Structural Change and Global Trade Logan Lewis1

Ryan Monarch1 Jing Zhang3 1 Federal

2 Federal 3 Federal

Michael Sposi2

Reserve Board

Reserve Bank of Dallas

Reserve Bank of Chicago

November 2017 The views expressed here should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, or any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System.

Introduction Figure 1: Global Trade to Expenditure Ratio 0.6 0.55 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Year

I

Global trade openness triples over the past half century.

Structural Change Figure 2: Sectoral Expenditure Shares 1 Goods Services

0.9

Sectoral expenditure share

0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Year

I

Global expenditure switches from goods to services over time.

Sectoral Expenditure Derivation

Sectoral Openness Figure 3: Trade to Expenditure Ratios by Sector 2

Goods Services

Sectoral trade/sectoral expenditure

1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Year

I

Goods are more tradable than services.

2005

2010

2015

Structural Change and Trade Openness Figure 4: Correlations (gtrade-to-expenditure , gservices expenditure share ) ‐0.5 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 ‐0.55 ‐0.6 ‐0.65 ‐0.7 ‐0.75 ‐0.8 ‐0.85 ‐0.9 ‐0.95

I

A faster rise in the services expenditure share is associated with a slower growth in global trade openness

What we do I

I

We quantify the impact of structural change on global trade growth I

A simple empirical exercise

I

A general equilibrium trade model

We find that structural change has substantially held back trade growth over the past four decades I

The model implies that global trade openness would have been about 70 percent (23 ppts higher) by 2015 without structural change in expenditure shares

I

The simple empirical calculation overstates the impact of structural change

Literature

I

Trade affects structural change I

I

Why does trade grow faster than GDP? I

I

Matsuyama (2009), Uy, Yi, and Zhang (2013), Betts, Giri and Verma (2016), Teignier (2016), Sposi (2016), Kehoe, Ruhl and ´ ecki (2016), Reyes-Heroles (2017) Steinberg (2016), Swi¸

Rose (2011), Baier and Bergstrand (2001), Imbs and Wacziarg (2003), Yi (2003)

Non-homothetic preferences help explain trade patterns I

Markusen (1986), Fieler (2011), Simonovska (2015)

Empirical Counterfactual

I

Data openness (26 countries and ROW 1970-2015) Tradegt Expgt Tradest Expst Tradet = + Expt Expgt Expt Expst Expt

I

Counterfactual openness ^t Tradegt Expg 0 Tradest Exps0 Trade = + Expt Expgt Exp0 Expst Exp0

Empirical Counterfactual Figure 5: Aggregate Trade to Expenditure Ratio 1.1 Data Fixed expenditure weights

1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Year

I

In the counterfactual, the trade/expenditure ratio is 93 percent or 45 percentage points higher than in the data.

Discussion on Empirical Counterfactual I

Reduced form analysis shows substantial impact of structural change on global trade flows

I

On the other hand, the reduced form analysis is limited I

I

Ignores endogenous responses of sectoral trade openness to structural change I

Ignores input-output linkages

I

Ignores endogenous responses of prices and trade patterns

So we analyze the implications of structural change on international trade in a quantitative model

Model

I

A multi-country two-sector Eaton-Kortum trade model with two key features: 1. Non-homothetic preferences generates the rising expenditure share of services over time 2. An input-output structure generates gross trade and accounts for linkages across sectors

I

The EK structure generates both intra- and inter-sector trade, which is crucial for matching bilateral trade patterns.

Model: Preferences I

We use “non-homothetic CES” preferences, as in Gorman (1965), Hanoch (1975) and Comin et al. (2015)

I

The aggregate consumption Ci combines sectoral composite goods Cik according to the implicitly defined function: X k=g ,s

 ωk

Ci Li

 k −σ  σ

Cik Li

 σ−1 σ

= 1,

I

k gives sector-specific income elasticity of demand

I

σ gives elasticity of substitution between sectoral composites

Model: budget constraint

I

Earns labor income and spends on goods and services: Pig Cig + Pis Cis = wi Li − (ρi wi Li − RLi ), {z } | {z } | Pi Ci

I

NXi

Trade imbalances are introduced as in Caliendo, Parro, Rossi-Hansberg, and Sarte (2014) I

A exogenous fraction ρi of income is sent to global portfolio.

I

Global portfolio disperses R to every worker to maintain zero balance.

Model: Optimality

I

The sectoral expenditure shares are given by Pik Cik = ωkσ eik = Pi Ci



Pik Pi

1−σ 

Ci Li

k −1

I

σ governs how relative prices affect expenditure shares

I

k governs how income affects expenditure shares

(1)

Model: Production I

Production of good z in sector k and country i  1−λik γikn Yik (z) = Aik (z)(Tik Lik (z))λik Πn=g ,s Mikn (z)

I

I

Aik (z) drawn from a Fr´echet with shape parameter θk

I

Tik value-added productivity

Sector composite (“absorption”), standard in EK. Z Qik =

1

Qik (z)

η−1 η

η  η−1

dz

0 I

Absorption is split between final consumption and input usage: X Qik = Cik + Mink , n=g ,s

Model: Trade I

Sectors source from the cheapest source with trade costs τijk

I

Import shares θλjk

πijk = PI

Tjk

(vjk τijk )−θ

θλjk

s=1

Tjk

(vsk τisk )−θ

where λik

vik = Bik wi I

(Πn=g ,s (Pin )γikn )1−λik

Relationship between production and absorption I X

Pjk Qjk πjik = Pik Yik

j=1

I

Global market clearing Pik Qik = Pik Cik +

X n=g ,s

(1 − λin )γink

I X j=1

πjin Pjn Qjn

Model: Equilibrium

I

A competitive equilibrium is a sequence of output and factor prices {wi , Pig , Pis , Pi }Ii=1 , allocations {Lig , Lis , Migg , Migs , Misg , Miss , Qig , Qis , Yig , Yis , eig , eis , Cig , Cis , Ci }Ii=1 , transfers from the global portfolio, R, and trade shares {πijg , πijs }i,j=1,..I , such that (i) given prices, allocations are optimal; (ii) markets clear.

Calibration I

26 countries and ROW aggregate over 1970-2015

I

Two sectors: goods and services

I

labor endowment {Li }: employment data

I

trade imbalances {ρi }: net exports data

I

Fr´echet parameter {θk }: 4.0 (Simonovska and Waugh 2014)

I

production coefficients {λik , γikn }:

I

preferences parameters {σ, k , ωk }

I

trade costs {τijg , τijs }, productivities {Tig , Tis },

Calibration of Production Parameters

I

World Input-Output database (WIOD) (1995-2011)

I

Extend to the full time period (1970-2015)

I

Parameter values: Cross-country, cross-time averages λg

Value added share in sector g

0.39

λs

Value added share in sector s

0.61

γgg

Share of g ’s Intermediate input from g

0.68

γss

Share of s’s Intermediate input from s

0.66

Calibration of Preferences I

The equilibrium condition on relative expenditure shares 

I

eig eis



 =

ωg ωs

σ 

1−σ 

Ci Li

εg −εs

Pick (ωg , σ, εg − εs ) to maximize the fit to the data on d c expenditure shares ec ik , expenditure Pi Ci , sectoral prices Pik " X X  ωg σ min ωs t i \ P it Cit s.t. = cit L

I

Pig Pis

X k

ωkσ

d P igt Pc ist 

Cit cit L

!1−σ 

εk −σ

Cit cit L

εg −εs

1−σ d P ikt

σ = 0.4, εg = 1, εs = 1.59, ωg = 0.49

 −

!

1 1−σ

ec igt ec ist

 #2

Calibration of Productivity and Trade Costs I

Target the expenditure shares and bilateral trade shares

I

d b Compute {Pig , Pis } from data on {c eig , ec is , Pi Ci , Li } and estimated {σ, εk , ωk }

I

Calibrate Tik and τijk using {Pig , Pis } and bilateral trade shares πijk Tikλik = τijk

Bik νik −

1

θk Γ−1 k Pik (πiik )   1   πijk − θk Pik = πjjk Pjk

Summary of Productivity and Trade Costs

6 5

Log index of productivity Goods Services

6

Sectoral trade barriers Goods Services

5

4 4 3 3

2

2

1 0 1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

1 1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

I

Productivity growth is much faster in goods than in services.

I

Trade barriers decline over time, and are lower for goods.

Model-based Counterfactual

I

Solve the model counterfactuals by setting εk = 1, σ = 1, and ωik = eik0 I

No income effects: g = s = 1

I

No relative price effects: σ = 1

I

Keep all other baseline driving forces unchanged

I

Compare the resulting changes in trade/expediture ratios to the baseline model solution.

Model-Based Counterfactual Figure 6: Global Trade to Expenditure Ratio 1.1 Baseline Fixed expenditure shares

1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 1970

I

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

By 2015, the model-based counterfactual is 23 percentage points or 48 percent higher than the data. Goods expenditure share

Model-Based v.s. Empirical Counterfactual Figure 7: Global Trade to Expenditure Ratio 1.1 Baseline Fixed expenditure shares, model Fixed expenditure weights, empirical

1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 1970

I

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

The empirical counterfactual overestimates the impact of structural change on global openness by 25 percentage points.

Sectoral Trade Openness Figure 8: Trade over expenditure by sector Goods Baseline Fixed expenditure shares

2

0.15

1

0.1

0.5

0.05

I

1980

1990

2000

2010

Baseline Fixed expenditure shares

0.2

1.5

0 1970

Services

0.25

0 1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Goods trade openness is lower in the counterfactual than the baseline/data.

Sectoral Trade Openness Tradekt Absorptionkt Tradekt = × Expkt Absorptionkt Expkt

0.4 0.2

Absorption over expenditure

1980

1990

2000

Baseline Fixed expenditure shares

4

3

2 1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Baseline Fixed expenditure shares

0.12 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04

2010

Goods

5

Trade over absorption

0.6

1970

Services

0.14

Baseline Fixed expenditure shares

1970

Absorption over expenditure

Trade over absorption

Goods 0.8

1980

1990

2000

2010

Services

2.4

Baseline Fixed expenditure shares

2.2 2 1.8 1.6 1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Counterfactual without Cross-Sector I/O Linkage set γgg = γss = 1

0.4 0.2 1980

1990

2000

No IO No IO, fixed expenditure shares

4

3

2 1970

1980

1990

2000

0.1

2010

No IO No IO, fixed expenditure shares

0.08 0.06 0.04

2010

Goods

5

Trade over absorption

0.6

1970

Services

0.12

No IO No IO, fixed expenditure shares

1970

Absorption over expenditure

Trade over absorption

Goods 0.8

Absorption over expenditure

I

1980

2000

2010

Services

2.4 2.2

1990

No IO No IO, fixed expenditure shares

2 1.8 1.6 1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Counterfactual with No Income Effect I

set εg = εs = 1 Figure 9: Global Trade over Expenditure 1.1 Data Fixed expenditure shares No income effects

1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Year

I

Income effect explains about 1/4 of the difference between the data and the fixed expenditure counterfactual.

Counterfactul with Fixed Trade Costs I

set τijkt = τijk0 Figure 10: Global Trade over Expenditure 1.1 Data Fixed expenditure shares Fixed trade costs

1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Year

I

Impact of structural change on global trade growth is similar to that of trade barriers

Implication of Structural Change on Trade Costs

5.5

Goods Services Trade-weighted average of two sectors One sector calibration

Sectoral trade barriers

5

4.5

4

3.5

3

2.5 1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Year

I

Ignoring structural change misinterprets trade costs dynamics

Implication of Structural Change on Gains from Trade

Two-sector model One-sector model

World "C" in baseline relative to autarky

1.1

1.08

1.06

1.04

1.02

1 1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Year

I

Ignoring structural change overestimates gains from trade

Projection I

Assume that productivity grows at the “average” rate for the next 25 years. All other parameters constant at 2015 levels. Figure 11: Global Trade over Expenditure 0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1 1970

I

1980

1990

2000

2010

2020

2030

Global trade openness would fall to 37% in 2035

Conclusion I

As countries switch away from highly traded goods over time, this structural change dragged down global trade growth over the past four decades

I

Our model with non-homothetic preferences and an input-output structure estimates that global trade openness would be 23 percentage points or 48 percent higher if structural change had not occurred. I

The empirical counterfactual that takes sectoral openness as given overstates the implications of structural change

I

The model implies that structural change held back global trade growth roughly as much as reductions in trade costs boosted it.

I

Global openness might decrease in coming years if the effect of structural change dominates that of trade costs.

Country List

Australia, Austria, Belgium-Luxembourg, Brazil, Canada, China, Cyprus, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, India, Indonesia, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Turkey, United Kingdom, and United States, plus a “Rest of World” Back

Counterfactual Global Expenditure Shares Figure 12: Global Expenditure Share on Goods 0.8 Baseline Fixed expenditure shares

0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2 1970

back

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Figure 13: Derivation of Sectoral Expenditure

Net

Production

Consumption

Value Added

Expenditure

(Subtract input usage)

(Multiply by GO/VA ratio)

Gross

back

Gross Output

(Add imports, subtract exports)

Absorption

Projection Figure 14: Projection

0.8

0.6

Good's share in GDP

Trade / expenditure, tot

0.7

0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1

1 Baseline Projection, produtcivity growth = median 2011-2015 0.5

0.6

0.4

0

0.2

-0.5

0 1980

2000

2020

-1 1980

2000

2020

-1

2

1

Absorption / expenditure, gds

3

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0

0.5

10 8 6 4 2

1980

2000

2020

1980

2000

2020

0.3

0.2

0.1

0

0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0

1980

2000

2020

1980

2000

2020

1980

2000

2020

2

Absorption / expenditure, srv

0.3

Trade / absorption, srv

0.4

Trade / expenditure, srv

0

12

Trade / absorption, gds

Trade / expenditure, gds

4

-0.5

1.9 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.4

1980

2000

2020

1

Country Plots Figure 15: Country Trade/Expenditure 3.5

AUS

3.5

AUT

3.5

BLX

3.5

BRA

3.5

3

3

3

3

3

2.5

2.5

2.5

2.5

2.5

2

2

2

2

2

1.5

1.5

1.5

1.5

1.5

1

1

1

1

1

0.5

0.5

0.5

0.5

0.5

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

CHN

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

CYP

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

DEU

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

DNK

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

3

3

3

3

3

2.5

2.5

2.5

2.5

2.5

2

2

2

2

2

1.5

1.5

1.5

1.5

1.5

1

1

1

1

1

0.5

0.5

0.5

0.5

0.5

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

FIN

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

FRA

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

GBR

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3.5

GRC

3.5

3

3

3

3

2.5

2.5

2.5

2.5

2.5

2

2

2

2

2

1.5

1.5

1.5

1.5

1.5

1

1

1

1

1

0.5

0.5

0.5

0.5

0.5

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

ESP

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

3

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

CAN

IDN

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

2

2

2

2

2

1

1

1

1

1

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Country Plots

Figure 16: Country Trade/Expenditure

IND

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

IRL

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

ITA

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

JPN

KOR

3

3

3

3

3

2

2

2

2

2

1

1

1

1

1

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

MEX

NLD

PRT

SWE

TUR

3

3

3

3

3

2

2

2

2

2

1

1

1

1

1

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

USA

ROW

3

3

2

2

1

1

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Baseline Fixed Expenditure

Country Plots Figure 17: Country Sectoral Expenditure Shares 1

AUS

1

AUT

1

BLX

1

BRA

1

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

CHN

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

CYP

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

DEU

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

DNK

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

FIN

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

FRA

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

GBR

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

GRC

1

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

ESP

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0.8

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

CAN

IDN

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

Country Plots

0 0 Figure 18: Country01970Sectoral Expenditure Shares 01970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

IND

IRL

1

1

ITA

1

JPN

1

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

MEX

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

NLD

1

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

PRT

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

SWE

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0.2

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

1

USA

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

ROW

1

0.8

0 1970

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Goods Services

1980

1990

2000

2010

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

KOR

TUR

0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Structural Change and Global Trade

Structural Change. Figure 2: Sectoral Expenditure Shares. 1970. 1975. 1980. 1985. 1990. 1995. 2000. 2005. 2010. 2015. Year. 0. 0.1. 0.2. 0.3. 0.4. 0.5. 0.6. 0.7. 0.8. 0.9. 1. Sectoral expenditure share. Goods. Services. ▷ Global expenditure switches from goods to services over time. Sectoral Expenditure Derivation ...

552KB Sizes 0 Downloads 274 Views

Recommend Documents

Trade, Structural Transformation, and Growth
Jan 16, 2014 - Seung-Gyu Sim, E. Young Song, and Kevin Donovan are gratefully acknowledged. All remaining errors are ours. The views expressed herein are ...... 234-250. Rodríguez, Francisco, and Dani Rodrik, 2001, "Trade Policy and Economic Growth:

Late Industrialization and Structural Change
the recent phase of crisis and recovery from 1995 to 2000. Growth during ..... sectors. Before proceeding to discuss the results, the data used, their sources, the aggregation ...... Handbook of Industrial Organization (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

SUPPLEMENTAL APPENDIX Structural Change and ...
Building, University Park, Nottingham NG7 2RD, UK. ..... with T − 1 year dummies; 2FE — OLS with country and time dummies; FD — OLS with variables in first.

Job Polarization and Structural Change
personal services, entertainment, business and repair services (except advertising and computer and data processing services), nursing and personal care ...

Job Polarization and Structural Change
Keywords: Job Polarization, Structural Change, Roy model ... computer technologies (ICT) substitute for middle-skill and hence middle-wage. (routine) ...

Global Supply Chains and Trade Policy
... CEPR; [email protected]. §Dartmouth College and NBER; [email protected] ..... number of additional technical assumptions. We focus on a ...

Lewis, Monarch, Sposi, and Zhang - Structural Change ...
Nov 9, 2017 - For example, by setting the income elasticity in preferences to be 1, so that expenditure shares do .... We take value added by sector from the UN Main Aggregates Database (UN (2017)), trade data from the IMF ..... in the model, so the

Tests for structural change, aggregation, and ...
available in existing software packages. As opposed to this, the MV route is ...... Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 10 (2), 221–228. Kramer, W., 1989.

Lewis, Monarch, Sposi, and Zhang - Structural Change ...
Aug 8, 2017 - Reserve Bank of Dallas, or any other person associated with the Federal ... of this paper is to quantify the effect of structural change on international trade flows. We start ... than international trade is for explaining the pattern o

Agricultural Diversity, Structural Change and Long-run ...
sense of lowering unit costs). .... Water-rotted hemp 0.02. 07.17 ..... geo-climatic controls, to give a sense of the variation that is used to identify the causal effects.

Structural Change and Cross-Country Growth Empirics
economy framework, discuss the data and briefly review the empirical ..... GMM and Blundell and Bond (1998) System GMM, MG — Pesaran and Smith .... performs well even when the cross-section dimension N is small, when ... global/local business cycle

economics of global trade and finance pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. economics of ...

Vertical Linkages and the Collapse of Global Trade
http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.101.3.308 ... linkages. The framework we use draws from ..... Comparing (6) to (5), both gross exports and.

The collapse of global trade, murky protectionism, and ...
declines for the US, South Africa, and Korea. Egypt and New Zealand, which had ini* tiated new investigations in 2004, did not initiate any new investigations in ...

Global Networks of Trade and Bits
Sep 2, 2011 - the network of trade in digital services (trade in bits) and compare it with that ..... Table 1: Network density and share of bilateral links. Bits.

Vertical Linkages and the Collapse of Global Trade
The framework we use draws from Robert C. Johnson and Guillermo Noguera (2010) .... we note that our framework generates a decline in world trade of 11%, which is close to the actual decline of 15%. This is a ... shares play an additional role in exp

Global Networks of Trade and Bits
Sep 2, 2011 - in the digital economy, and to map the international trade of digital goods. It has to be ...... Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J.. Newman ...

Hinrich Global Trade Scholarship -
4. Copies of transcripts, and any official English language exams results (eg: TOEFL or IELTS). 5. Scanned copy of your passport photo page (if available).