 1984. Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. American Economic Review 74, 433–444. Solow, R., 1979. Another possible source of wage stickness. Journal of Macroeconomics 1, 79–82.

Supervision and effort in an intertemporal efficiency ...

According to the shirking model (e.g., Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984), firms ... condition, as it became known, states that an optimizing firm sets its wage at the level ...

45KB Sizes 2 Downloads 173 Views

Recommend Documents

Supervision and effort in an intertemporal efficiency ...
benefit from paying their workers more than the market clearing wage, thus generating involuntary ... pay efficiency wages in order to reduce workers' shirking.

Wage and effort dispersion
choose how much capital to purchase. While they address the ... the paper.1 A worker exerts a continuous effort e, which yields one of two levels of output. With .... it will get at least as many workers in expectation if not more, and will have larg

Efficiency and Lack of Commitment in an Overlapping ...
than a young agent. Endowments are perishable and there is no saving technology. At each date, every agent can transfer some part of his/her endowments to ...

Intertemporal Disagreement and Empirical Slippery ...
In this article I point out another location at which these arguments may go wrong: ... 4 J. E. Olson and D. B. Kopel, 'All the Way down the Slippery Slope: Gun Prohibition ..... not take the sincere belief of a clairvoyant that the world will end in

EFFICIENCY AND FAIRNESS IN AIR TRAFFIC CONTROL1
air traffic controllers in their decision-making process. There is a ... coordinate their path of flight between themselves, and the Collaborative Decision Making concept. [3] which is ..... www.doc.ic.ac.uk/˜ue/MARA/mara-may-2005.pdf. [5] Marc ...

Efficiency and Information Transmission in Bilateral Trading
Aug 17, 2015 - theories information transmission enhances the efficiency of the market, .... assume that traders share all of their information in every meeting.

EFFICIENCY AND FAIRNESS IN AIR TRAFFIC CONTROL1
In classical resource allocation the central question is “what is the best allocation of ... To see which notion of fairness is best suited for the ATC domain, note that ...

EFFICIENCY AND FAIRNESS IN AIR TRAFFIC CONTROL1
Much effort is being put into the development of software tools to assist the air traffic ... If air traffic controllers wouldn't abide to this, they risk protests of airline companies who feel that ..... www.doc.ic.ac.uk/˜ue/MARA/mara-may-2005.pdf.

Modeling of Effort Perception in Lifting and Reaching ...
Jun 26, 2001 - measures of effort and use this information to predict fatigue or the risk of injury. Lifting and reaching tasks were performed in seated and standing ... required to perform these tasks were rated on a ten point visual analog scale. S

Modeling of Shoulder and Torso Effort Perception in ...
Proceedings of SAE Digital Human Modeling for Design and Engineering Conference,. Munich ... A total of 2,551 ratings were obtained from twenty subjects.

On the Relationship of Arousals and Artifacts in Respiratory Effort ...
plethysmography sensor (RIP) during whole-night polysomnog- raphy (including sleep stage and arousal annotations done with. EEG) and annotated the ...

Risk preferences, intertemporal substitution, and ...
Feb 15, 2012 - EIS is bigger than one or habits are present—two assumptions that have .... aggregate data on the volatility of output and consumption growth, ...

Intertemporal Cooperation and Symmetry through ...
It is easy to see that the denominator of (B11) is positive. For the numerator, either t − s ... inator of (19) are positive when (8) and (9) hold. Therefore, we have.

intertemporal budget constraint and public
the sum of all current and expected future non-interest outlays — expressed in ... economy by taking into account the growth of national income. In such a case, ...

An Intertemporal CAPM with Stochastic Volatility - Scholars at Harvard
Jan 23, 2017 - This paper studies the pricing of volatility risk using the first-order conditions of a long-term equity investor who is content to hold the aggregate ...

An Intertemporal CAPM with Stochastic Volatility - Scholars at Harvard
Jan 23, 2017 - Email [email protected]. Polk ... Email [email protected]. ...... Though admittedly somewhat ad hoc, this bound is consistent with ...

Dopamine and effort-based decision making - Frontiers
Jun 21, 2011 - Motivational theories of choice focus on the influence of goal values and strength of reinforcement to explain behavior. By contrast relatively little is known concerning how the cost of an action, such as effort expended, contributes

Dopamine and effort-based decision making - Frontiers
Jun 21, 2011 - dopaminergic system, correlates with the prediction error signals derived from ... with these effects in turn being blocked by systemic administration of a DA ... of cortico-subcortical networks for cost–benefit decision making.

effective effort - GitHub
These can make a big difference! ... Need to “link” data. Distance data/detection function. Segment data. Observation data to link segments to detections ...

Logical Effort - Semantic Scholar
D What is the best circuit topology for a function? .... Logical effort extends to multi-stage networks: ..... Asymmetric logic gates favor one input over another.