04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 69

© 2002 Journal of Peace Research, vol. 39, no. 1, 2002, pp. 69–90 Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi) [0022-3433(200201)39:1; 69–90; 021062]

Conflicting Identities: Solidary Incentives in the Serbo-Croatian War* GAVAN DUFFY Department of Political Science, Syracuse University

NICOLE LINDSTROM Department of International Relations and European Studies, Central European University Conflict elites often mobilize by distributing to their constituents solidary incentives to participation. Although elites find this strategy relatively cost-free at mobilization time, it greatly limits their action possibilities at conflict settlement time. The non-retractability of solidary incentives limits the ability of leaders to accommodate their adversaries. It thereby tends to produce protracted conflicts. This article draws upon the Serbo-Croatian conflict to illustrate this general proposition. It shows how distributions of solidary incentives contributed to the protractedness of the 1990–95 conflict between Croatia and Serbia following the dissolution of the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia. The reliance of political leaders on solidary incentives also helps account for subsequent difficulties in implementing the Dayton Peace Agreement. The article concludes by reflecting on how the non-retractability of solidary incentives could affect practical strategies for producing peace in this setting.

Introduction Social categorization theory has greatly advanced our understanding of the processes by which individuals identify with groups. From Durkheim’s (1947) anthropological observations, through Tajfel’s (1981, 1984a; Tajfel & Turner, 1979) experiments, and to the contemporary work of Turner and others (1984, 1987; Oakes, Haslam & Turner, 1994; Turner et al., 1994), social categorization * We gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments of Augusta del Zotto, Mladenka Fangiullos, Mitchell Orenstein, Marko Kocic, Maple Rasza, Dennison Rusinow, and two anonymous reviewers. We also thank Nathalie Frensley for reminding us of the indispensability of social representations for settlement. We ourselves bear responsibility for any errors in this article, an early version of which we presented to the International Society of Political Psychology Twentieth Annual Scientific Meeting, Krakow, Poland on 22 July 1997.

theory teaches that humans make their social world sensible by constructing cognitive categories that represent groups. The contents of these categories inform judgments that people make every day to cope with the complexities of social life. In their stereotypical judgments, individuals attribute to others properties that they believe characterize members of the groups with which those others identify. We most notice stereotypical judgments when they contribute to ethnocentric or other forms of chauvinist speech and behavior. But this dark side of social categories consists not in the act of deduction from social representations, but in the chauvinist contents of the social representations of chauvinist persons. Less often recognized, but nonetheless socially significant, are the host of stereo-typical inferences we each 69

04duffy (ds)

70

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 70

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

draw every day. Our conception of the place of others in our cognitive network of social categories establishes our expectations of their behavior. Our self-conception within that same network likewise regulates our own behavior, often in pro-social ways. In the aggregate, stereotypical judgment provides the cognitive glue necessary for social cohesion. Pathological uses of social representations bear obvious relevance to the problem of ethnic group conflict. Students of conflict sense that ethnic group animosities, pervasive among group identifiers and often persistent over generations, in large measure explain the protractedness of ethnic conflicts. Yet the relationship between the psychological processes of group identification and the social and political processes of conflict have not yet been articulated with any specificity. In this article, we begin such an articulation by linking social identification to a theoretical account of conflict processes. We argue that group elites often mobilize mass political constituencies for collective action by exploiting the human propensity to mediate understandings of social reality through social representations. That is, leaders encourage followers to participate in conflict by manipulating symbols pertaining to social categories. These actions subsequently limit leaders’ abilities to accommodate their adversaries, producing protracted conflicts as a consequence. Elite manipulations of social representations thereby make conflict more likely and peace less likely. We illustrate our thesis by showing how the elite manipulations of social representations contributed to the protractedness of the SerboCroatian conflict and how it has affected implementation of the Dayton Peace Accords. We also reflect upon practical strategies for producing peace in this setting.

Conflict Processes In ‘configurational history’ (Hall, 1999: 216–220), one assesses a theory by showing

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

the goodness of its fit to some historical episode. This practice conforms roughly to the realist notion that one cannot account adequately for such episodes without first postulating a theory – however tentative and revisable – of the processes responsible for generating them (Dessler, 1991). In its absence, we can neither posit expectations nor recognize anomalies into which additional inquiry might prove productive. Any theoretical model thus constitutes a hermeneutic ‘preunderstanding’ (Moon, 1975) against which to assess political events for the purpose of elaborating or ‘retrovalidating’ (Rescher, 1977) a more refined theoretical understanding that can similarly configure future research. Theory of Conflict Processes As depicted in Figure 1, the Duffy & Frensley (1991; Frensley, 1998, 2000) theoretical model of political conflict processes describes conflict processes as a series of choices elites make in response to political conditions. Although validated against historical events surrounding the conflict in Northern Ireland and elsewhere, we apprehend the model as only a rough and revisable approximation of conflict processes. Below, we refer to nodes in the model as letters in square brackets and pathways as hyphenated strings of nodes in square brackets. All conflicts begin with some identifiable stakes, or a motivation [A]. If group elites believe that the benefits of competing for these stakes outweigh the costs and risks of mobilizing their constituents, they mobilize them [A-B-C]. If not, the potential conflict over the stakes remains temporarily latent [AB-A]. In the event that elites mobilize, and if the costs and risks of conflict engagement allow it [D], the parties conflict. Importantly, these costs and risks vary as a consequence not only of factors internal to the conflict situation, but also of factors external to it – especially the posture of the international community. If institutional mechanisms exist

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 71

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

Figure 1. Theoretical Model of Conflict Processes

for resolving intergroup differences [E], the parties compete within those institutions. Institutionalized conflict ([E-F-G-L] and [EF-G-H-M]) may beconsidered ordinary, peaceable, political competition. Groups

engage in ‘hot conflict’, however, if those institutions do not exist ([E-I-J-K]) or if one or more groups does not recognize its (real, non-normative) legitimacy ([E-F-I-J-K]). Nodes in the hot conflict pathway ([I], [J],

71

04duffy (ds)

72

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 72

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

and [K]) are ordered arbitrarily. In particular, group elites may pursue the ‘divide and conquer’ strategy [J] before the cooptation strategy [I], if they find it less costly. And elites may pursue all three strategies simultaneously. Whether intergroup competition proceeds down the institutional or hot conflict pathway, the model suggests continual cycles of mobilization and counter-mobilization ([L-C] or [M-C]) until elites across groups agree to settle. If they can persuade constituents to accept their terms [N], they implement the settlement [O]. Only when the terms adequately address the conflict stakes is the conflict resolved ([P-Q]). Alternatively, a settlement may produce a period of peace during which the conflict ‘goes latent’, possibly resurfacing later should elites again find mobilization in their interest ([P-A-B-C]). Some settlement terms in hot conflict environments construct or reform political institutions that all parties find legitimate, such that future iterations of intergroup competition proceed down the more peaceable institutional conflict pathway. The model incorporates factional conflict at nodes [R], [S], and [T]. The entire model recursively represents each category of factional conflict, but with different parties and different stakes. The parties to a factional conflict are subsets of the membership of the larger group. The stakes typically include control of the leadership apparatus of the larger group. Each form of factional conflict arises from a failure of an ascendant group elite. • Failed Mobilization [D-R-A] – the failure of group elites to mobilize their constituents (a) against a perceived threat to group interests or (b) for the pursuit of a perceived benefit to group interests. • Failed Solidarity [J-S-A] – the failure of group elites to maintain solidarity in response to the divisive tactics of rival groups.

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

• Failed Demobilization [N-T-U-A] – the failure of group elites to demobilize their constituents in order to implement the terms of a settlement effected with elites of rival groups. Any of these failures can encourage hardliner cadres to challenge the ascendancy of incumbents. Successful challenges produce greater conflictual group behavior, since hardliners assume the mantle of group leadership. But even unsuccessful challenges can escalate conflict, as the incumbents may harden their intergroup policies in order to fend off the internal challenge. The effect is particularly salient with respect to failed demobilization. Settlements can fail because hardliners will not accept their terms, and the fear of such a failure can motivate leaders to reject settlement terms even when they find those terms in the group’s interest. Factional infighting and even its prospect thus logically promote conflict protractedness. Serbo-Croatian Conflict Processes The dissolution of Yugoslavia produced a number of interrelated, protracted conflicts. Although we could assess the model against this entire family of conflicts, we restrict our focus to the conflict between Croats and Serbs for three reasons: (1) Tensions between Serbia and Croatia were central throughout the existence of Yugoslavia, as the other constituent republics tended to align themselves with either Serbia or Croatia, depending on their strategic or material interests (Dragnich, 1992). (2) Although sporadic ethnic fighting flared earlier in Kosovo, large-scale conflict did not erupt until 1991, when Serbian governing elites tried to prevent Croatia, with its substantial minority of ethnic Serbs, from seceding.

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 73

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

(3) With the implementation of the Dayton Peace Agreement in 1995 [O] and diplomatic normalization, relations between Serbs and Croats are sufficiently stable to facilitate retrospective evaluation. Below, we briefly recount the history of the Serbo-Croatian conflict, showing how Tito’s Yugoslavia constituted a legitimate institutional mechanism for channeling the conflict down the institutional pathways ([EF-G]). Once the institutions of the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia lost all legitimacy, the Serbo-Croatian conflict proceeded down the hot conflict pathway [E-I-J-K-L].1 Conflict Sublimation under Tito, 1945–86 Tito’s Federal Republic of Yugoslavia, founded in 1945, implemented an intricate balance-of-power system to sublimate national conflicts within the Federation (Burg, 1983; Cohen, 1983; Ramet, 1992). Tito’s scheme was always unstable, as he constructed it over tenuous faultlines. Eruption seemed imminent twice, during the ‘Reform Struggle’ of 1962–65 and, most notably, during the ‘Croatian Crisis’ of 1970–71. In both episodes, political elites mobilized support around mutually incompatible Serbian and Croatian policy preferences [A]. Serbs demanded the redistribution of wealth from the Northern republics of Slovenia and Croatia to underdeveloped regions in the South, the concentration of industry in Serbia, centralization of the political system, and the reassertion of Serbian hegemony. Croats insisted upon curtailing aid to unprofitable enterprises in Serbia and the southern republics, dismantling central planning, and decentralizing 1

The term ‘Serb’ can refer ambiguously to Serbs in Serbia, in Croatia, in Bosnia, or anywhere else. The term ‘Croat’ can produce similar ambiguities. Following Banac’s (1994: 17–18) guidance, in this article ‘Serb’ refers to ethnic Serbs in Serbia and ‘Croat’ to ethnic Croats in Croatia, unless indicated otherwise.

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

economic decisionmaking. Federal institutions proved sufficiently legitimate across both groups to contain both crises [E-F-G], avoiding the hot conflict pathway [I-J-K]. Under Tito, ‘institutionalized patterns of cooperation and mutual acceptance had become a stable part of the political landscape, allowing national excesses to be contained, defused, or even bypassed’ (Ramet, 1992: 34). The Reform Struggle of 1962–65 dashed Tito’s hope that politicized ethnicity had diminished to the point of extinction in Yugoslavia. Although the crisis revolved around economic issues, elites mobilized popular support by appealing to national identity. Nationalist rumblings emerged in the Croatian coastal town of Split over the Yugoslav central bank’s appropriation of hard-currency profits from Split’s tourist economy and over Serbian firms’ construction of large tourist hotels in the area. Addressing Split discontent in May of 1962, Tito warned of the dangers of localism, chauvinism, and national particularism, but the Croats (and Slovenes) continued to press the case. By the 1964 meeting of the Eighth Congress of the League of Communists of Yugoslavia, Croatia and Slovenia had enlisted Macedonian support for reform. Tito responded with a series of economic reforms in 1965. These included abolition of the federally controlled General Investment Fund and devolution of some power from the federal government to individual republics and their banks. The Reform Struggle thus traversed the institutional conflict pathway [E-F-G-H-MN], producing a settlement [O] in which the arbiter [H], Tito, relaxed the authority of these same institutional mechanisms to ensure continued legitimacy in the eyes of the parties. In distributing greater autonomy to the republics, Tito thereby retained the institutional conflict pathway as a peaceable alternative to hot conflict. Because this

73

04duffy (ds)

74

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 74

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

settlement did not fully address the underlying motivations, it did not resolve the conflict but instead drove it to a latency phase [O-P-A]. Demands for economic and political change would not long remain latent. They re-emerged in the Croatian Crisis of 1970–71. Although the crisis first manifested as a series of cultural demands, Croatian leaders mobilized constituents around the concern [A] that Belgrade was diverting Croatian hard-currency profits in order to develop the Serbian economy. Croat critics also charged that ethnic Serbs dominated the army officer corps, the Croatian police, and the Croatian Communist Party. By 1970, secession had become mainstream sentiment in Croatia. The Croatian Crisis would produce hot conflict, as secession demands explicitly denied legitimacy to Yugoslav political institutions [E-F-I-J-K]. Some Croats began to arm in anticipation of a showdown with the Yugoslav army [A-BC]. In November 1971, student strikes broke out in Zagreb. Tito threatened to dispatch troops to disperse strikers and prevent Croatian secession. The immediate crisis ended when Tito secured resignations of the Croatian party leadership in December 1971. Over the next several years, more than 750 Croat leaders were purged from the party, imprisoned for treason, or exiled [KO]. Leaders of the other Yugoslav republics supported Tito’s actions, arguing that Croatia had threatened their territorial integrity and economic interests. Settlements born of repression tend to harden attitudes among the repressed. During a [K-O-P-A] latency, repressed groups typically consolidate their resources and otherwise prepare to meet the repressive actions of their adversaries in future iterations of the conflict. Short of annihilation of repressed groups, then, increased levels of violence should be expected in conflict iterations after [K-O-P-A] latencies. Perhaps

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

recognizing this, Tito used the relative peace of the latency after the Croatian Crisis to address underlying Croat motivations. The Yugoslav Constitution of 1974 devolved power within the federation to an unprecedented extent. It reduced the federal jurisdiction to defense, foreign policy, and a few economic instruments. It granted to each republic its own central bank, police, courts, and schools. It stripped Serbia of its authority over the provinces of Vojvodina and Kosovo, each of which was granted power to nominate officials to federal bodies and votes in the Yugoslav Presidency. Tito borrowed heavily throughout the 1970s to bolster living standards artificially. In short, he inhibited revitalization of the conflict by making participation more costly for mass constituents and mobilization more costly for group elites. These steps helped prolong the latency, but they ultimately proved inadequate. Their success depended crucially on Tito’s presence. Owing to the force of his personality and his reputation for ruthlessness, Tito himself provided the glue that held together the fragile federation. Yugoslavia quickly unraveled after his death in 1981. Political opportunists, such as Slobodan Milošević in Serbia and Franjo Tudjman in Croatia, resurrected nationalist tensions to mobilize support for their claims to power (Woodward, 1995). In so doing, they prompted new rounds of intergroup conflict [P-A-B-C]. Descent into War, 1986–91 The post-Tito rounds of conflict revived the Croatian Crisis, latent since the early 1970s. Crushing the Croatian Spring sustained a deep-seated resentment and mistrust of the federal government in Croatia. Tudjman, who had twice been imprisoned for his role in the Crisis, rose to power on these credentials in 1990. For their part, Serbs considered the 1974 Constitution to be the beginning of

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 75

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

their downfall. Because it granted some autonomy to Kosovo and Vojvodina, many Serbs saw in the Constitution a plot to disempower them. Milošević rose to power in 1987 largely on the promise that he would regain Serbia’s lost constitutional powers, even at the expense of the Yugoslav Federation. He coordinated street protests in Vojvodina and Kosovo to support his purges of local elites and their replacement by those loyal to him. Some representatives of other republics resisted Milošević’s efforts to establish Serbian control over the Federation. The Croats and Slovenes proposed instead a loose confederation. But, by 1989, Milošević had managed to gain control of the Kosovo and Vojvodina votes. Because it already controlled Montenegro’s vote, Serbia now controlled four of the eight votes in the Presidency. With this new balance of power, Serbia could reject Croatian and Slovenian demands. It defeated every amendment to Party rules proposed by Croatia or Slovenia at the 14th Communist Party Congress in January 1990. In protest, the Slovenian delegation walked out, prompting the demise of the Yugoslav Communist Party. By the summer of 1991, both the Croatian and Slovenian publics had passed secession referenda. Both republics declared independence on 25 June 1991. The Yugoslav National Army (JNA) was dispatched to Slovenia to secure Yugoslavia’s borders. The JNA met armed resistance from the Slovenian Territorial Defense, leading to a ‘ten-day war’. The European Community, shocked by the nearby violence, threatened economic and political sanctions if the JNA did not withdraw. Whether due to this threat or to Serbia’s disinterest in retaining ethnically homogeneous Slovenia within the Yugoslav orbit, further military engagement in Slovenia appeared too costly, and the JNA withdrew [B-A]. Serbian attention turned to the growing conflict in Croatia, where ethnic Serbs

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

comprised a significant minority. Although Milošević could survive the loss of Slovenia, he could not allow Croatian secession. This would have signified sacrifice of the ambition of uniting Serbs within one state. Croatian Serbs took up arms. By September 1991, Croatia and the Serb-controlled JNA were at war. A United Nations envoy negotiated a lasting ceasefire in December 1991. Although Croatia rapidly gained widespread diplomatic recognition, by January 1992 the JNA controlled nearly one-third of its territory. It is important not to exaggerate the role of external interventions. The European Community and the United Nations, after all, failed to prevent the spread of conflict in Yugoslavia. External powers can inhibit conflict mobilization by increasing its costs to a conflicting party. However, other factors may render acquiescence to external pressure more costly to political leaders than mobilization and engagement. Much depends upon (a) the structure of incentives elites distribute in order to gain support and mobilize forces and (b) the relative difficulty elites encounter in retracting those incentives in the face of external pressure. We next discuss these incentives in the abstract, after which we illustrate their effects by reference to the Serbo-Croatian conflict.

Identity, Solidarity, and Mobilization Of the incentives that promote conflict participation, those that rely upon individuals’ personal attachments to groups are most available to political elites. They most reliably overcome the main obstacles to anyone’s participation – the risks of landing in jail, in the hospital, or in the morgue. Participation Incentives Clark & Wilson (1961; Wilson, 1973) proposed three categories of incentives that elites

75

04duffy (ds)

76

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 76

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

distribute to encourage voluntary participation: • Purposive incentives – the promise of collective goods that the action (or series of actions) is designed to produce. • Material incentives – the promise of private goods directed to individuals in return for their participation. • Solidary incentives – the promise of relational goods that individuals derive from associating with others with whom they identify. Purposive incentives cannot alone effectively mobilize constituents. Purposive incentives promise collective goods, the enjoyment of which leaders cannot exclude non-participants from. For instance, a Serb can enjoy the benefit of a ‘Greater Serbia’ regardless of her participation in efforts to consolidate it. Thus, if she calculates costs and benefits when deciding whether to participate in the conflict, she will discount purposive benefits by the likelihood that her participation will prove pivotal in providing them. Since this likelihood is infinitesimally small for each prospective participant, all will similarly discount the purposive incentives. They will ‘free-ride’, or seek to enjoy the benefits of group action without contributing to the costs of providing them. This creates a ‘free-rider problem’ for leaders. To the extent that constituents are individually rational, elites’ efforts to mobilize them will fail.2 2

As conflicts escalate, greater numbers of constituents participate, increasing the subjective likelihood that one’s participation will prove pivotal. The costs and risks of participation simultaneously decline as they are distributed across greater numbers. This suggests a ‘tipping’ effect. At some point in the history of a collective action, prospective participants’ assessments of the (discounted) collective benefits outweigh the perceived costs of participation, making participation rational and free-riding irrational. Chong (1991) holds that this resolves the longstanding ‘participation paradox’ of rational choice (Riker & Ordeshook, 1973: 57–58). But it begs the question. Given the compelling incentive to free-ride, how do collective actions escalate to a scale sufficiently large to stimulate this tipping effect?

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

Material incentives promise private goods to prospective participants in return for their participation. Elites selectively direct these goods to participants and withhold them from non-participants. Olson (1965) thus termed them ‘selective incentives’.3 In some conflict settings, leaders distribute material incentives to participants in the form of paychecks and other material benefits to soldiers and police officers. In other settings, however, leaders lack access to sufficient resources to distribute material incentives widely and must resort to the distribution of solidary incentives. They build and reinforce among constituents positive self-conceptions as members of the group, glorifying their history and extolling their virtues. Elites typically fortify a positive in-group self-conception not only in absolute terms but also relative to other groups in the environment. They denigrate, vilify, and even demonize the adversaries, stereotyping them in negative terms, and casting them as intrinsic threats to the well-being of the ingroup. They portray the conflict as a zerosum struggle of the forces of light against the forces of darkness. Even leaders who distribute material resources (e.g. state elites) often also distribute solidary incentives as a mobilization supplement (Bloom, 1990). But where leaders lack access to significant material resources, solidary incentives comprise their only means of overcoming the tendency of constituents to free-ride. In issuing solidary incentives, leaders encourage others to distribute ‘relational consumption goods’ (Uhlaner, 1989) – or interpersonal payoffs participants receive from personal associates. Chief among these payoffs is social approval. Actions that further the attainment of group goals evoke 3

Because material goods are directable to participants, withholdable from non-participants, and retractable once leaders no longer desire constituent participation, selective incentives tend in practice to be realized as material goods. Nevertheless, the two are not strictly coextensive.

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 77

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

the approval of others significant to the participant, thereby strengthening the bonds individuals feel with respect to these others and to the wider group. Leaders who distribute solidary incentives through their communications to constituents count upon the amplification of their message in the social networks that surround each individual constituent (Coleman, 1990: 277; Tilly, 1978: 62–64; White, 1992: 60–64).4 Relational investment goods refer to expectations of future material payoffs that participants hope to receive from leaders. Prospective participants discount them by the perceived probability that leaders will observe their participation. On the assumption of methodological individualism – that one may describe social outcomes as the emergent product of individual choices – public choice theorists construe political mobilization as the aggregation of individual participation decisions. The participation decision for any prospective participant takes the form of Equation 1. If a prospective participant believes A to be positive, the total benefits of participation outweigh the costs (C ). If she believes the costs to outweigh those benefits, then A is negative and she does not participate. A = pp B – C + S + Rc + po Ri

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

S are the (generally material) goods that leaders selectively distribute only to participants; Rc are relational consumption goods that leaders distribute by issuing solidary incentives to prospective participants; Ri are relational investment goods that prospective participants hope to realize after a successful collective action in recognition of their participation; and po is the discount rate of Ri, or the probability that group leaders observe one’s participation. Absent relational and/or material goods, rational prospective participants lack any reason to participate. They would discount the collective benefits B by the probability of pivotalness pp, since leaders cannot exclude them from enjoying B should the collective action succeed. Because pp is infinitesimally small in mass mobilization contexts, ppB is effectively zero. The costs C always outweigh ppB = 0, and rational prospective participants all free-ride. Selective incentives and relational goods were introduced precisely to explain observed participation in the light of the otherwise compelling incentive to freeride. Equation 2 presents the rational participation model after the removal of the effectively zero ppB.

(1) A = S + Rc + po Ri – C

where: A is the net benefit of participation; B are the collective benefits of participation (about which leaders distribute purposive incentives); pp is the discount rate of B, or the probability that one’s participation will prove pivotal in securing B; C are the costs of participation; 4 Relational consumption goods may also be material. What distinguishes relational consumption goods from the material goods typically distributed as selective incentives is not their materiality or immateriality. Rather, it is the fact that they are side-payments not directly under the control of the leaders who encouraged their distribution.

(2)

Note that political issues escape the rational calculation. These all are incorporated into the collective good, B, which rational individuals discount by pp. This implies, perversely, that decisions regarding participation in political action in no way concern political issues. To resolve this problem, we suggest that solidary incentives interact with purposive incentives. Persons moved by solidary incentives derive their selfconceptions from their social identifications with the group. As a consequence, they come to see group benefits as personal benefits.

77

04duffy (ds)

78

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 78

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

There can be, for such persons, no possibility of free-riding, as they have so tightly bound their personal identities to their groups that they find their fate inextricably intertwined with the fates of their groups. This suggestion, if correct, implies two additional observations. A sociological observation concerns settlement. For a strong group identifier, any accommodation to the demonized enemy constitutes an affront to her personal sense of well-being. For this reason, leaders who distribute solidary incentives at mobilization time find their action possibilities severely constrained at settlement time. Although a great deal of experimental evidence confirms the importance of group identification in individual decisionmaking (Tajfel, 1981, 1984a; Tajfel & Turner, 1979; Turner, 1984, 1987), the psychological processes by which elite-inspired and communityreinforced feelings of solidarity overwhelm the propensity to free-ride have not been described with any precision. But the process appears to encourage participants to adopt group purposes as their own, thereby enhancing the effectiveness of purposive incentives. Once actors perceive group benefits as personal benefits, free-riding amounts to self-abnegation. A methodological observation concerns the enterprise of understanding political mobilization as the aggregation of individual decisions. Our account undermines the assumption of methodological individualism on which public choice accounts depend. One can argue, of course, that choice theorists have always understood the fictive status of this assumption. They posit it only as a methodological convenience that allows analyses to proceed. It can be relaxed under warranted circumstances, like this one. But the implication remains: to the extent that leaders distribute solidary incentives to mobilize constituents, individualist analyses that do not address intergroup and

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

intragroup dynamics likely will fail to illuminate. Participation Incentives in the SerboCroatian War Both Tudjman and Milošević distributed solidary incentives to mobilize constituents around their nationalist agendas. They endeavored to convince constituents of the inevitable link between their individual destinies and the fates of their nations. The strategy had three components: (1) identify and stigmatize a national enemy; (2) unite the nation against this threat; and (3) call for resistance. State-controlled media were integral to the implementation of this strategy. Milošević’s nationalist agenda centered around the traditional Serbian slogan, ‘Samo Sloga Srbina Spašava’ [Only Unity Saves the Serbs]. He promised to unite Serbs dispersed throughout Yugoslavia whose fate he claimed Croat or Muslim majorities threatened. Kosovo Albanians became the first enemies he mobilized against. Conflicts between Kosovo’s Albanian Muslim majority and its minority Serb population had intensified since Kosovo gained increased autonomy after 1968. Kosovar Serbs complained of harrassments, forced relocations, and even rape and murder (Banac, 1992). For Serbs, growing independence demands from Kosovar Albanians threatened the loss of what they considered the birthplace of their nation. In April 1987, the Communist leadership tasked Milošević, then a relatively unknown party official, to end violent demonstrations of Kosovar Serbs, who protested alleged oppression by Kosovar Albanians. When Milošević encountered Serb protesters, he did not seek to pacify them. Instead he saluted them, declaring ‘No one should dare to beat you again’ (Popov, 1995: 94). A 1986 memorandum by 200 members of the Serbian Academy of Arts and Sciences gave intellectual momentum to

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 79

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

Milošević’s rise to power as protector and unifier of all Serbs. The document argued that Serbian existence was threatened in Yugoslavia, particularly those Serbs living in Kosovo, who were facing ‘genocide’ (Magaš, 1993: 51), and Serbs living in Croatia who had ‘never been as endangered as they are today’ (Woodward, 1995: 7). Under his 1990 slogan, ‘Odlučimo sami o našoj sudbini’ [We will decide our fate by ourselves], Tudjman mobilized Croats around a historic quest for self-determination. Tudjman rose to power on the promise that he would restore Croatian national pride and reverse the discriminations that Croats allegedly suffered in Yugoslavia. His project included ending Serbian overrepresentation in Croatia’s state administration, reviving Croatian cultural symbols, producing a constitution that made Croatia a state of the Croatian nation, and establishing the Croatian language and Latin script as official modes of discourse (Hislope, 1996: 476). Tudjman and Milošević coexisted symbiotically. By dismissing them from official positions and prohibiting the use of Cyrillic script, Tudjman readied ethnic Serbs to accept Milošević’s politics of crisis and fear. Likewise, Tudjman’s resurrection of symbols that Croatia had used during World War II, when it was a Nazi quisling state, aided Milošević’s efforts to mobilize constituents. It reminded them of that regime’s attempted wartime genocide against the Serbs (see Mirkovic, 2000; Verdery, 1999: 99–102). Conversely, earlier misgivings among some Croats toward Tudjman’s nationalism dissipated once Milošević dispatched JNA troops to prevent Croatia’s secession. As Croatian national television aired the first casualty reports, Croats united around a fear of the other – the Serbs. The state-controlled press in both Serbia and Croatia played instrumental roles in the distribution of solidary incentives. The

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

Serbian press urged unity in defense of ethnic Serbs in Kosovo and Croatia with such newspaper headlines as ‘Scenes from 50 Years Ago Repeated as Croatian Ustase Attack the Serb People’ or, in a drive for volunteers, ‘Let’s Go and Protect our People’ and ‘Time for Unity’. Radio Television Serbia (RTS) portrayed Serbs as ‘fighting for freedom’ or ‘defending’ and ‘guarding’ their ‘native soil’ against ‘Ustase’ and ‘Islamic fundamentalists’ (Thompson, 1994: 76–78, 102, 128). The Croatian press portrayed the conflict similarly, except that it characterized Serbs as aggressors and Croats as defenders (Malešić, 1993: 34–35, 181). In 1991, the Croatian government decreed that television announcers would refer to opposition Serbs as ‘Serb terrorists’, ‘rebel Serbs’, ‘bandits’, ‘Chetniks’, and ‘Serbian aggressors’ and to accompany casualty figures with such partisan ascriptions as ‘gave their lives to defend the homeland’ or ‘fell for Croatia’s freedom’ (Uzelak, 1998: 463). Material incentives to action often accompanied the solidary ones. To attract participants for protests designed to destabilize party leaders during Milošević’s rise to power, Yugoslav secret police worked behind the scenes to recruit crowds from factories and workplaces (Silber & Little, 1996: 59). Thousands of workers were bussed in from provincial factories and rewarded with food and payment in exchange for their support of Milošević and his nationalist program. ‘Ethnic cleansing’ later became an effective inducement to action that combined material and solidary incentives. The practice usually proceeded as follows: an irregular militia unit would enter a town or village, give residents two hours to pack their possessions, destroy all evidence of their legal claims to the property, and then allow them (sometimes excluding men between 16 and 50) to flee. Militia members would then claim the property for themselves, often scrawling their names above doorways.

79

04duffy (ds)

80

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 80

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

Ethnic cleansing thus served two purposes. First, it eradicated all traces of the other, helping to ‘purify’ the nation-state. This was particularly important to the nationalist projects in both countries, as the boundaries between ‘us’ and ‘them’ permeated villages and often ran through the middle of families. The need to legitimate statehood in ethnic terms entailed the exile or eradication of anyone living within the territorial boundaries of the state who did not share the ethnicity of the hegemonizing group (Bowman, 1994: 149). As a second, often overlooked, purpose, ethnic cleansing provided material rewards to militia members. Many enriched themselves (Dezulovic, 1995: 6). The testimony of Miro Bajramović, a Croat soldier who served in a Croatian special military unit during the 1991–92 fighting in eastern Slavonia, highlights both the mobilization effectiveness of solidary incentives and the material profitability of the murder and mayhem they were mobilized to commit. ‘In those days’, stated Bajramović, ‘I had absolutely no feeling that Serbs were people like us, that they were somebody’s fathers, brothers, children’, illustrating the effective dehumanization of the enemy. Bajramović describes the profitability of ethnic cleansing. Great avarice reigned at the time. About 30 of us went 50 meters ahead of the first tank, we mopped up and rubbed out anybody we bumped into. Behind us went some who were known as merčepovci [Tomislav Merčep’s men], who robbed and burned the houses . . . Merčep told us to take everything from the Serbs but that we had to hand over the money we found in their houses to headquarters, for buying weapons. But Trusic, Merčep, [and others] split the money into equal shares among themselves . . . and we aren’t talking here about 1,000 or 100,000 German marks, but much, much more. (Bajramović, 1997)

On the basis of this confession, Bajramović and three fellow soldiers were indicted for crimes against humanity. They

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

await trial at the International Criminal Tribunal for the Former Yugoslavia (ICTY) in The Hague. Bajramović’s confession flowed from no feeling of guilt or remorse. He claimed to be motivated by the failure of the prison commander – who had directed the killings and who now owns several restaurants seized from Serbs – to share the profits as he had promised. Bajramović was not necessarily dissatisfied by the sense of solidarity and social approval, relational consumption goods, he had gained from his war service. He just expected an accompanying material payoff. In combining solidary and material incentives, Serb and Croat elites created an environment productive of horrendous atrocities. Their vilifications and demonizations revived ethnic animosities that Tito’s Federation had sublimated. The material incentives they added into their mix of inducements to collective action prompted mass rapes, death camps, and ethnic cleansing. By separating the out-group from their property by whatever means, however inhumane, soldiers and civilians engaged in these actions claimed that property as their own. The obscenity of these practices is compounded by the sight of newly wealthy Croat and Serb conflict participants now roaming freely through their respective capitals in new fur coats and BMWs.

Producing Peace In November 1995, leaders of Croatia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, and Serbia met at a US Air Force base outside Dayton, Ohio, to negotiate a settlement of conflicts in Bosnia and Croatia. After ten days of intense talks, they agreed to a ‘General Framework Agreement on Peace’ (node [N] in Figure 1), or the Dayton Peace Accords (United States, 1995). An international Implementation Force (IFOR) was dispatched to Bosnia and Herzegovina to perform constabulary tasks, and

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 81

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

the United Nations established a ‘transitional administration’ in Eastern Croatia. The violence quickly abated. After several years of Western hand-wringing over Balkans war atrocities, the international community’s intervention altered the cost calculations of Balkan political elites. External intervention made continuation of hot conflict infeasible, at least in the short term. Peace prospects are more uncertain over the longer term. Dayton did not resolve the conflict but only directed it into a temporary latency [O-P-A]. Lasting resolution can come about only with the removal of the underlying motivations for conflict [O-P-Q]. Once the international community removes its troops, as ultimately it must, their stabilizing effects may well be lost. The conflict only deepened longstanding ethnic animosities in the region. Future leaders who seek to rally popular support will be tempted to distribute solidary incentives by exploiting these animosities. Just as the dissolution of the Yugoslav Federation revived ethnic animosities and thereby re-ignited a long-dormant ethnic conflict, so too might the withdrawal of the NATO-led international Stabilization Force (SFOR). Distributions of material incentives are readily stopped. One might, for instance, deny conflictual leaders material resources to distribute. One might compete with conflictual leaders by distributing material incentives to their constituents in return for their nonparticipation in conflict. Or, one might distribute to potentially conflictual leaders material disincentives, such as threats of military intervention and prosecution. But how would one prevent distributions of solidary incentives? Retraction of Solidary Incentives Negotiated settlements more likely fail in civil wars with ethnic cleavages (Licklider, 1995), in which we expect solidary incentives to have been distributed most widely.

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

We attribute this observation to the solidary incentive retraction problem: Although elites can distribute solidary incentives inexpensively in order to mobilize constituents, they often discover later, when they wish to demobilize, that they have greatly constrained their own action possibilities. Having successfully demonized their adversaries, they now find it difficult to persuade constituents of the wisdom of settlement. Typically, constituents view any accommodation to the out-group as a betrayal of the in-group. This perception provides hardliner cadres with the opportunity to mobilize factional opposition to the incumbent leadership. Recognizing this, incumbents often refrain from settling even when they believe settlement to be in the group’s interest. Thus, the distribution of solidary incentives in the mobilization phase inhibits demobilization in the settlement phase and thereby contributes to the protractedness of conflict. Of course, some leaders concern themselves less with maintaining their incumbency than with producing optimal outcomes for their constituents. When they determine that prospective settlement terms enhance their constituents’ prospects, they may forge ahead with settlement efforts despite the risks. Such leaders generally seek to minimize hardliner opposition by negotiating secretly or at least without fanfare and great publicity. Israeli Prime Minister Yitzak Rabin put this quite frankly at a 1993 press conference at the White House: We have found that direct and quiet contacts between Israel and its partners in the effort to achieve a comprehensive peace is the best way to overcome prejudices of the past. The less the talks are exposed to the limelight of the media, the better are the chances to achieve agreements. (United States, 1993)

Yet, even if they quietly come to an agreement with their adversaries, these leaders must eventually persuade their constituents

81

04duffy (ds)

82

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 82

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

to accept its terms. They risk failed demobilization factional conflict ([M-N-T]), as ambitious hardliners may see their ‘betrayal’ of group interests as an opportunity to challenge incumbents for their leadership positions (Horowitz, 1985: 342–359). As hardliner opposition to settlement mounts within the group, incumbents expose themselves not only to electoral challenge, but potentially also to assassination – a fate that befell Anwar Sadat in 1981 and then Rabin in 1995. Distributions of solidary incentives to mobilize conflict participation thus limit the opportunities for later settlements and diminish the likelihood that settlements will succeed. Solidary incentives, by manipulating the group regarding personal identities of mass political constituents, help to produce conflict and also to prevent peace. What practical strategies can leaders employ to demobilize constituents previously mobilized by means of solidary incentives? Some might argue for mass education (or reeducation) at the sites or potential sites of protracted conflicts. On this view, didactic effort may diminish the tendency for persons to cognize about social reality in terms of the stereotypical prejudices of learned social representations. When people perceive social reality as it really is, so this argument might run, political leaders would be unable to exploit social stereotypes when they seek to mobilize mass political constituencies for conflict. Hopefully, we erect a straw man here, for this strategy is painfully naive. Social representations perform a necessary function. They are not superstitions that one can educate into submission. Social representations help make complex political realities sensible to persons who lack the disposable time and other resources needed to obtain and process quality political information. Moreover, social representations and group identity contribute to the implementation of

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

settlements. By establishing cognitive categories within which individuals make social comparisons – distinguishing their comrades from others they might encounter (Turner, 1987: 46–49) – social representations promote among group members a sense of responsibility toward each other and reinforce the consensual beliefs and attitudes necessary for group functioning. They instill in individuals a readiness to be influenced by the group. Just as intragroup communication and the attainment of group goals foster group cohesion, social representations reciprocally fortify the group cohesion needed to ensure intragroup communication and the attainment of group goals. So, while the cohesion born of social representations and group identity enables political leaders to distribute solidary incentives for mobilizing constituents for conflict, it also supports the communication and collective goal orientations required for the formation of group consensus on the terms of settlements and on the goal of implementing them (Deutsch, 1973: 72–73). If peacemakers cannot eliminate social representations, perhaps they can alter their contents. Persons draw upon a variety of idiosyncratic and social elements as they construct their personal identities. Political leaders might emphasize identity elements that differ from those salient to the conflict, diverting attention from the divisions along which they had earlier distributed solidary incentives. Of course, the effectiveness of this strategy hinges upon the presence of crosscutting cleavages. But communities with such cleavages are least apt to generate violent and longstanding conflicts in the first place. Also, ambitious hardliners must collaborate with incumbents in pursuing this strategy. They are unlikely to do so, however, because they would effectively abandon a route to their own ascent to leadership. Incumbents might repress hardliners to prevent them from spoiling the strategy, but this might

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 83

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

only initiate the factional conflict the incumbents seek to avoid. One may change the contents of social representations by introducing ‘superordinate goals’ in the community, or goals that require concerted collective action across groups. Under this strategy, derived from the celebrated ‘robbers’ cave’ experiment (Sherif et al., 1961), conflicting parties would be induced to set aside mutual grievances in order to focus on attainment of goals valued across groups. While worth pursuing, there is reason to believe this strategy would prove ineffective. Superordinate goals fostered intergroup cooperation among the Sherifs’ 11-year-olds, but their solidarity had existed only a few days. The result may not apply among adults in communities where solidarity has persisted over generations.5 Quasi-therapeutic encounter sessions or ‘dialogue groups’ among grassroots constituents across groups have been proposed as a means of reformulating or derigidifying stereotypes in solidary conflict settings (Northrup, 1989; Schwartz, 1989). This proposal rests upon the ‘contact hypothesis’ – the idea that intergroup tensions can be reduced by exposing group identifiers to positive experiences with out-group members. Unfortunately, the nature of social attribution conspires against the contact hypothesis, producing resistance as a strategy for reducing cognitive dissonance. When exposed to the counter-stereotypical behavior of out-group members, in-group members avoid cognitive upset by attributing positive experiences with out-group members to factors particular to those individuals and uncharacteristic of out-group members generally (Hewstone, 1989: 199–203). Only when exposed to positive or counter-stereotypical behavior on the part of out-group members 5

Richard Braungart (personal communication), once a student of the Sherifs, reports that the introduction of a superordinate goal only temporarily suspended intergroup animus among the Sherifs’ subjects.

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

whom they regard as typical can counterstereotypical contacts contribute to reconciliation. Research on natural categorization demonstrates amply that the contents of abstract categories tend to overrepresent properties drawn from prototypes, or salient exemplars in individuals’ experiences (Rosch 1978, 1983; Mervis & Rosch, 1981). In the sharply segregated societies characteristic of community conflict, mass constituents find the most ready prototypes in group leaders and their mass-mediated representations. Even where competing groups interact at the street level, leaders likely remain the most salient, prototypical exemplars of their group. We can conjecture, then, that repeated presentations over time of counterstereotypical behaviors of group elites and counter-stereotypical public characterizations of group elites by one another might most effectively counteract the conflictprotracting effects of social representations within solidary constituencies. Conjectures being what they are, we cannot offer definitive conclusions regarding the effectiveness of counter-stereotypical presentations of elitescum-prototypes. Nevertheless, we believe the idea merits systematic study and perhaps even practical trial in a naturalistic setting. Whatever the mix of strategies employed to retract solidary incentives or at least minimize their continuing impact, efforts to produce peace between divided solidary constituencies will always prove arduous. The ‘peace process’ will take various twists and turns and alternatively suffer setbacks and make gains, particularly when hardliners across groups find it in their interest to erect barriers to its progress. While research is needed to develop effective strategies to combat the conflict-sustaining effects of previously distributed solidary incentives, practical steps can and should be taken to educate future leaders of divided communities of the dangers. They should understand,

83

04duffy (ds)

84

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 84

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

before they accede to leadership positions, that they may find the distribution of solidary incentives can provide them with short-term tactical advantage. But they should also understand that exploiting this advantage poses severe longer-term dangers, both to their constituents and to themselves. Demobilization, 1995–2000 After Dayton, Croat and Serb leaders found themselves in a nested game. They were forced to respond to the external demobilization pressures of the international community to settle [M-N-O], as they sought simultaneously to mollify the internal pressures of domestic hardliners. Failure to satisfy them risked factional conflict [M-N-T] and possibly new rounds of conflict mobilization [T-U-A-B-C]. Such competing pressures can motivate leader actions that appear incoherent to outsiders, as they sometimes promote and at other times prevent movement toward lasting peace. In both Serbia and Croatia, these competing demands appeared in three contexts as conflict elites considered the terms of Dayton [N]: 1. Normalization of Relations In August 1996, Serbia and Croatia agreed to normalize diplomatic relations. The Serb-controlled eastern region of Croatia would return to Croatia proper and Serb refugees expelled from the Krajina would be allowed to return to Croatia as full citizens. Tudjman and Milošević each promoted the agreement as a victory for their respective national interests. But hardliners in both states viewed the agreement as treasonous. Vojislav Šešelj, an accused war criminal and ultranational leader of the Serbian Radical Party, excoriated Milošević for treason and capitulation. Serbian Democratic Party leader Zoran Djindjic blasted the agreement as a personal policy that Milošević purchased for his own benefit at the expense of the Serbian nation

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

as a whole. Hardliner Croats also opposed the agreement. Croat columnist Srečko Jurdana characterized normalization as ‘a handshake over Croatian graves and the destruction of Croatian culture’ (Krause & Markotich, 1996: 52–55). 2. Cooperation with the War Crimes Tribunal Nationalist elites also face hardliner resistance to the Dayton requirement that they submit war criminals and material evidence to the International Criminal Tribunal for the former Yugoslavia (ICTY). Although Milošević formally agreed at Dayton to cooperate with the ICTY, the Yugoslav government provided little assistance in capturing Bosnian-Serb war criminals, who traveled freely within the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia while Milošević held power. Milošević’s occasional promises to hand over Bosnian Serbs Mladić and Karadžić to the tribunal often triggered destabilizing backlashes within the ultranationalist ruling circles that controlled Republika Srpska and maintained influential positions in many institutions of the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia, especially the military (Markotich, 1996: 35–36). Milošević’s successor Koštunica has also shown reluctance to support the ICTY. He rejected Milošević’s extradition, denying ICTY’s legal authority and declaring it a ‘common tool of political pressure’ (Buden, 2000). Tudjman’s cooperation with the ICTY, although only partial and induced under extreme international pressures, likewise cost him political support in Croatia. Ante Djapić, president of the radical nationalist Croatian Party of Right, voiced the most extreme resistance. In 1998, Djapić called for the Croatian army to seize power to protect Croatian sovereignty in the event that Croatian army generals were extradited to The Hague. In a September 1997 poll, 59% expressed the view that Croat soldiers could not have committed war crimes because they

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 85

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

were waging a defensive war against Serbian aggression (Hedl, 1997). The post-Tudjman regime also faces hardliner opposition to cooperation with the ICTY. After enactment of a ‘Law on Cooperation with the Hague Tribunal’ in Spring 2000, which sanctioned a nationwide effort to arrest Croats accused of war crimes, 12 generals of the Croatian army warned the new administration not to devalue the Croat war against Serbs. The nationalist HDZ party supported the generals and called on Croats at home and in the diaspora to overthrow the ‘anti-Croatian Communist government’ (Perica, 2000). In February 2001, hundreds of thousands of Croats gathered in Split to protest the post-Tudjman government’s indictment of General Mirko Novac for the executions of Serb civilians in 1991. 3. Relations with the Constituent Republics in Bosnia and Herzegovina Under Dayton, both Tudjman and Milošević pledged to help halt the war they each had fostered in Bosnia. They committed themselves to end arms shipments, to refuse recognition to the Bosnian-Serb state of Republika Srpska and the Bosnian-Croat state of Herceg-Bosnia, and to aid the capture of Bosnian-Croat and Bosnian-Serb war criminals. Milošević publicly severed ties with Republika Srpska. He convinced the Serbian public that the benefits they might enjoy from the successes of Bosnian Serbs and attaining the goal of ‘Greater Serbia’ could never outweigh the costs of making Serbia an international pariah. As the Bosnian Serbs became a political liability for Milošević, he increasingly blamed them for the war and for Serbia’s economic and political isolation. Tudjman found it more difficult to distance himself from the Bosnian Croats. Tudjman had long argued for Croatia’s jurisdiction over Bosnia (see Tudjman, 1981). He had fostered nationalist factions in Bosnia

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

and Herzegovina that wanted to annex Herzegovina and portions of Bosnia to Croatia proper. Tudjman eventually recognized that the international community would not accept a seizure of Bosnian territory. Still, he could not abandon the Bosnian Croats. Radical Herzegovinian Croats provided much of the financial backing of the HDZ and held a disproportionately large share of political and economic power in Croatia (Culic, 1996: 31–32). Tudjman consequently vacillated in response to the competing pressures of the international community and the Herzegovinian Croats. But this pleased no one. His critics in the democratic Croat opposition would become infuriated whenever he took actions they interpreted as capitulation to the Bosnian Croats. They would complain of his transfer of scarce state funds to the impoverished region and argue that his policies jeopardized Croatia’s already tenuous relationships with the West. His critics to the right would become enraged whenever they believed Tudjman to be abandoning the Bosnian Croats. Hardliner critics, such as Croatian Party of the Right founder Dobraslav Paraga, called for Tudjman’s resignation when he attempted to do so. The international community has relied on both incentives and disincentives to encourage Serb and Croat leaders to implement the terms of the Dayton Agreement. Disincentives include exclusion from international bodies and regional associations, trade sanctions, diplomatic isolation, and even the threat of military intervention. Incentives include the promise of international loans and grants for reconstruction, offers to join European Union accession talks, and general recognition that these nations belong to European or Western civilization. Dependence on the West, not merely for its approval but also for economic and political survival, fuels a certain amount of backlash against Western in influence. Hardliners

85

04duffy (ds)

86

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 86

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

invoke the threat of Western domination as a solidary incentive to mobilize constituent support. Hardliner Maja Freundlich, in the main state-run daily in the Tudjman era, responded to Western threats of economic sanctions against Croatia: The Croatian government faces a threat from the world to its sovereignty and survival. The Croatian state finds itself confronting the same challenge as in 1991. The diplomatic war is no less dangerous than armed warfare. Just as the Croatian people gathered and defended itself, the Croatian state today has the same duty; gather its people in defense of their very survival. (Freundlich, 1997: 4)

Hardliners demonize the West in order to criticize incumbent national elites for caving to Western mandates. For instance, Serb hardliner Vojislav Šešelj remarked, when casting his ballot in the October 1997 elections, that his victory would ‘annul any possibility of Serbia kneeling before any Western power’. Nationalist elites, in turn, invoke anti-Western rhetoric to inoculate themselves from the hardliner critique. For instance, responding to student protests in December 1996, Milošević publicly warned demonstrators that ‘we must be completely clear: no matter how often your leaders go to foreign embassies and travel to world capitals, a foreign hand shall not rule Serbia’ (Markotich, 1997: 42). The Western powers have established the prospect of Western integration and recognition as a superordinate goal in the postDayton context. Its effectiveness as a lever for pressuring political leaders in the Balkans depends crucially upon the extent to which these leaders and their domestic allies and adversaries consider it attainable. Western leaders thus must perform a delicate balancing act. Too little pressure will encourage the view that low-level ethnic war can be pursued without endangering integration prospects. Too much pressure will encourage the view that integration is unattainable. In that case, domestic hardliners could

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002

successfully challenge incumbents, prompting destabilization and failed-demobilization factional conflict (node [T] in Figure 1), thereby increasing the likelihood of a decision to scrap Dayton in favor of revived ethnic warfare.

Conclusions The Balkan wars demonstrate that political leaders can distribute solidary incentives to promote political participation among their constituents. By glorifying the group and demonizing its enemies, leaders encourage their constituents to tie their personal fates to the fate of the larger group. Solidary incentives, in interaction with purposive incentives, inhibit the propensity of constituents to free-ride on the group’s collective actions. The case indicates also that solidary incentives interact with and enhance the effects of material incentives. To the extent that one buys into leaders’ demonizations of group adversaries, one can rationalize one’s involvement in non-generalizable activities – like ethnic cleansing. Solidary incentives thus comprise a powerful and relatively costless mobilization tool. It is important to recognize, however, that political leaders can use solidary incentives for good or ill. The experience also illustrates the difficulty of retracting solidary incentives when leaders wish to settle conflicts. When leaders find settlement to be in their interest – whether or not powerful external actors impose this interest upon them – their efforts to retract solidary incentives strengthen the hands of hardliner cadres who wish to continue the conflict and/or topple the incumbents. However effective distributions of solidary incentives had proven at mobilization time, leaders discover that they powerfully constrain their action possibilities at settlement time. In conflict settings, distributions of solidary incentives not only promote violent outbreaks, they also inhibit peaceful resolutions.

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 87

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom

The case further illustrates the delicate nature of international efforts to defuse ethnic conflicts. The deployment of international peacekeeping troops and monitors in 1995 ended hot conflict in Bosnia and forestalled it in Slavonia. The superordinate goal offered to leaders and their constituents – prospective integration into supranational Western institutions – has encouraged governments in the Balkans to accede to the demands of the international community. Yet, domestic political leaders can accede only so far before hardliners challenge their actions as treachery against the solidarity the leaders had themselves so skillfully cultivated. This poses a dilemma for leaders. They can either continue to push the policies that external actors demand of them and thereby suffer the wrath of domestic hardliners, or they can accede to the hardliners and suffer the approbation of the international community. In reviving the cause of preventing Kosovo’s secession from Yugoslavia, Milošević opted for the latter. As in Bosnia, Milošević combined solidary incentives with ethnic cleansing as a material incentive, this time against ethnic Albanian Kosovars. After Milošević rejected the Rambouillet settlement in February 1999, NATO responded with a massive bombing campaign against Yugoslavia. Milošević withdrew Yugoslav forces from Kosovo early the following June. Whatever its contribution to Milošević’s downfall the following year, the bombing also strengthened domestic hardliners and provided them with new enemies to demonize – NATO and its constituent states. Milošević’s successors face political constraints similar to those that Milošević faced and that prompted his actions in Kosovo and elsewhere. The West is now concerned with how it might alter those contingencies to promote Serbian conformity to international norms. Peace prospects are somewhat brighter in

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

Croatia. Tudjman’s death in December 1999 and the victory of Social Democrats in the January 2000 parliamentary elections diminished the influence of Croat nationalist hardliners. The hardliner strategy of stigmatizing opposition parties as ‘dupes of the West’ and ‘traitors to the nation’ failed in the parliamentary campaign. Growing divisions between moderate and hardliner factions now threaten the cohesion and viability of Tudjman’s nationalist party (HDZ). Although the Social Democrats have not entirely abandoned nationalist appeals, they appear to have successfully shifted public debate around social over nationalist concerns. The international community has rewarded Croatia for abiding by Dayton. Less than a year after Tudjman’s death, Croatia gained admission to the World Trade Organization and began official talks with the EU on a Stabilization and Association Agreement, the first step towards EU membership. However, the Croatian military, some veterans’ associations, and nationalist parties continue to try to derail Croatia’s cooperation with the ICTY. This signals that the new Croat leadership faces significant hardliner opposition to any capitulation to the West. Given the depth of ethnic animosities, the latent conflict in Bosnia and Herzegovina may re-erupt once SFOR withdraws. Bosnians can avoid hot conflict by erecting political institutions that each ethnic group finds legitimate. However, a number of political conditions have hindered this process. Nationalist Bosnian Serb and Bosnian Croatian parties have consistently blocked efforts to develop effective central institutions. Although financial, military, and political support from Belgrade and Zagreb has decreased, nationalists across both ethnicities sustain hopes of eventual political unification with their respective titular states. Because it provides for group rights and ethnic representation in Bosnia,

87

04duffy (ds)

88

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 88

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H

the Dayton constitution itself obstructs peace (Western & Serwer, 2000). Pressures on Croatia and Serbia to cut ties with their ethnic counterparts in Bosnia diminish material incentives for conflict. However, they cannot guarantee that Bosnian Serb and Bosnian Croat nationalists will not again produce conflict and seek secession. Although a necessary condition for lasting peace, cross-ethnically legitimate political institutions would not suffice. Lasting peace requires a political leadership that understands the dangers inherent in mobilizing constituents around solidary incentives and that undertakes to transmit that understanding to succeeding generations of political leaders. In developing their political institutions, Bosnians should consider designs that require political leaders across ethnicities to coordinate with one another and thereby provide them the incentive to treat one another publicly with mutual dignity and respect. Such counter-stereotypical acts could create a profoundly positive demonstration effect among the ordinary Bosnians who witness them. References Bajramović, Miro, 1997. ‘Kako smo ubijali u Pakraćkoj Poljani’ [How We Killed in Pakraćka Poljana], Feral Tribune, 1 September: 15. Translation in Tatić (1997). Banac, Ivo, 1992. ‘Post-Communism as PostYugoslavism: The Yugoslav Non-Revolutions of 1989–1990’, in Ivo Banac, ed., Eastern Europe in Revolution. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press (168–187). Banac, Ivo, 1994. The National Question in Yugoslavia. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Bloom, William, 1990. Personal Identity, National Identity, and International Relations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bowman, Glen, 1994. ‘Xenophobia, Fantasy and the Nation: The Logic of Ethnic Violence in Former Yugoslavia’, in Victoria Goddard,

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002 Josep R. Llobera & Chris Shore, eds, The Anthropology of Europe. Oxford: Berge (143–172). Buden, Boris, 2000. ‘Srbima ne treba zavidjeti’ [We Should Not Be Envious of the Serbs], Vjesnik (17 October): 3. Burg, Steven, 1983. Conflict and Cohesion in Socialist Yugoslavia. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Chong, Dennis, 1991. Collective Action and the Civil Rights Movement. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Clark, Peter B. & James Q. Wilson, 1961. ‘Incentive Systems: A Theory of Organizations’, Administrative Science Quarterly 6 (September): 129–166. Cohen, Lenard J., 1983. Political Cohesion in a Fragile Mosaic. Boulder, CO: Westview. Coleman, James S., 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Culic, Marinko, 1996. ‘Herzegovinian Croats Steer Croatian Politics’, Transition 2(14): 31–32. Dessler, David, 1991. ‘Beyond Correlations: Toward a Causal Theory of War’, International Studies Quarterly 35(3): 337–355. Deutsch, Morton, 1973. The Resolution of Conflict. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Dezulovic, Boris, 1995. ‘The Great Mover’, Feral Tribune, 11 September: 4. Dragnich, Alex, 1992. Serbs and Croats. New York: Harcourt Brace. Duffy, Gavan & Nathalie J. Frensley, 1991. ‘Community Conflict Processes: Mobilization and Demobilization in Northern Ireland’, in James W. Lamare, ed., International Crisis and Domestic Politics. New York: Praeger (99–135). Durkheim, Emile, 1947. The Elementary Forms of the Religious Life. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. [First French edition published in 1915.] Frensley, Nathalie J., 1998. ‘Ratification Processes and Conflict Termination’, Journal of Peace Research 35(2): 167–191. Frensley, Nathalie J., 2000. ‘Identity Variability and Ratification in Northern Ireland Peace Settlements’. Typescript, University of Nevada, Las Vegas. Fruendlich, Maja, 1997. ‘Plan Povratka Hrvata’, Vjesnik, Zagreb, 17 May: 4.

04duffy (ds)

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 89

Gava n Du ffy & Nicol e Linds trom Hall, John R., 1999. Cultures of Inquiry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hedl, Drago, 1997. ‘Who Will Bear the Consequences?’, Transitions 4(6): 16–17. Hewstone, Miles, 1989. Causal Attribution. London: Blackwell. Hislope, Robert, 1996. ‘Intra-Ethnic Conflict in Croatia and Serbia’, East European Quarterly 30(4): 471–494. Horowitz, Donald, 1985. Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Krause, Stefan & Stan Markotich, 1996. ‘Belgrade and Zagreb Inch Toward Recognition’, Transition 2(20): 52–55. Kriesberg, Louis; Terrell A. Northrup & Stuart J. Thorson, eds, 1989. Intractable Conflicts and their Transformation. Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press. Licklider, Roy, 1995. ‘The Consequences of Negotiated Settlements in Civil Wars, 1945–1993’, American Political Science Review 89(3): 681–690. Magaš, Branka, 1993. The Destruction of Yugoslavia. New York: Verso. Malešić, Marjan, 1993. ‘The Role of Mass-Media in the Serbian-Croatian Conflict’, Report 164. Stockholm: Styrelsen För Psykologiskt Försvar. Markotich, Stan, 1996. ‘Belgrade Unwilling to Arrest War Criminals’, Transition 2(14): 35–36. Markotich, Stan, 1997. ‘Backtracking Toward Dictatorship in Serbia and Montenegro’, Transition 3(2): 41–44. Mervis, Carolyn B. & Eleanor Rosch, 1981. ‘Categorization of Natural Objects’, Annual Review of Psychology 32: 89–115. Mirkovic, Damir, 2000. ‘The Historical Link Between the Ustase Genocide and the CroatoSerb Civil War: 1991–1995’, Journal of Genocide Research 2(3): 363–373. Moon, J. Donald, 1975. ‘The Logic of Political Inquiry’, in Fred I. Greenstein, ed., The Handbook of Political Science, vol. 1. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley (131–228). Northrup, Terrell A. 1989. ‘The Dynamic of Identity in Personal and Social Conflict’, in Kriesberg, Northrup & Thorson (55–82). Oakes, Penelope J.; S. Alexander Haslam & John

S E R B O -C RO AT I A N W A R

C. Turner, 1994. Stereotyping and Social Reality. Oxford: Blackwell. Olson, Mancur, 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Perica, S., 2000. ‘HDZ zeli paralizirati vladu’ [The HDZ Wants to Paralyse the Government], Vecernji List, 2 October: 1. Popov, Nebojsa, 1995. ‘Serbian Populism and the Fall of Yugoslavia’, Uncaptive Minds (Fall–Winter): 83–111. Ramet, Sabrina, 1992. Nationalism and Federalism in Yugoslavia: 1962–1991. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press. Rescher, Nicholas, 1977. Dialectics. Albany, NY: SUNY Press. Riker, William H. & Peter C. Ordeshook, 1973. An Introduction to Positive Political Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Rosch, Eleanor, 1978. ‘Principles of Categorization’, in Eleanor Rosch & Barbara B. Lloyd, eds, Cognition and Categorization. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum (27–48). Rosch, Eleanor, 1983. ‘Prototype Classification and Logical Classification’, in Ellin Kofsky Scholnick, ed., New Trends in Conceptual Representation. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum (73–86). Schwartz, Richard D., 1989. ‘Arab–Jewish Dialogue in the United States’, in Kriesberg, Northrup & Thorson (180–209). Sherif, Muzafer; O. J. Harvey, B. Jack White, William R. Hood & Carolyn W. Sherif, 1961. The Robbers Cave Experiment. Middletown, CT: Wesleyan University Press, 1988. [First published 1961.] Silber, Laura & Allan Little, 1996. Yugoslavia: Death of a Nation. New York: Penguin. Tajfel, Henri, 1981. Human Groups and Social Categories. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Tajfel, Henri, 1984a. ‘Intergroup Relations, Social Myths and Social Justice in Social Psychology’, in Tajfel, 1984b (695–715). Tajfel, Henri, 1984b. The Social Dimension, vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Tajfel, Henri & John C. Turner, 1979. ‘An Integrative Theory of Intergroup Conflict’, in William G. Austin & Stephan Worchel, eds, The Social Psychology of Intergroup Relations. Monterrey, CA: Brooks/Cole (33–47).

89

04duffy (ds)

90

10/12/01

9:18 am

Page 90

j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H Tatić, Sava, 1997. ‘How We Killed for Croatia’, Transitions 4(6): 20–28. Thompson, Mark, 1994. Forging War: The Media in Serbia, Croatia and Bosnia-Herzegovina. Avon: Bath Press. Tilly, Charles, 1978. From Mobilization to Revolution. New York: McGraw-Hill. Tudjman, Franjo, 1981. Nationalism in Contemporary Europe. New York: Columbia University Press. Turner, John C., 1984. ‘Social Identification and Psychological Group Formation’, in Tajfel, 1984b (518–538). Turner, John C., 1987. Rediscovering the Social Group. London: Blackwell. Turner, John C.; Penelope J. Oakes, S. Alexander Haslam & Craig McGarty, 1994. ‘Self and Collective: Cognition and Social Context’, Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 20(5): 454–463. Uhlaner, Carole Jean, 1989. ‘ “Relational Goods” and Participation’, Public Choice 62: 253–285. United States, 1993. ‘Press Conference by the President and Prime Minister Rabin of Israel’, White House, 12 November. United States, 1995. ‘Fact Sheet’, Department of State, Office of the Spokesman, 30 November. Uzelak, Gordana, 1998. ‘Franjo Tudjman’s Nationalist Ideology’, East European Quarterly 31(4): 449–472. Verdery, Katherine, 1999. The Political Lives of Dead Bodies. New York: Columbia University Press. Western, Jon W. & Daniel Serwer, 2000. ‘Bosnia’s

volume 39 / number 1 / january 2002 Next Five Years’, Special Report 62. Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace. Wilson, James Q., 1973. Political Organizations. New York: Basic Books. White, Harrison C., 1992. Identity and Control. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Woodward, Susan, 1995. Balkan Tragedy. Washington, DC: Brookings.

GAVAN DUFFY, b. 1949, PhD in Political Science (Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1987); Associate Professor, Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse University (1989– ); Instructor, Assistant Professor, University of Texas (1985–89); recent articles in International Studies Quarterly, Japanese Journal of Political Science, and International Interactions.

NICOLE LINDSTROM, b. 1970, PhD Candidate in Political Science, Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse University (1996– ); Assistant Professor of International Relations and European Studies, Central European University, Budapest (2001– ). Research supported by grants from the National Security Education Program, Syracuse University, and the Institute for the Study of World Politics. Articles in The Fletcher Forum, American Politics Quarterly, and several Croatian-language journals.

Solidary Incentives in the Serbo-Croatian War

cooperation and mutual acceptance had become a ..... fictive status of this assumption. They posit ...... Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Woodward ...

180KB Sizes 1 Downloads 133 Views

Recommend Documents

Solidary Incentives in the Serbo-Croatian War
1 The term 'Serb' can refer ambiguously to Serbs in Serbia, in Croatia, in Bosnia, ... Over the next several years, more than. 750 Croat ... and schools. It stripped ...

Incentives in the Probabilistic Serial Mechanism - CiteSeerX
sity house allocation and student placement in public schools are examples of important assignment ..... Each object is viewed as a divisible good of “probability shares.” Each agent ..... T0 = 0,Tl+1 = 1 as a technical notation convention. B.2.

Driving the Gap: Tax Incentives and Incentives for ...
The size of the bandwidth invokes the classic tradeoff between efficiency and bias. In our context ... First, technical issues make it more difficult to achieve the.

Shifting Incentives in Forecasting Contests
Participants were employees at a large software company asked to place bets on the outcome of ... Management ranked employees on their performance in.

Risk Sharing, Investment, and Incentives in the ...
Therefore, capital accumulation and growth would be faster in an economy without perfect insurance than in one with perfect insurance. This article explores the tradeoffs between insurance and growth in the neoclassical growth model with two agents a

Incentives in the Probabilistic Serial Mechanism
instance, the “replica economy” model often used to discuss asymptotic ..... However, the high degree of efficiency and fairness of the probabilistic serial ...

Agency and Incentives: Vertical Integration in the ...
Aug 12, 2015 - Freddie Mac did not allow integrated auctioneers in foreclosure ... backed by Freddie Mac as well as the fraction of the law firm's business in a given year that ... number of days.4 If the borrower fails to make good on the missed ...

Promotion incentives in the public sector: evidence from ... - Albert Park
Dec 3, 2016 - Most teachers in the sample completed vocational college or .... competitors increases (higher n) effort increases for those with skill near the marginal skill ...... We thank Matthew Collin, Jishnu Das, Stefan Dercon, Eliana La ...

Promotion incentives in the public sector: evidence from ... - Albert Park
Dec 3, 2016 - Most teachers in the sample completed vocational college or regular college, with nearly ..... In year t = X − 3 there are two such years (t = X + 1.

Collective versus Relative Incentives: the Agency Perspective
ing social phenomena in the workplace. When- .... Definition 1. (Standard ... effort, according to the previous definition. In ...... 360 degree evaluation) has become increasingly popular in ...... Social Science Research Center Berlin (WZB) Dis-.

WAR IN THE WEST.pdf
Luftwaffe would have to neutralize the Royal ______. First, though, Hitler ordered. Goering's Luftwaffe to destroy the ______. Goering concentrated his attack on air. bases. Outnumbered 5 to 1, the RAF ______. WHY?? 1) British had ______ - excellent

The Biafran War in Britain
ote: The author will email a version of this article containing images, which cannot be .... journalists like Waugh or Frederick Forsyth were at the forefront of these ...

Neural responses to monetary incentives in major ...
Functional Neural Images (AFNI) software (50). For preprocessing ..... defined monetary incentives. In the present sample of ..... San Antonio,. TX: Psychological ...

Incentives and Stability in Large Two-Sided Matching ...
Hitotsubashi, Kyoto, Osaka, Tokyo, 2006 North American Summer Meetings of ... “Before you might have a situation where a school was going to take 100 new.

contracts, externalities, and incentives in shopping malls
fixed in advance. Tables 1 and ... large malls as in our case, and did not have data on actual sales. A more .... We begin our analysis of externalities in table 3 by.

On Countervailing Incentives
0q— 5(0) and substituting the transfer _V(()] away in the principal's objec- tive, the problem ..... R9) or F(0)— 1. In this case, the balance of incentives is unam-.

Incentives for Expressing Opinions in Online Polls
markets where the security that is traded depends on the realization of a ... tory of the Unites States of America(as of 2001-01-01) that .... comfort of their home.

targets, incentives and public accountability in ...
Most modern European universities are funded almost entirely from public .... According to the European Commission [2006], the EU has about 4 000 institutions ..... whether this results in better service delivery to the students; sometimes I.

Incentives in Merchant Empires: Portuguese and Dutch ...
Oct 26, 2011 - business decisions across merchant empires, suggesting very .... at least some time in Bengal between 1669 and 1799, one year before the ...

Integrative Complexity in Reasoning About the Gulf War and the ...
Briefly, differentiation reflects the degree to which people ... higher levels of support for the U.S. action than did females (Ms = 3.12 [SD = 1.06] for ..... Research Scholarship (10023-00) to David R. Mandel, a University of British Columbia.

Incentives for Quality in Friendly and Hostile Informational Environments
Feb 24, 2012 - In contrast, friendly environments create free riding among sellers, which ... tion is another illustration: prestigious journals (mostly) include good ...... Learning and Statistical Discrimination, American Economic Review (Papers.

Eligibility Recertification and Dynamic Opt-in Incentives ...
All four rotation groups in the 2001 panel provide information for 36 ...... not allowed and income change reporting is required for adults (see 42 CFR, Sec.

Incentives for Quality in Friendly and Hostile Informational Environments
Feb 24, 2012 - Email: [email protected] .... ity with a probability g if quality is high (”good news”) and probability b if quality is low ..... revision obtains from the fact that the fraction of self-regulating firms is F(c∗),

contracts, externalities, and incentives in shopping malls
web of externality and incentive issues between store own- ers and the mall developer.1 ... University of Chicago; and Graduate School of Business, University of. Chicago ...... discounted on average15 by i per unit of sale: ri ri iyi. (5). This is a