Reforming the IMF John Morgan

A

fter 60 years of stabilizing international financial markets, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) is now in danger of becoming irrelevant, going bankrupt, or both. Its finances are threatened by a projected $370 million revenue shortfall on an annual budget of $980 million. Its credibility is undermined by a power structure that is badly out of touch with economic reality. For example, China, with 20 percent of the world’s population and a GDP on par with Germany, has less influence on decision making than the Benelux

John Morgan is the Gary and Sherron Kalbach Professor of Business Administration at the Haas School of Business and the Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley. E-mail: [email protected].

countries (Belgium, The Netherlands, and Luxembourg). The IMF itself has acknowledged the seriousness of the situation: The twin problems of country representation and budget financing will occupy center stage at the upcoming Annual Meetings of the Fund in Washington, D.C. We propose a simple, market-based solution to both problems. Our solution is to “float” the price of voting rights through an auction. An auction helps solve the representation problem by allocating additional voting rights to economically powerful but underrepresented countries, who presumably value them most. Moreover, the proceeds of the auction can be used to fix the budget problem and provide the IMF with a financing model that relies less on financial crises as a source of funds.

© The Berkeley Electronic Press

background

H

istorically, the IMF has funded itself through loans to countries facing balance of payments problems. This business has largely dried up and is likely to dry up further. To start with, there have been relatively few financial crises recently and, hence, little need for IMF loans. Over the long-term, the Fund faces a more fundamental challenge as many countries are self-insuring against crises through the costly accumulation of vast amounts of foreign reserves—the very thing the IMF was supposed to obviate. As a result, the financial position of the Fund is tenuous at best. Why are countries self-insuring? Many countries, especially fast-growing Asian economies, no longer see the Fund as an attractive partner in times of crisis. IMF loans come with strings Economists’ Voice  www.bepress.com/ev  October, 2007

--

attached—strings that these countries are no longer willing to accept, and over which they have little control owing to their lack of voice. As a result, costly self-insurance has become the more attractive option. A country’s influence at the IMF largely depends on its “quota,” which determines the weight of a country’s vote in the decision making process.1 While, in theory, quotas reflect countries’ economic power, currently, there is little relation between the two. Indeed, even after a recent quota adjustment, China’s quota is still only four-fifths of that of the Benelux countries. Similar examples abound. Throughout its existence, quotas at the Fund have been determined by formulas placing weights on GDP, trade flows, and other macroeconomic variables. While the formulas have evolved and multiplied over time, there is still little agreement on the “right” one. Currently, no fewer than five competing formulas are being considered. the underlying problem

T

he difficulties in devising an acceptable formula result from the many competing roles that quotas serve in the IMF. Quotas simultaneously determine the capital

contributions (“subscriptions”) of member countries, their borrowing rights, and the weights of their votes in decision making. The main obstacle to quota reform is the tension between the first and third of these roles: namely, the fixed relationship between capital contributions and votes. Unlike equity shares in a publicly traded company, quota shares in the Fund are not tradable—there is no market price for ownership and voting rights. Nevertheless, a fixed, non-market price does exist: the Fund’s Articles of Agreement prescribe that each country receives one vote per Special Drawing Rights (SDR) 100,000 in quota subscriptions.2 But the fight over quotas suggests that, in an open market, one additional SDR in quota subscription would sell for considerably more than its nominal value. Thus, whenever additional quota is allocated at SDR 100,000 per vote, a net value transfer to the buyer takes place at the expense of the existing shareholders. What accounts for this disparity? As mentioned above, quota determines more than how much a country can borrow from the Fund. Through its role in decision making, quota also confers influence on lending by the fund—to whom and on what terms. More indirectly, it affects a country’s ability to use the IMF for the

advancement of its economic interests. For instance, the US has been trying to change China’s exchange rate policy through pressure from the Fund. Finally, quota determines a country’s impact on international financial standards. The standard solution for dealing with excess demand, whether for tires, corn, or IBM stock, is to raise the price or to increase supply. Changing the quota formula, without addressing the issue of price and quantity, does nothing to solve the problem of excess demand. Not surprisingly, consensus over the “right” formula has proved elusive. the solution

W

e propose a market-based solution to determine quotas, through the creation of an auction for quota rights. This auction would determine how much additional quota each country is allowed to buy at the prescribed price of SDR 100,000 per vote, and how much it would have to pay for that right. Compared to the formula-based approach, the use of an auction is both simpler and more transparent. Moreover, by allowing the price of quota rights to float freely, our approach aligns the demand and allocation of quotas with Economists’ Voice  www.bepress.com/ev  October, 2007

--

countries’ ability and willingness to pay, reflecting their true economic, financial, and political power. As in international financial markets, the auction encodes underlying fundamentals in the form of a price, as opposed to using a formula to attempt to divine the same information. The details of our proposal are as follows: The Fund announces that it is going to auction, say, SDR 20 billion in new quota rights on a fixed date—approximately 10% of the existing quota. Each member country submits a demand schedule, stating the quota rights it would like to buy as a function of the price it would have to pay. At the end of the bidding process, the Fund aggregates the demand schedules of all bidders and determines the market clearing price for the new quota rights—that is, the price where the demand curve for quota rights as derived from the bidding schedules meets the vertical supply curve of available quota rights (SDR 20 billion in our example). The market price and the allocation of quota rights are announced, and the winning bidders make payments to the Fund in the amount of the market price times the increase in their quota. Next, to conform to the Articles of Agreement, the Board of Governors officially proposes a quota adjustment that corresponds to

the outcome of the auction. Finally, actual subscription payments are made and the quota adjustments are implemented. Note that countries make two separate payments. First, they pay for the quota rights they have won in the auction. Then, they pay the actual quota subscriptions. Hence, quota rights are simply “call options.” Continuing with our example, suppose that China bids most aggressively and captures half of the rights, i.e., SDR 10 billion. Japan captures SDR 5 billion, while India and Korea each capture SDR 2.5 billion. The market price, which is determined by the highest losing bid, turns out to be SDR 1. In this case, China pays SDR 10 billion for the rights, Japan pays SDR 5 billion, and India and Korea each pay SDR 2.5 billion. Finally, each country is allocated—and pays for—its additional quota. The resulting quota shares for a selection of member countries are shown in Table 1. Notice that China now has greater representation than the Benelux countries. The proceeds from the auction can be invested in an endowment. Conservatively, such an endowment would generate a three percent real return per year. At a price of SDR 1 per quota right, a SDR 20 billion rights auction

Table 1 Country Quotas Country

% of Total After Auction

% of Total Before Auction

United States

15.7

17.1

Japan

7.7

6.1

China

7.6

3.7

Germany

5.5

6.0

United Kingdom

4.5

4.9

France

4.5

4.9

Italy

3.0

3.2

Saudi Arabia

2.9

3.2

India

2.8

1.9

Canada

2.7

2.9

Russia

2.5

2.7

Korea

2.3

1.3

Netherlands

2.2

2.4

Belgium

1.9

2.1

would generate roughly enough income to cover the entire operating budget of the Fund. Admittedly our proposal does not address all problems. Another widely acknowledged aspect of the representation problem, which our proposal does not directly address, is the issue of strengthening the voice of low-income countries at the IMF. There appears to be consensus within the Fund Economists’ Voice  www.bepress.com/ev  October, 2007

--

that this is best handled through an increase in the number of “basic votes” given to every member country, rather than through quota adjustments. conclusion

C

ompared to allocating quota by formula, an auction has several advantages. First, it allows countries to directly express the value they place on these rights. Second, the returns from the auction can be used to put the financing of the Fund on a more stable footing. Third, by controlling the amount of new quota rights issued, the Fund’s Board fully controls the maximal dilution of the voting shares of member countries not participating, or not winning, in the auction. Fourth, the same auction framework can be used repeatedly to adjust quotas without revisiting the basic mechanism. Finally, the allocation of quota rights through an auction does not require an amendment of the Fund’s Articles of Agreement. Such amendments are difficult to pass since they require an 85% supermajority.

Letters commenting on this piece or others may be submitted at http://www.bepress.com/cgi/ submit.cgi?context=ev.

notes 1. In addition to votes through quota, each country receives 250 “basic” votes. At present, basic votes account for only 2.1 percent of total votes. 2. The SDR is the IMF’s unit of account and corresponds to a basket of international currencies; on 27 September 2007, 1 SDR = $1.55.

references and further reading

Arnold, Wayne (2006) “Where Brashness Doesn’t Play,” New York Times, April 11. Available at: http://www.nytimes.com/2006/04/11/business/ worldbusiness/11thai.html. (On self-insurance: Thailand’s foreign currency reserves have risen to more than $50 billion after the Thai Prime Minister declared his “financial independence” from the Fund following the early repayment of a $3.4 billion loan made by the Fund during the Asian crisis.) Cooper, Richard N. and Edwin M. Truman (2007) “The IMF Quota Formula: Linchpin of Fund Reform,” Policy Briefs in International Economics, Peterson G. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC. The Economist (2007) “Funding the Fund,” February 1. Available at: http://www. economist.com/finance/displaystory.cfm?story_ id=8637836. (On projected budget shortfall.)

Feldstein, M. (1999) “Self-protection for Emerging Market Economies,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working paper 6097. Cambridge, MA. Available at: http://papers. nber.org/papers/w6907.pdf. (On the trend toward self-insurance rather than reliance on the Fund.) International Monetary Fund (2007) “IMF Members’ Quotas and Voting Power, and IMF Board of Governors,” September 13. Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/memdir/ members.htm. (On quota shares of China versus Benelux.) International Monetary Fund (2006) “Report of the Executive Board to the Board of Governors,” August 31. Washington, DC. International Monetary Fund (2005) “The Managing Director’s Report on the Fund’s Medium-Term Strategy,” September 15. Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/np/omd/2005/ eng/091505.pdf. International Monetary Fund (1992) Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund (1944). Washington, DC. Ito, Takatoshi (2007) “Asian Currency Crisis and the International Monetary Fund, 10 Years Later: Overview,” Asian Economic Policy Review Economists’ Voice  www.bepress.com/ev  October, 2007

--

2:16–49. (On self-insurance and the increasingly tenuous position of the Fund.) Mikesell, Raymond F. (1994) “The Bretton Woods Debate: A Memoir,” Essays in International Finance, No 192. Princeton, NJ: International Finance Section, Princeton University. Truman, Edwin M., ed. (2006) Reforming the IMF for the 21st Century. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Zwaniecki, Andrzej (2006) “Treasury Official Urges More Active IMF Role on Currency Issues,” Bureau of International Information Programs, U.S. Department of State, February 6. Available at: http://usinfo.state.gov/eap/Archive/2006/Feb/ 06-805224.html. (On US efforts to change China’s exchange rate policy through pressure from the Fund.)

Economists’ Voice  www.bepress.com/ev  October, 2007

--

Reforming the IMF

on the “right” one. Currently, no fewer than five competing formulas are being considered. the underlying problem. The difficulties in devising an acceptable formula result from the many compet- ing roles that quotas serve in the IMF. Quo- tas simultaneously determine the capital contributions (“subscriptions”) of member ...

161KB Sizes 4 Downloads 311 Views

Recommend Documents

Reforming the IMF
The Berkeley Electronic Press. After 60 years of stabilizing inter- national financial markets, the .... attempt to divine the same information. The details of our proposal are as follows: The Fund announces that it is ... of Agreement, the Board of

World Economic Outlook - IMF
business of restoring bank health and credit transmis- sion and from ..... Trend growth is estimated using a Hodrick-Prescott filter and may differ from the IMF ...

IMF Notes.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. IMF Notes.pdf.

World Economic Outlook - IMF
Publication orders may be placed online, by fax, or through the mail: .... Temporary Oil Price Shock Impact on GDP and Current Accounts: Scenarios 1, 2, and 3. 30 ..... These files may be downloaded for use in a variety of software packages.

Reforming-Theological-Anthropology-After-The-Philosophical-Turn ...
... fonts are quick within the eyes, some use a ton of ... 3. Page 3 of 3. Reforming-Theological-Anthropology-After-The-Philosophical-Turn-To-Relationality.pdf.

World Economic Outlook - IMF
Emerging Market and Developing Economies: Debt-Service Ratios ..... or online forum (telephone inquiries cannot be accepted): ...... as to small businesses) over widespread stimulus. ...... higher, benefiting growth in oil suppliers with spare.

World Economic Outlook - IMF
World economic outlook : a survey by the staff of the International Monetary Fund. — ...... Johnson, Douglas Laxton, Peter Manchev, and Troy Mathe- son, 2010 ...

IMF Director copy.pdf
dictator Mobutu Sese Seko to leave the Congo with a debt of. $175 billion at the end of his reign. e citizens of these. countries should absolutely not be asked to ...

The IMF and the World Bank Approaches to ...
context, public sector expenditures are much higher than its revenues and thus fiscal deficits ... macroeconomic accounts (IMF,1987; Tarp,1993): ... INP = interest payments from the government and the private sector to the foreign sector, ... finance