R&D Dynamics and Corporate Cash Xiaodan Gao∗

Jake Zhao

National University of Singapore

Peking University HSBC Business School April 2018

Abstract High-tech firms hold substantial cash reserves. Potential explanations in the literature for this phenomenon include R&D adjustment costs, financial frictions, knowledge spillover, innovation uncertainty, and market competition. We build a parsimonious industry equilibrium model that incorporates all of the cited explanations and determines which factors are the most important for understanding the cash policy of high tech firms. We find that innovation uncertainty is the major driver behind the phenomenon, followed by knowledge spillover and financial frictions. Market competition has non-monotonic effects, while R&D adjustment costs play a relatively minor role since R&D investment is naturally persistent. We also discover that R&D tax credits are more effective in economies with low innovation volatility, low financial frictions, low fixed operating costs, or high knowledge spillover.

JEL Classification: G32; L11; O32 Keywords: Cash holdings; R&D investment; R&D adjustment costs; financial frictions; knowledge spillover; innovation uncertainty; market competition ∗

We would like to thank Fangjian Fu, Pengjie Gao, Roger Loh, Dino Palazzo, Ivan Png, Tom Sargent, Vladimir Vladimirov, Rong Wang, Daniel Yi Xu, Jingyi Zhang and the audiences at NUS, SMU, SUFE, Tsinghua Workshop in Macroeconomics 2017, 2017 Asian Meeting of the Econometric Society, and 2017 European Finance Association annual meeting for insightful comments and suggestions.

1

1

Introduction

High-tech firms in the United States hold massive cash reserves. During the 2000s, high-tech firms’ median and mean cash-to-assets ratio are 0.32 and 0.37, respectively, which are 3.8 times and 2.4 times as large as those of non-high-tech firms. This empirical regularity is evidenced by the significant positive correlation between R&D expenditures and cash holdings observed by Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009). Previous studies attribute the large cash stocks to various factors relevant for high-tech industries: R&D adjustment costs (Brown and Petersen, 2011), financial frictions caused by the non-collaterability of R&D (Falato, Kadyrzhanova, and Sim, 2013), knowledge spillover (Qiu and Wan, 2015), innovation uncertainty (Lyandres and Palazzo, 2014; Hsu, Li, and Lin, 2016), and intense market competition (Ma, Mello, and Wu, 2014; Lyandres and Palazzo, 2016).1 The goal of this paper is to understand the quantitative importance of these proposed economic forces that drive high-tech firms’ substantial cash reserves. This step is necessary and important because it helps identify the main determinant(s) of high-tech firms’ strong cash demand, address issues regarding the interaction between cash and R&D spending, and guide effective policy tools that the government can use to boost productivity given that R&D is a key driver of productivity and economic growth. Moreover, each of these factors has been studied in the absence of others, which is potentially problematic because it may bias their respective contribution and provide a misleading picture of how each mechanism influences cash decisions. For instance, if there is a high correlation between R&D adjustment costs and financial frictions, only including one of these factors in a model will tend to overstate the relative importance of the included factor. In this paper, we examine the role of all of these possible mechanisms within a unified framework. Identifying the impacts of these factors on cash demand is empirically challenging. Most factors are unobservable and thus hard to measure accurately. They are also potentially correlated which makes it difficult to disentangle their effects. To address this issue, we take a 1

In addition to the factors mentioned above, Foley, Hartzell, Titman, and Twite (2007) also link the high cash holdings with tax policy. They find that multinationals facing higher repatriation taxes tend to store more cash. We compare the average cash ratios for high-tech firms with and without foreign income. Interestingly, multinational high-tech firms tend to have lower cash-to-assets and cash-to-sales ratios than their counterparts: 0.33 versus 0.40 and 0.86 versus 2.51, respectively. It seems reasonable to conjecture that factors other than the tax-avoidance motive are responsible for high-tech firms’ cash stock. As such, we abstract from a tax-based explanation in this paper.

2

structural approach. We incorporate all of these mechanisms into a parsimonious model and use estimated parameters to characterize them. We then extract the information on each factor from firms’ R&D and cash choices, and systematically investigate and quantify their impacts. Specifically, we build a dynamic industry equilibrium model of R&D and cash with endogenous entry and exit. In the model, firms hire labor to produce differentiated products and compete in the product market. They invest in R&D to improve their competitive positions, but face knowledge spillover and innovation risks. Also, adjusting R&D expenditures incurs costs. The capital market is assumed to be imperfect, so firms have no access to debt financing due to prohibitive collateralization of R&D; they can, however, borrow funds through equity issuance (Brown, Fazzari, and Petersen, 2009; Hall and Lerner, 2010; Hall, Moncada-Patern` oCastello, Montresor, and Vezzani, 2015). Equity inflow (equity issuance) and equity outflow (dividend distribution) are costly. This generates a precautionary motive for holding cash, even though firms are risk neutral (Zhao, 2016). That is, to avoid external financing costs in case of a liquidity shortage, firms accumulate internal funds. Meanwhile, the presence of other frictions—R&D adjustment costs, knowledge spillover, innovation uncertainty, and market competition—affects the strength of the precautionary motive. To examine the model’s quantitative implications for cash and R&D policies, we estimate the model and validate it by demonstrating its ability to match relevant data moments. We then use the structural estimates obtained to assess how each factor affects cash and R&D choices jointly. Each factor is encapsulated by one or more estimated parameters. We change one parameter at a time and perform two sets of counterfactual analysis: (i) changing the value of each parameter by 5%, and (ii) shutting down each channel. These two exercises produce the following results. Innovation uncertainty has the strongest effect, and financial frictions and knowledge spillover are also significant drivers behind high-tech firms’ strong cash demand. These results support the conclusions of Falato, Kadyrzhanova, and Sim (2013), Qiu and Wan (2015) and Hsu, Li, and Lin (2016). However, our results deviate from previous studies along two dimensions. First, our model differentiates between incremental innovation and radical innovation, and suggests that innovation uncertainty captured by innovation volatility (the probability of realizing extreme productivity including radical innovation) is the key to explain the large cash

3

balance. Second, knowledge spillover affects cash policy through a channel different from that proposed by Qiu and Wan (2015). In particular, we find that in response to an increase in knowledge spillover, firms cut R&D investments. The decline in precautionary cash demand, however, is fully offset by the increase in the substitution away from R&D to cash (substitution effect) and the increase in income that spillover brings (income effect). This generates a pattern in line with the empirical observation that cash holdings increase with knowledge spillover. R&D adjustment costs play a smaller role in generating cash holdings than the other factors, because the absence of adjustment costs only reduces the real price of investment—and thus affects the level of R&D expenditures. As long as financial frictions and income uncertainty are present, cash will be valuable regardless of the magnitude of the adjustment costs. R&D investment is also naturally persistent since productivity improvements are stochastic. Market competition has important but non-monotonic impacts on high-tech firms’ cash policy, regardless of the sources of competitive pressure—product substitutability or entry barriers induced by fixed operating costs. The non-monotonicity arises from a composition change in the stationary distribution. When changes in market competition prompt lowproductivity firms to stay, many of them choose to increase their R&D spending in order to compete in the market. Those firms tend to be financially constrained and have few resources to save, which drives down the average cash ratio. When changes in market competition drive out low-productivity firms, firms that continue to operate tend to be less likely to run into financial distress and have weaker cash demand, which also reduces cash holdings. We further examine the policy implications of our model. First, we find knowledge spillover reduces R&D investment significantly, while financial frictions have almost no impact on R&D investment. This somewhat surprising finding suggests that the existence of corporate cash holdings largely eliminates potential market failures stemming from imperfect capital markets. Second, we discover that productivity can be boosted efficiently by R&D tax credits. In particular, we show that R&D tax credits are more effective in improving productivity when innovation uncertainty, financial frictions, and R&D adjustment costs are low. R&D tax credits are also effective in raising productivity when knowledge spillover is high. This paper contributes in three ways. First, it complements the literature of corporate cash management by systematically analyzing the role of R&D features in explaining high-tech

4

firms’ substantial cash reserves. A number of these features have been studied in the literature; however, little is known about their relative quantitative importance, which is the key step toward understanding the rationale behind high-tech firms’ cash holdings. Furthermore, these factors have been examined in isolation, and this may cause erroneous conclusions to be reached. We determine in our study that some results from previous work are overturned once all the features are analyzed jointly. Second, our paper develops a novel and computationally tractable framework to study firms’ R&D choices. In particular, it proposes a theoretically appealing approach to model the transition probabilities that govern the evolution of endogenous productivity. In contrast to previous studies that restrict firms from moving beyond the technology level that is closest to their current one (Ericson and Pakes, 1995; Xu, 2008; Hashmi and Van Biesebroeck, 2016), our approach allows for the realization of different levels of innovation—radical innovation vs. incremental innovation—and neatly captures a wide range of possible innovation dynamics. Lastly, this paper contributes to the literature on R&D by studying R&D decisions, cash holdings, and financial frictions within a unified framework. A large literature addresses the role of financial frictions in R&D investments in the absence of internal cash stocks.2 However, in response to financial frictions, firms will endogenously choose to accumulate cash, which has important implications for the R&D-financial friction relationship. As such, the inclusion of cash choices in the model helps to generate important insights overlooked in previous studies and, more importantly, is necessary for a full understanding of the role of financial frictions in R&D and their long-term effects on productivity. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 lays out a dynamic industry equilibrium model of R&D and cash with endogenous entry and exit. Section 3 provides intuition about how R&D features influence high-tech firms’ cash and R&D choices and reports the estimation results of the model. Section 4 quantitatively evaluates the role of each feature in explaining high-tech firms’ cash demand and discusses policy implications of the model for R&D tax credits. Section 5 concludes. 2

Hall, Moncada-Patern` o-Castello, Montresor, and Vezzani (2015) give a comprehensive review of the available literature on the relationship between R&D and financial constraints.

5

2

Model

In this section, we consider an industry equilibrium model of corporate R&D investment and cash holdings, which nests Hopenhayn (1992), Riddick and Whited (2009), and Xu (2008). In the model, time is discrete and infinite. Within the industry, a continuum of firms with mass one operate in a monopolistically competitive market and specialize in the production of differentiated goods. Firms compete in the product market and face financial frictions. Each period, incumbent firms make their exit decisions.3 Firms that choose to continue to operate produce goods and make financial, R&D-investment, and dividend-distribution choices. Potential entrants make their entry decisions by weighing the expected benefits and costs, and firms that eventually choose to enter decide their R&D spending. We first specify the demand function that each firm faces and its production technology, knowledge accumulation process, and financing options, then state the firm’s problem and the industry equilibrium.

2.1

Demand and Technology

Assume there is a unit measure of firms and firm i ∈ [0, 1] produces output with labor li ,

yi,t = zi,t li,t .

(1)

Here, zi,t is the firm’s relative technological position within the industry at period t and is determined stochastically and is dependent on the firm’s investment in knowledge, its past technological position, and the intra-industry knowledge spillover. We do not include physical capital in our model. This simplifying assumption is unlikely to affect our model’s key implications for a variety of reasons. First, the capital-to-assets ratio of R&D intensive firms is only about one third as much and exhibits less autocorrelation when compared to R&D non-intensive firms. Next, R&D intensity is almost independent of physical capital stock for high-tech firms.4 Finally, the static productive response to endogenous 3

We model firm entry and exit endogenously, because exogenous entry and exit assumption can force highproductive firms to exit, which is not a desirable feature. 4 The correlation between the R&D-to-sales ratio and beginning-of-period net capital stock is −0.067 for high-tech firms during the 2000s. See, also, Klette and Kortum (2004).

6

productivity changes in the model mimics the quick and efficient outsourcing of production by innovative firms in the real world. We do recognize, however, that introducing physical capital in our model as well as any other feature could change the dynamics and results. The firm faces a demand function taking the following form:

d yi,t

where Pt =

hR

1 1−σ 0 pi,t di

i

1 1−σ

and Yt =

 =

 R1 0

pi,t Pt

−σ

σ−1 σ

yi,t di

Yt , 

σ σ−1

(2)

. Here, σ denotes the elasticity of

substitution between goods, pi,t denotes the price charged by firm i, Pt and Yt are industry d is the quantity demanded for good i. This demand curve can price and quantity level, and yi,t

be derived from the optimal choices of households. They consume a composite consumption good that is a Dixit-Stiglitz index of differentiated goods in the industry.

2.2

Knowledge Investment and Production

In every period t, firm i invests in R&D and learns via spillover from competing firms that have relatively more advanced technologies. The firm’s total input of knowledge production, Di,t , at period t is therefore given by

Di,t = di,t + θSi,t−1 .

(3)

Here, di,t is firm i’s own R&D spending, θ captures the magnitude of knowledge spillover, and Si,t−1 is the average previous-period knowledge investment by firms that have stronger R technological positions than firm i in the current period, that is, Si,t−1 = {j:zj,t >zi,t } dj,t−1 dj. From this point on, we drop subscript i to simplify notation. The firm must pay costs for adjusting its knowledge investment level, defined as

A(dt−1 , dt ) = γ0 1dt 6=dt−1 + γ2

(dt − dt−1 )2 , dt + dt−1

(4)

where γ0 ≥ 0 is the fixed adjustment cost, γ2 ≥ 0 is the convex adjustment cost, and 1dt 6=dt−1 is an indicator function that equals one if current R&D investment deviates from previous R&D spending. Adjustment costs can be justified by the fact that a large share of R&D expenses

7

goes to scientists’ salaries, and turnover in skilled workers can trigger large costs and losses (Hall, 1993; Bond, Harhoff, and Van Reenen, 2005). This specification is close to the one assumed for physical capital adjustment costs (Abel and Eberly, 2002; Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans, 2005; Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe, 2005; Cooper and Haltiwanger, 2006; and Del Negro and Schorfheide, 2008, among others). The fixed cost reflects the loss from disruption in restructuring knowledge production factors. The convex adjustment cost reflects an increasing marginal cost of adjustment, and is quadratic in changes in R&D investment. To allow for zero R&D spending, the second term is quadratic in the midpoint percentage change (i.e., changes in investment relative to the average of the previous and current expenditures

2(dt −dt−1 ) dt +dt−1 ),

rather than changes in rates (i.e.,

dt dt−1

− 1) as

employed by Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005) and Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2005). The firm’s future productivity level zt+1 is determined by its total knowledge input Dt , innovation uncertainty δ and ρ, and current status zt , where the current productivity level zt reflects the firm’s knowledge stock and past R&D effort. The transition in productivity from zt to zt+1 is specified as follows:    z¯ ≥ zt+1 > zt with probability Pr(zt+1 > zt ) × Pr(zt+1 |zt+1 > zt ),           Γ(zt+1 |zt ) = zt+1 = zt with probability Pr(zt+1 = zt ),             z ≤ zt+1 < zt with probability Pr(zt+1 < zt ) × Pr(zt+1 |zt+1 < zt ),

(5)

where Pr(zt+1 |zt+1 > zt ) =

1 −zt )ρ 1 (zt+1 −zt )ρ

,

(6)

1 (zt −zt+1 )ρ P 1 (zt −zt+1 )ρ zt+1
.

(7)

(z

P t+1 zt+1 >zt

and Pr(zt+1 |zt+1 < zt ) =

Specifically, the probability of transitioning from current level zt to future level zt+1 is equal to the product of the probability of directional movement and the probability of reaching zt+1 conditional on the directional changes. We follow Xu (2008) to specify the probability of directional movement. We assume that the firm improves its relative technological position and

8

reaches a higher level with probability Pr(zt+1 > zt ) = position with probability Pr(zt+1 = zt ) = probability Pr(zt+1 < zt ) =

δ 1+Dt .

1−δ+δDt 1+Dt ,

(1−δ)Dt 1+Dt ,

maintains its past technological

and loses its position and falls behind with

The parameter δ captures three knowledge-related risks:

knowledge obsolescence or depreciation, firms’ inability to keep up with competitors, and the uncertainty associated with innovation output. This specification also implies that higher investment in R&D improves firms’ relative competitive positions by raising the likelihood of technological advancement. Previous studies restrict firms from moving beyond the technology level that is closest to their current one, which is equivalent to the assumption that firms are only allowed to conduct incremental innovation and improve their technology gradually (Ericson and Pakes, 1995; Xu, 2008; Hashmi and Van Biesebroeck, 2016). Unlike those studies, we relax the assumption by incorporating radical innovation in the model. Incremental and radical innovations differ in several respects. In this paper, we focus on their differential effects on technology and revenue— that is, radical innovation improves technology more rapidly than incremental innovation and helps generate higher revenue. Specifically, we assume that firms’ future technology zt+1 can move to any level, with the probability changing with its distance from current level zt . The parameter ρ controls the likelihood of realizing extreme productivity, including radical innovation. The greater the value of ρ, the less likely firms will realize radical innovation and high income. Moreover, the parameter ρ captures a wide range of possibilities. When ρ → ∞, the firm will move to the value closest to zt with near certainty, which is equivalent to the assumption made by previous studies. When ρ = 0, the firm will have an equal chance of reaching any level other than zt , that is, an equal probability of realizing incremental innovation or radical innovation. When ρ → −∞, the firm will move to the farthest value of zt+1 with near certainty. We denote the conditional probability distribution for zt+1 by Γ(zt+1 |zt ).

2.3

Financing

Firms can finance R&D investment through three different sources: current-period revenue, internal cash balance, and external borrowing. Cash balance, ct , earns a risk-free rate r. The amount of interest earned is taxed at the corporate tax rate τc when taxable income is positive.

9

External borrowing takes the form of equity issuance. This assumption follows the observation by Brown, Fazzari, and Petersen (2009) that equity finance is a more relevant substitute for internal cash flow because of the intangible nature and low collateral value of R&D.5 Issuing equity incurs both fixed costs, λ0 , and linear costs, λ1 (Hennessy and Whited, 2007; Nikolov and Whited, 2014). Following previous studies, we describe negative equity flow et < 0 as equity issuance and positive equity flow et ≥ 0 as dividend distribution.

2.4 2.4.1

The Firm’s Problem The Incumbent’s Problem

Each period, after productivity zt is realized, the firm decides whether to leave the market by weighing the expected benefits of continuing to operate and of exiting. If the firm chooses to stay, it hires labor lt at the wage rate w to produce output and sets a price pt on its product. Its taxable income is

πt = pt yt − wlt − cF + rct − dt ,

(8)

in which cF is the fixed operational cost. Upon receiving its profit, the firm makes decisions about R&D investment and cash savings. If available internal resources are insufficient to cover those expenses, the firm borrows externally by issuing equity; otherwise, it distributes dividends. Net cash flow is

gI (et ) = −1et <0 λ0 + (1 − 1et ≥0 τd + 1et <0 λ1 )et (πt , ct , ct+1 , dt−1 , dt ),

(9)

et (πt , ct , ct+1 , dt−1 , dt ) = (1 − τc 1πt ≥0 )πt + (ct − ct+1 ) + τrd dt − A(dt−1 , dt ).

(10)

where

The first term of et is the firm’s net income, and the other terms are the net change in cash, R&D subsidy, and adjustment costs, respectively. Parameters τc and τrd are the corporate 5

Also, we find that the median short-term debt-to-assets ratio and long-term debt-to-assets ratio are 0.005 and 0.005, respectively, for high-tech firms during the 2000s. This confirms high-tech firms’ low reliance on debt financing.

10

income tax rate and R&D tax-credit rate. The indicator function 1et ≥0 equals one if the firm distributes dividends and zero otherwise, while 1et <0 equals one if the firm issues equity and zero otherwise. On the other hand, the indicator function 1πt ≥0 means that the firm is only taxed when taxable income is positive. If the firm chooses to exit, the corresponding net cash flow is

gX (et ) = −1et <0 λ0 + (1 − 1et ≥0 τd + 1et <0 λ1 )et (πt , ct , ct+1 = 0, dt−1 , dt = 0).

(11)

The risk-neutral incumbent maximizes its value. Moving on to the recursive formulation, let VI (z, c, d−1 ; µ) and VX (z, c, d−1 ; µ) denote the value functions of continuing to operate and exiting, respectively. The parameter µ is the current-period joint distribution of idiosyncratic productivity level, cash balances, and previous R&D spending, which will be specified in Subsection 2.5. Also, let x0 denote the continue/exit decision where x0 = 0 indicates that the firm continues and x0 = 1 indicates that the firm exits. Then the incumbent’s problem becomes

V (z, c, d−1 ; µ) = max {VI (z, c, d−1 ; µ), VX (z, c, d−1 ; µ)},

(12)

VI (z, c, d−1 ; µ) = max {gI (e) + βEV (z 0 , c0 , d; µ0 )}, 0

(13)

VX (z, c, d−1 ; µ) = gX (e).

(14)

x0 ∈{0,1}

where c ,d

and

Here, subscript −1 denotes a variable in the preceding period, and a prime denotes a variable in the subsequent period. The parameter β is the discount factor and equals

2.4.2

1 1+r .

The Potential Entrant’s Problem

A potential entrant pays a cost, cE , at the beginning of a period to draw a z with probability 1 (z−z)ρ 1 (z−z)ρ z>z

Pr(z > z) = P

11

,

(15)

where z is the lowest productivity level. This probability specification is the same as the one that incumbents face, and its corresponding probability distribution is denoted as ΓE (z). Upon seeing z, the potential entrant can either choose to throw away the draw, or commit to enter the economy and produce y. If the potential entrant commits to enter, it carries c = 0 and d−1 = 0 from the previous period because it was not operational, and chooses c0 and d to maximize the expected discounted value of the firm. With this form of entry, the potential entrant throws away low-z draws because potential profits are low and it does not want to pay the adjustment costs. On the other hand, high-z draws induce entry in order to capture more substantial profits. If a firm enters, it also invests in cash and R&D to set itself up for the future. The free-entry condition is Z max{VI (z, 0, 0; µ), 0}dΓE (z) ≤ cE ,

(16)

and the condition holds with equality when there is a non-zero mass of entry. Note that the entrant cost cE is endogenously determined by this condition.

2.5

Law of Motion for Distribution µ

Conditional on the current-period joint distribution µ(z, c, d−1 ) of idiosyncratic productivity level, cash balances, and previous R&D spending, the next-period distribution is determined by 0

0

0

µ (z , c , d) =

Z

I(z, c, d−1 ; µ)dΓ(z 0 |z)dµ(z, c, d−1 ) Z 0 +M I(z, 0, 0; µ)dΓ(z 0 |z)dΓE (z),

(17)

where I(z, c, d−1 ; µ) ≡ 1C(z,c,d−1 ;µ)=c0 1D(z,c,d−1 ;µ)=d 1X (z,c,d−1 ;µ)=0 is a combined indicator function for incumbents, I(z, 0, 0; µ) ≡ 1C(z,0,0;µ)=c0 1D(z,0,0;µ)=d × 1X (z,0,0;µ)=0 is a combined indicator function for potential entrants, and M 0 is the mass of potential entrants. Note that C(z, c, d−1 ; µ), D(z, c, d−1 ; µ), and X (z, c, d−1 ; µ) are the cash, R&D, and exit decision rules, respectively, for incumbents, while C(z, 0, 0; µ), D(z, 0, 0; µ), and X (z, 0, 0; µ) are the cash, R&D, and exit decision rules, respectively, for potential entrants. The “exit” decision X (z, 0, 0; µ) = 1 for potential entrants means that they throw away the z draws, while the “continue” decision

12

X (z, 0, 0; µ) = 0 means that they enter and produce with their z draws. The entry and exit dynamics in this type of model can be best described as “bottom churning.” That is, the worst firms exit every period and are replaced by entrants with higher z draws.

2.6

Industry Equilibrium

In this paper, we focus on the stationary industry equilibrium. Definition 1 A stationary industry equilibrium is a stationary distribution µ, a price P , a quantity Y , and policy functions C(z, c, d−1 ; µ), D(z, c, d−1 ; µ), and X (z, c, d−1 ; µ) such that: (i) policy functions solve the firm’s problem, given industry price P , industry output Y and distribution µ; (ii) the distribution µ is invariant over time; (iii) the free-entry condition is satisfied; and (iv) the product market clears.

3

Model Estimation

In this section, we apply the model described in Section 2 to data. We first select and construct a set of data moments, using a sample of firms that (i) operate in 3-digit SIC high-tech industries—SIC 283, SIC 357, SIC 366, SIC 367, SIC 382, SIC 384, and SIC 737—and (ii) have positive sales, positive assets, and non-missing R&D investment for the period 2000-2014 from Compustat.6 We then parameterize the model by matching selected data moments and show that our model is able to replicate high-tech firms’ R&D and cash-holding behavior observed in the data.

3.1

Parameterization

We set the length of a period in the model to be one year. The average real risk-free interest rate during the 2000s was 3.1%. We therefore set r to be 3%. 6

In approximately 17% of the firm-year observations, we have missing R&D expenditures. Although deleting those observations leads to a loss of data, the sample still contains enough information about firms’ R&D behavior.

13

We discretize technology z to 10 levels and calibrate their values as follows. We calculate firms’ value-added as the sum of their labor expenses and operating income before depreciation and deflate it by the production price index. Given our production function specification, the technology level is the ratio of firms’ real value added to employment. We then normalize the mean technology level to be 1 and set the value of zi , where i = {1, 2, ..., 10}, as the median of each decile of the distribution. We choose the value of elasticity of substitution between goods σ to match the markup charged by high-tech firms during the sample period. Markup is defined as the percentage of sales over cost of goods sold. We set σ to be 2 to match a 100% markup, which falls between the median and mean markup suggested by our sample. We calibrate dividend tax, corporate income tax, and R&D tax credits as follows. Dividend tax is chosen to be 15%, a rate commonly used in the literature (Hennessy and Whited, 2005). Corporate income tax τc is set at 35%, which is the statutory corporate income tax in the 2000s. The Internal Revenue Code provides three methods to calculate R&D tax credits, the simplest of which is called the Alternative Simplified Credit method. Using this approach, firms can claim a tax credit equal to 14% of qualified R&D expenditures that exceed a calculated base amount, while the base amount cannot be less than 50% of their current-year qualified expenditures. Therefore, we set the R&D tax credits to be 6%, slightly lower than half the 14% rate. [Table 1 about here.] Parameters are shown in Table 1. Panel A summarizes the parameters that are either directly calibrated from data or borrowed from other relevant studies. Panel B reports the remaining parameters, which are estimated using a Simulated Method of Moments (SMM) approach. That is, we recover underlying parameters from a list of selected moments by minimizing the distance between the moments constructed from model-simulated data and the moments computed with actual data. The match is quite close and the details are discussed in Subsection 3.2.2.

14

3.2

Comparative Statics and Parameter Identification

To identify the parameters that are not predetermined, we need moments that are informative— that is, sensitive to parameter changes. To this end and also to provide intuition about how each R&D feature influences high-tech firms’ cash and R&D decisions, we report comparative statics of the following parameters: R&D adjustment costs (γ0 and γ2 ), innovation uncertainty (δ and ρ), knowledge spillover (θ), external borrowing costs (λ0 and λ1 ), and market competition (σ and cF ). These parameters take the values of equally spaced points in the following intervals, respectively: γ0 ∈ [0, 0.1], γ2 ∈ [1, 3], δ ∈ [0.1, 0.3], ρ ∈ [0, 2], θ ∈ [0, 1], λ0 ∈ [0, 0.1], λ1 ∈ [0, 0.2], σ ∈ [1.9, 2.1], and cF ∈ [0.4, 0.8]. These intervals represent reasonable bounds on each parameter since the estimated parameter values are close to the center of the corresponding intervals. We change one parameter at a time, holding all other parameters at the calibrated or estimated values reported in Table 1.

3.2.1

Comparative Statics

Figures 1-3 plot the comparative statics results. Panels in the left column show the sensitivity of the first quartile, second quartile, third quartile, and industry mean of cash-to-firm value ratios with respect to each parameter, and panels on the right present the sensitivity of the first quartile, second quartile, third quartile of R&D-to-firm value ratios and exit rates.7 We report exit rates to give information about the changes in the stationary distribution of firms. [Figure 1 about here.] [Figure 2 about here.] [Figure 3 about here.]

3.2.1.1

R&D Adjustment Costs γ0 and γ2

Brown and Petersen (2011) argue that adjusting R&D spending is costly, and therefore firms facing financial frictions tend to accumulate valuable internal funds to smooth their R&D investment and avoid potentially large adjustment costs. More specifically, a large share of 7

To limit the effects of extreme outliers generated by sales data, we examine R&D-to-firm value and cash-to-firm value ratios, instead of R&D- and cash-to-sales ratios.

15

R&D expenses goes to pay the salaries of highly educated scientists, engineers, and other specialists. Their effort creates a firm’s knowledge base, which is embedded in its human capital. Turnover among these skilled workers can erode the firm’s knowledge base and lead to dissemination of proprietary information. Firms, therefore, have strong incentives to retain skilled employees, as reflected by the highly persistent R&D spending—which, in turn, implies substantial adjustment costs. The effects of R&D adjustment costs (γ0 and γ2 ) are shown in the top four panels of Figure 1. An increase in γ0 raises investment costs uniformly for firms, regardless of the magnitude of their investment adjustment, while a rise in γ2 increases the investment costs proportional to the square of adjustment. Both costs place a heavier financial burden on firms and tend to prompt them to keep more cash. However, quantitatively, these effects are rather minor. R&D investment tends to be naturally quite persistent, and R&D adjustment costs therefore do not have a large impact on cash holdings. In particular, productivity is stochastic, so that raising or lowering R&D investment does not have a direct effect on productivity, and accordingly, firms change R&D levels only when necessary. This implies that higher adjustment costs raise the cost of investment moderately and predictably without strengthening the precautionary motive much.

3.2.1.2

Innovation Efficiency δ

The parameter δ captures innovation efficiency, which affects the marginal product of R&D investment (Lyandres and Palazzo, 2014; Hsu, Li, and Lin, 2016). Hsu, Li, and Lin (2016) suggest a positive role of innovation efficiency in shaping high-tech firms’ cash policies. They argue that an increase in innovative efficiency (i.e., a drop in δ) generates stronger precautionary considerations by raising the likelihood of innovation success as well as the opportunity costs of being financially distressed. The responses of cash and R&D ratios to changes in δ are reported in the bottom two panels of Figure 1. Overall, firms at different levels of R&D intensity react to changes in δ in a similar fashion. An increase in δ makes innovation less efficient. Facing a higher probability of innovation failure, firms decide to invest more in R&D so as to improve innovation success rates and compete in the market. This explains the upward trend of R&D ratio. However, as δ further increases, fewer firms can survive in such uncertain environments. Followers that decide

16

to stay choose to take advantage of knowledge spillover and reduce their R&D investment to zero, while leaders struggle to maintain their R&D spending. This explains the decline in the R&D ratio when δ is high. An increase in δ affects firms’ cash policy through three interesting channels. First is the precautionary consideration. Higher R&D spending generates stronger demand for precautionary cash. Second is the substitution effect. Shifting more resources to R&D implies less is left for cash savings. Third is the income effect. A lower chance of innovation success reduces cash flow that can be allocated to cash stock. When δ is small, the first channel dominates: a higher δ leads to an increase in cash holdings. As δ continues to increase, the latter two channels become important, and cash ratios start to decrease with δ.

3.2.1.3

Innovation Volatility ρ

Incremental and radical innovations have different impacts on firms’ competitive positions and revenue. Little attention so far has been paid to the effect of this feature on cash policies. As shown in the top two panels of Figure 2, a rise in ρ—that is, a decline in the probability of realizing extreme outcomes—plays a role similar to an increase in δ. In response to an increase in ρ which implies a lower chance of drawing extremely negative and positive productivity, all firms become less concerned about radical failure and choose to increase their R&D expenditures to improve the likelihood of realizing radical innovation, yet in different magnitudes. High R&D intensive firms are the ones that respond more aggressively. An increase in ρ also impacts firms’ cash decisions in a way similar to δ. First, it strengthens firms’ incentives to invest in R&D, which increases firms’ needs for precautionary cash. Second, it shifts more resources to R&D, which reduces the resources available for cash reserves. These two channels compete with each other. When ρ is high, the second channel dominates.

3.2.1.4

Knowledge Spillover θ

Qiu and Wan (2015) emphasize a positive effect of technology spillover on cash policies. They argue that the enhancement of the marginal product of R&D via spillover provides firms with stronger incentives to apply external knowledge and perform R&D, which in turn leads to a higher demand for cash. Results of the effect of spillover on cash holdings are reported in the middle two panels of

17

Figure 2. They are in line with the findings by Qiu and Wan (2015), yet suggest a different mechanism. As spillover becomes greater, R&D intensive firms effectively have lower returns to knowledge investment. They are discouraged from innovating and choose to cut their R&D spending. Meanwhile, followers free ride leaders and reduce their own R&D expenditures. Lower R&D investment weakens the precautionary motive for cash. However, the decrease in precautionary cash savings is overpowered by the increase in the substitution away from R&D to cash (substitution effect) and the increase in income that knowledge spillover brings (income effect). Therefore, an increase in knowledge spillover drives up cash ratios until the parameter is larger than 0.85. A common theme so far is that the substitution and income effects are often at odds with the precautionary motive to hold cash. These conflicting forces then produce the observed hump shaped cash holding behavior.

3.2.1.5

Financial Frictions λ0 and λ1

One of the features frequently used to explain high-tech firms’ large cash positions is financial frictions (Falato, Kadyrzhanova, and Sim, 2013, Falato, Sim, Falato, and Sim, 2014; Hall and Lerner, 2010). Due to information asymmetries and low collateral value of R&D, high-tech firms face expensive equity-issuance costs. To avoid underinvestment in R&D caused by financial constraints, firms accumulate internal funds. Our results, reported in the bottom two panels of Figure 2 and the top two panels of Figure 3, tell a story in accordance with previous studies: An increase in financing costs, λ0 and λ1 , has no significant adverse effects on R&D investment, except for firms with high R&D that choose to cut their R&D ratio by about 2%. This finding implies that firms’ internal cash reserves largely eliminate possible underinvestment in R&D caused by financial frictions. At a certain point, further increases in financing costs do not have an impact on firms since they choose to self finance. In addition, fixed and linear equity issuance costs have different impacts on the cash policies of cash-poor firms. These firms choose to increase their cash ratios in response to an increase in λ0 to cut down on fixed issuance costs. On the other hand, they reduce their cash holdings if λ1 increases. When they face worse credit market conditions due to a proportional increase in external-financing costs, cash-poor firms choose to issue equity in smaller amounts and save

18

less.

3.2.1.6

Market Competition σ and cF

Market competition is another often-discussed determinant of high-tech firms’ cash policies (He and Wintoki, 2015; Lyandres and Palazzo, 2016; Ma, Mello, and Wu, 2014). It can be captured by two parameters in our model: elasticity of substitution between differentiated goods (σ) and fixed operating costs (cF ), with comparative statics shown in the last four panels of Figure 3. Elasticity of substitution σ reflects the degree of responsiveness in demand with respect to   σ price changes and determines the markup σ−1 that firms can charge above their marginal costs (w/z). An increase in the elasticity σ intensifies product market competition, and reduces markup and the expected benefit of entry. It drives up exit rates and induces higherproductivity firms to enter, which further increases competitive pressures in the industry. Firms therefore raise their R&D spending to compete and demand more precautionary cash savings. However, higher R&D investment implies higher expenditures, which compete for resources with cash savings. The second channel dominates the first at high values of σ and generates a hump-shaped response of cash ratios. Compared to an increase in σ, an increase in operating costs cF —another measure of intensified market competition—has qualitatively similar but quantitatively different impacts on high-tech firms’ cash and R&D policies. Therefore, disentangling different sources of market competition is necessary and can have important implications for the choice of pro-competition policies.

3.2.2

Parameter Identification

Given the comparative statics shown above, we choose the following moments to estimate our undetermined model parameters: the 25th and 75th percentiles of R&D-to-firm value and cash-to-firm value ratios, serial correlation of within-firm R&D and cash ratios, their correlation, fraction of firms with zero R&D investment, and firm exit rates. In particular, in the face of high fixed costs of adjusting R&D expenses γ0 , firms may select into non-R&D performers. The fraction of firms with zero R&D investment therefore can be used to infer γ0 . Given the degree of innovation uncertainty, the persistence of within-firm R&D ratio provides information on the magnitude of convex R&D adjustment costs γ2 .

19

The persistence of within-firm cash ratios can be used to infer the magnitude of fixed equity-issuance costs λ0 . A smaller λ0 leads to less lumpy equity issuance and a more smooth cash ratio. Cash-poor firms tend to be more sensitive to changes in credit market conditions. The 25th percentile of cash ratio thus contains information about linear equity-issuance costs λ1 . An increase in δ has significant impacts on firms’ R&D effort. It implies a higher chance of innovation failure and induces firms to invest more in R&D in order to promote success rates. We therefore use the 25th percentile of R&D ratio to identify δ. Changes in ρ affect the prospects for realizing breakthrough, which has impacts on leaders’ income and R&D effort and in turn affects their cash holdings through both substitution and income effects. We thus use the 75th percentile of cash ratio to estimate ρ. An increase in θ tends to have a discouraging effect on R&D investments. The 75th percentile of R&D ratio, therefore, is informative about the size of knowledge spillover θ. We infer fixed operating costs cF from firm exit rates. As cF increases, fewer firms can cover the costs and are more likely to choose to exit the market. Lastly, we estimate wage costs w from the correlation between R&D investment and cash holdings. In response to a higher wage rate, firms pass the increased production costs to customers by setting higher product prices. The corresponding changes in income move cash and R&D investment in the same direction through the income effect, which generates a higher correlation between them.

3.3

Estimation Results

In this subsection, we report estimation results of the model described in Section 2.

3.3.1

Parameter Estimates

Parameter estimates are reported in Panel B of Table 1. The estimated γ0 is 0.057, which implies that the fixed R&D adjustment cost is roughly equal to 2% of an average firm’s sales. The estimated γ2 is 2.30. This value suggests that if current R&D investment deviates from the past value by 10%, the convex adjustment costs would amount to approximately 1% of R&D investment. Very few structural estimates of R&D adjustment costs are available in the literature. Li and Liu (2012) find the convex R&D stock adjustment cost is larger than that of

20

physical capital; their estimates range from 3.26 to 67.47, depending on model specifications. Kung (2014) sets the convex R&D adjustment cost parameter to be 3.3 by matching the relative volatility of R&D investment growth to consumption growth in the data. Our estimate of the convex adjustment costs γ2 appears to be close to the lower bound of their estimates. Given the different adjustment-cost specifications, one should be cautious about making direct comparisons. However, our estimate delivers a message consistent with that of Li and Liu (2012) and other R&D studies—that is, R&D adjustment costs are high. Two other parameters inferred from firms’ R&D and cash behavior are innovation efficiency δ and knowledge spillover θ. The estimate of δ is 0.1959, which implies moderate risks associated with innovation in general. The estimate of θ is critical for measuring returns to R&D for policy considerations. Our estimate of θ is 0.5789, which is lower than the estimate provided by Xu (2008) and indicates relatively small intra-industry externalities among publicly traded technology companies. The estimated fixed and linear equity-issuance costs, λ0 and λ1 , are 0.0456 and 0.1198, respectively. The linear cost is higher than the value estimated by Hennessy and Whited (2007) who find it to be approximately 0.091. We conjecture that our higher estimate arises from a different sample of firms. We examine high-tech companies who tend to be collateral poor due to information asymmetries and thus face higher external borrowing costs. The parameter ρ is newly introduced to the R&D literature. It relaxes the restriction imposed by previous studies in which firms can only conduct incremental innovation and move to a productivity level that is equal or close to their current positions (Xu, 2008; Hashmi and Van Biesebroeck, 2016). When ρ equals zero, there is an equal chance of realizing incremental and radical innovation and reaching any level other than the current one. The larger the parameter, the greater the likelihood that firms will move to the closest value. The estimated ρ is 0.7578, implying a 5.7% chance of moving from median productivity to technological frontier. Lastly, the fixed operating cost cF is 0.6583. This value amounts to roughly 32% of an average firm’s sales.

21

3.3.2

Simulated Model Moments

Tables 2 and 3 report the data moments and their corresponding simulated model moments, including the moments of R&D-to-firm value and cash-to-firm value ratios, share of non-R&D performers, and exit rates. To be consistent with our model, we treat it as an exit if firms are deleted from Compustat due to bankruptcy (data item dlrsn is 2), liquidation (data item dlrsn is 3), or acquisition and merger (data item dlrsn is 1, 4, or 6) when previous sales growth is negative. Table 2 presents the targeted model moments at the point estimates reported in Table 1. As shown, most targets are well matched. The model-implied first and third quartiles of R&D and cash distributions, within-firm serial correlation of R&D investment and cash holdings, fraction of non-R&D performers, and exit rates are all close to data moments. The correlation between R&D and cash is slightly undershot by the model, 0.368 vs. 0.285. [Table 2 about here.] We further evaluate model performance by comparing the model-implied distributions of R&D and cash ratios with the empirical distributions derived from data. We consider the following nontargeted moments: industry average, cross-sectional dispersion, industry median, and the k th percentile of variable distribution with k = {1, 5, 10, 90, 95, 99}. Results are reported in Table 3. As can be seen, model-implied distributions closely resemble the data. The industry average, cross-sectional dispersion, and the right tails of R&D and cash distributions are all close to their data counterparts. An exception is the left tail of cash-to-firm value ratio. Compared to the data, the model implies a slightly thinner left tail of cash distribution—5th and 10th percentiles—and overshoots the industry median cash ratio. [Table 3 about here.] Overall, the model is able to achieve a good match for both cross-sectional heterogeneity and within-firm dynamics and explain the key patterns of firms’ R&D and cash-holding behavior observed in the data. This validates and serves as a test of our model to strengthen the reliability of parameter estimates reported in Table 1.

22

4

Model Implications

In the following subsections, we use the parameter estimates obtained in Section 3 to quantitatively evaluate the role of each R&D feature in explaining the observed large cash stocks maintained by high-tech firms. We further use the model to shed light on the effectiveness of R&D tax credits. In particular, we explore the transmission channels of the policy, which provides important implications for productivity improvement.

4.1

Why Do High-tech Firms Hold So Much Cash?

In this subsection, we rely on the structural estimates obtained above to quantify the importance of key R&D features in explaining innovative firms’ cash and R&D choices. We consider the following factors: R&D adjustment costs (γ0 and γ2 ), innovation uncertainty (δ and ρ), knowledge spillover (θ), financial frictions caused by the non-collaterability of R&D and information asymmetry between firms and investors (λ0 and λ1 ), and market competition (σ and cF ). We change one parameter at a time, holding all other parameters constant. Two effects are examined: (i) local effects by changing the value of each parameter by 5%, and (ii) global effects by shutting down each feature.

4.1.1

Local Effects

First, we explore the effects of each feature locally by changing their parameter values by 5%. We change the parameters in the direction which enhances or strengthens each mechanism. For instance, lowering ρ increases innovation volatility while raising θ increases knowledge spillover. Results are reported in Table 4. [Table 4 about here.] Our estimation results suggest that R&D adjustment costs may not be a first-order factor in explaining innovative firms’ high cash balances, which echoes the comparative statics analysis in Subsection 3.2.1. A 5% increase in adjustment costs has little effect on firms’ cash demand and R&D choices.

23

A 5% increase in innovation efficiency, which is captured by a drop in δ, barely changes the average cash ratio. The minor change is caused by the interaction between the precautionary motive, substitution effect, and income effect. A decrease in δ drives down the likelihood of innovation failure. It discourages R&D spending and generates higher revenue. The weakened precautionary motive is offset by the increase in cash brought by substitution and income effects. A 5% decrease in ρ increases innovation volatility and generates a 8.2% increase in the average cash ratio. It is the most important contributor to high-tech firms’ cash demand locally. Knowledge spillover θ is the second most important factor in driving high-tech firms’ cash policy. A 5% increase in the externality drives up the mean cash ratio by 6.4%. Financial frictions also matter. The fixed equity issuance cost λ0 is another main driver, while the linear equity issuance cost λ1 plays a limited role. To economize on the fixed issuance costs, firms on average increase their cash ratios by 2.7% in response to a 5% increase in λ0 . Intensified market competition—a higher elasticity of substitution σ or a high operating cost cF —reduces firms’ cash holdings. In particular, a 5% higher elasticity induces a 67.1% drop in the average cash ratio, and a 5% rise in fixed operating costs reduces cash ratio by 19.2%. Both are due to the resource substitution away from cash to R&D investment.

4.1.2

Robustness

Although we computed the elasticity of cash to parameter changes in the previous subsection, there are alternative ways to compare local effects. One such alternative method is to change the value of each parameter such that average firm value increases by 1%. We can then re-evaluate the effects of each factor on firms’ cash choices. Results are reported in Table 5. Of course, we could also standardize parameter perturbations by a particular percentage increase or decrease of other moments such as sales. Average firm value, however, has the nice property that all parameters have an effect on it, which is not true of most other moments. [Table 5 about here.] Overall, our results are quite robust. Higher innovation volatility and greater knowledge spillover remain the key contributors to high-tech firms’ large cash balances. They drive up the average cash ratio by more than 7%, followed by financial frictions.

24

Moreover, one result in Table 4 is overturned. As the fixed R&D adjustment cost γ0 further increases, it starts to play a sizeable role in shaping innovative firms’ cash policies. In particular, a 8% increase in γ0 strengthens the precautionary motive for holding cash among cash-poor firms and pushes up the mean cash ratio by 5%.

4.1.3

Global Effects

Next, we quantify the effects of each R&D feature globally by shutting them down in turn. We either set the parameter to zero or set the parameter such that the average firm value changes by 25%. We don’t push down all parameters to zero because it either doesn’t make sense to do so or there is too strong of an effect. For example, setting the innovation efficiency parameter δ to zero would actually increase innovation efficiency instead of shutting it down or reducing it. Specifically, we set adjustment costs (γ0 and γ2 ), knowledge spillover (θ), and financial frictions (λ0 and λ1 ) to zeros. We raise δ and ρ to reduce the level of innovation efficiency and innovation volatility, respectively, and lower σ and cF to reduce the degree of market competition, each of which changes firm value by 25%. Note that reducing innovation efficiency and volatility lowers firm value by 25%, while reducing market competition raises firm value by 25%. Results are reported in Table 6. To ease the comparison between the importance of each feature in explaining innovative firms’ high cash balances, we report the percentage changes in average cash ratio relative to our benchmark model in the third column. [Table 6 about here.] Results in Table 6 suggest that the key contributor to high-tech firms’ cash stock is innovation volatility associated with the probability of realizing breakthroughs. When we shut down the innovation uncertainty channel by raising ρ from 0.7578 to 1.33, the chance of moving from median productivity to the technological frontier falls from 5.7% to 1.7%. Firms then devote more resources to R&D to improve innovation success rates. Higher expenses, together with lower income, leave fewer resources for cash savings. Firms’ average cash ratio drops by 53%. Results of global perturbations also confirm the importance of knowledge spillover and financial frictions. Closing these channels reduces the average cash ratio by 36.5% and 32.9%, respectively.

25

In addition, market competition is another factor that is critical for understanding innovative firms’ large cash reserves; yet, it exhibits non-monotonic effects as shown and explained in Subsection 3.2.1.6. The non-monotonicity arises from the change in the stationary distribution of firms. A lower product substitutability implies a higher markup and profitability, which leads more low-productivity firms to stay and compete in the market by investing in R&D. These low-productivity firms tend to be financially constrained and have fewer resources to allocate to cash stocks, which drives down the average cash ratio. A lower fixed operating cost reduces competition by producing a higher expected return of entry and driving up the entry cost. It leads to a lower cash demand due to lower R&D investment and operating expenses. R&D adjustment costs play a less important role than the other four elements. The absence of adjustment costs mainly reduces the real costs of investment and, in turn, raises the level of R&D expenditures. The presence of financial frictions and innovation uncertainty guarantees the value of cash, regardless of the magnitude of R&D adjustment costs. In sum, Tables 4-6 shed light on the main drivers behind innovative firms’ large cash balances. Our results suggest that the main contributor is innovation uncertainty, followed by knowledge spillover and financial frictions. Market competition has non-monotonic effects on firms’ cash policy, and R&D adjustment costs matter the least.

4.2

Policy Implications

We next explore policy implications of our model. Two classic questions in the R&D innovation literature are the impacts of knowledge spillover and financing frictions on R&D investment. Previous studies argue that both factors can cause market failure for R&D. An extensive body of empirical evidence supports the former, while the empirical support for the latter is more mixed.8 Our comparative statics results in Section 3.2.1 support some of the previous empirical findings. We find a significant reduction of R&D investment due to knowledge spillover, but knowledge spillover also raises average firm value. On the other hand, we do not find much quantitative impact from financial frictions on R&D investment. Worse credit conditions are largely absorbed by changes in cash policy, which alleviates the possible market failure. 8

See, for example, the literature review provided by Hall and Lerner (2010).

26

One of the often-used solutions to possible underinvestment stemming from knowledge spillover is the introduction of R&D tax credits. We use our model to evaluate the effects of this tax policy on productivity and explore its transmission channels. To do so, we first compute the industry average productivity implied by our benchmark model with and without R&D tax credits. Their difference gives the effects of tax credits on productivity. We then shut down each R&D feature alternately using the values in previous section, and examine their respective magnitudes and roles in policy transmission by comparing the resulting average productivity for τrd = 0 and τrd = 0.06. Results are reported in Table 7. [Table 7 about here.] Panel A of Table 7 suggests that in our benchmark model, a 6% R&D tax credit raises R&D investment and drives up the average productivity by 3.5%. Panel B reports the role of each R&D feature in affecting the efficacy of R&D tax credits. We find the following. Fixed R&D adjustment costs hinder the benefits of tax credits. Without fixed adjustment costs, tax credits would improve productivity by 4%. Innovation volatility, fixed and linear equity issuance costs, and market competition induced by low fixed costs also weaken the effectiveness of tax credits. Without these features, the productivity improvement generated by tax credits would rise to 5.7%, 5.3%, 5.4% and 6.5%, respectively. The convex R&D adjustment cost has no impacts on the effectiveness of tax-credit policy. However, the absence of this feature would significantly improve productivity, 1.214 vs. 1.190 (without tax credits) and 1.256 vs. 1.232 (with tax credits). Innovation efficiency improves the effectiveness of R&D tax credits in boosting productivity. A lower innovation efficiency would reduce the beneficial effects of tax incentives from 3.5% to 3.0%. Moreover, lower innovation efficiency reduces the average productivity in the industry, 1.152 vs. 1.190 (without tax credits) and 1.187 vs. 1.232 (with tax credits). Market competition generated by an increase in product substitutability is another channel to enhance the effectiveness of R&D tax credits. In particular, a drop in the elasticity of substitution would limit the effectiveness of tax credits from 3.5% to 3.3%. Knowledge spillover is a particularly interesting case. Shutting down knowledge spillover increases average productivity by 4.4%. However, a R&D tax credit in an economy without knowledge spillover has poor efficacy and only raises productivity by 1.4%. Firms already have

27

a strong incentive to invest in R&D when there is no knowledge spillover and a tax credit cannot push up investment or productivity much more. To sum up, R&D adjustment costs, knowledge spillover, and innovation uncertainty have the largest impacts on productivity. Also, tax credits are the most effective in economies with low innovation volatility, financial frictions, and fixed operating costs. Tax credits are the least effective in economies with low knowledge spillover. Policymakers could argue quite positively for R&D tax credits since a 6% credit boosts productivity by at least 3% in most cases. However, we can only know whether these credits are worth the cost with general equilibrium analysis.

5

Conclusion

High-tech firms hold a large amount of cash. A better understanding of their joint R&D and cash choices can help design policies to promote R&D investment and productivity. In this paper, we systematically analyze how unique features of R&D shape R&D and cash decisions and assess their respective importance in explaining the observed high cash balances. The model embeds five key factors highly relevant for high-tech industries: R&D adjustment costs, financial frictions, knowledge spillover, innovation uncertainty, and market competition. We show that our estimated model successfully replicates the empirical patterns of industry-level and firm-level R&D and cash choices. We then use the validated model to determine the quantitative importance of relevant R&D features in explaining high-tech firms’ substantial cash reserves. We find the following. Innovation uncertainty matters the most for the observed strong cash demand, followed by knowledge spillover and financial frictions. R&D adjustment costs have a relatively weak relationship with cash policy, and market competition has non-monotonic effects on cash holdings. Our model also has policy implications. It sheds light on the mechanisms which impact R&D investment, the effectiveness of R&D tax credits, and the efficient transmission channels. We find that greater knowledge spillover significantly reduces R&D spending, while worse credit market conditions have minor impacts on R&D intensity and mainly just influences the cash decisions of firms. We also find that R&D tax credits can effectively boost investment and productivity.

28

A

Appendix

A.1

Model Solution

First recall that the firm i’s output yi is a function of productivity shock zi and labor li :

yi = zi li .

A relationship between aggregate price P and individual price pi is derived by minimizing the cost of acquiring a fixed amount of aggregate good Y¯ . Therefore, we want to solve the following minimization problem:

min {P Y } = min yi

( X

yi

subject to, X

σ−1 σ

!

) pi yi

i

σ σ−1

= Y¯ .

yi

i

The Lagrangian is expressed as,  L=

X

pi yi + η Y¯ −

X

i

σ−1 σ

!

yi

σ σ−1

 

i

where η is the Lagrange multiplier. The first-order condition with respect to yi is,

pi = η

X

σ−1 σ

!

1 σ−1

yi

− σ1

yi

,

i

which then simplifies to, pσi yi = P σ Y, since the Lagrange multiplier η is equal to P . Then to find the profit maximizing price, we solve max{πi } = max{pi yi − wli }. pi

pi

29

The first order condition with respect to pi gives the optimal price as a markup over marginal cost, pi =

σ w . σ − 1 zi

Finally, profit can be rewritten as, πi =pi yi − wli − cf + rci − di −1 =(P σ Y )p1−σ − (P σ Y )wp−σ i i zi − cf + rci − di

=(P σ Y )σ −σ (σ − 1)σ−1 w1−σ ziσ−1 − cf + rci − di   (σ − 1)zi σ−1 1 σ − cf + rci − di . =(P Y ) σw σ Without loss of generality and for simplicity, we normalize P σ Y to 1 rather than w to 1 as in Melitz (2003).

30

References Abel, A. and J. Eberly (2002). Investment and q with Fixed Costs: An Empirical Analysis. Working Paper . Bates, T., K. Kahle, and R. Stulz (2009). Why Do U.S. Firms Hold So Much More Cash than They Used To? Journal of Finance 64 (5), 1985–2021. Bond, S., D. Harhoff, and J. Van Reenen (2005). Investment, R&D and Financial Constraints ´ in Britain and Germany. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique (December), 433–460. Brown, J., S. Fazzari, and B. Petersen (2009). Financing External Innovation and Growth: Cash Flow, Equity, and the 1990s R&D Boom. Journal of Finance 64 (1), 151–185. Brown, J. and B. Petersen (2011). Cash Holdings and R&D Smoothing. Journal of Corporate Finance 17 (3), 694–709. Christiano, L., M. Eichenbaum, and C. Evans (2005). Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy. Journal of Political Economy 113 (1), 1–45. Cooper, R. and J. Haltiwanger (2006). On the Nature of Capital Adjustment Costs. Review of Economic Studies 73 (3), 611–633. Del Negro, M. and F. Schorfheide (2008). Forming Priors for DSGE Models (and How It Affects the Assessment of Nominal Rigidities). Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (7), 1191–1208. Ericson, R. and A. Pakes (1995). Markov-perfect Industry Dynamics: A Framework for Empirical Work. Review of Economic Studies 62 (1), 53–82. Falato, A., D. Kadyrzhanova, and J. W. Sim (2013). Rising Intangible Capital, Shrinking Debt Capacity, and the US Corporate Savings Glut. Working Paper . Falato, A., J. Sim, A. Falato, and J. W. Sim (2014). Why Do Innovative Firms Hold So Much Cash ? Evidence from Changes in State R&D Tax Credits. Working Paper . Foley, F., J. Hartzell, S. Titman, and G. Twite (2007). Why Do Firms Hold So Much Cash? A Tax-Based Explanation. Journal of Financial Economics 86, 579–607.

31

Hall, B. (1993). R&D Tax Policy During the 1980s: Success or Failure? Tax Policy and the Economy 21, 1 – 36. Hall, B. and J. Lerner (2010). The Financing of R&D and Innovation. Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, Volume 1 01 (10), 609–639. Hall, B., P. Moncada-Patern`o-Castello, S. Montresor, and A. Vezzani (2015). Financing constraints, R&D investments and innovative performances: new empirical evidence at the firm level for Europe. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 8599 (October), 1–14. Hashmi, A. R. and J. Van Biesebroeck (2016). The Relationship between Market Structure and Innovation in Industry Equilibrium: A Case Study of the Global Automobile Industry. Review of Economics and Statstics 98 (1), 192–208. He, Z. and B. Wintoki (2015). The Cost of R&D and the High Cash Holdings in the U.S. Working Paper . Hennessy, C. and T. Whited (2005). Debt Dynamics. Journal of Finance 60 (3), 1129–1165. Hennessy, C. and T. Whited (2007). How Costly Is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Journal of Finance 62 (4), 1705–1745. Hopenhayn, H. (1992). Entry, Exit, and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium. Econometrica 60 (5), 1127–1150. Hsu, P.-H., F. Li, and T.-C. Lin (2016). Do Innovative Firms Hold More Cash? The International Evidence. Working Paper, University of Hong Kong. Klette, T. J. and S. Kortum (2004). Innovating Firms and Aggregate Innovation. Journal of Political Economy 112 (5), 986–1018. Kung, H. (2014). Macroeconomic linkages between monetary policy and the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Financial Economics (February), 1–16. Li, E. and L. Liu (2012). Intangible Assets and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns: Evidence from Structural Estimation. Working Paper (852).

32

Lyandres, E. and B. Palazzo (2014). Cash Holdings, Competition, and Innovation. Working Paper . Lyandres, E. and B. Palazzo (2016). Cash Holdings, Competition, and Innovation. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, forthcoming. Ma, L., A. Mello, and Y. Wu (2014). Industry Competition, Winner’s Advantage, and Cash Holdings. Working Paper . Melitz, M. J. (2003). The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity. Econometrica 71 (6), 1695–1725. Nikolov, B. and T. Whited (2014). Agency Conflicts and Cash: Estimates from a Dynamic Model. Journal of Finance 69 (5), 1883–1921. Qiu, J. and C. Wan (2015). Technology Spillovers and Corporate Cash Holdings. Journal of Financial Economics 115 (3), 558–573. Riddick, L. and T. Whited (2009). The Corporate Propensity to Save. Journal of Finance 64 (4), 1729–1766. Schmitt-Grohe, S. and M. Uribe (2005). Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model: Expanded Version. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 20. Xu, Y. (2008). A Structural Empirical Model of R&D, Firm Heterogeneity, and Industry Evolution. Working Paper . Zhao, J. (2016). Accounting for the Corporate Cash Increase. Working Paper .

33

0.1 0.3

Q1

Q2

Q3

mean

Q1

Q2

Q3

exit rate

0.09 0.08

R&D ratios and exit rate

0.25

cash ratios

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02

0.05 0.01 0

0 0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09

0.1

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09

0.1

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

0.22

0.24

0.26

0.28

0.3

0

0.35

0.1 0.09

0.3

R&D ratios and exit rate

0.08

cash ratios

0.25

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02

0.05 0.01 0

0 1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

2 2

0.2

0.3

0.18 0.25

R&D ratios and exit rate

0.16

cash ratios

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04

0.05 0.02 0 0.1

0.12

0.14

0.16

0.18

0.2

0.22

0.24

0.26

0.28

0 0.1

0.3

0.12

0.14

0.16

0.18

0.2

Figure 1: Comparative Statics I. This figure plots the effects of fixed R&D adjustment costs γ0 , convex R&D adjustment costs γ2 , and innovation efficiency δ on (i) cash-to-firm value ratio, (ii) R&D-to-firm value ratio, and (iii) exit rates.

34

0.4

0.12 Q1

Q2

Q3

mean

Q1

Q2

Q3

exit rate

0.35 0.1

R&D ratios and exit rate

0.3

cash ratios

0.25

0.2

0.15

0.08

0.06

0.04

0.1 0.02 0.05

0

0 0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

0.4

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09

0.1

0.15

0.35

R&D ratios and exit rate

0.3

cash ratios

0.25

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.05

0.1

0.05

0

0 0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0.14

0.3

0.12

R&D ratios and exit rate

0.35

cash ratios

0.25

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.05

0.1

0.08

0.06

0.04

0.02

0

0 0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09

0.1

0

0

Figure 2: Comparative Statics II. This figure plots the effects of innovation volatility ρ, knowledge spillover θ, and fixed equity issuance costs λ0 on (i) cash-to-firm value ratio, (ii) R&D-to-firm value ratio, and (iii) exit rates.

35

0.12

0.35 Q1

Q2

Q3

mean

Q1

0.3

Q3

exit rate

0.1

R&D ratios and exit rate

0.25

cash ratios

Q2

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.08

0.06

0.04

0.02

0.05

0

0 0

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

0.14

0.16

0.18

0.2

0

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

1

0.12

0.14

0.16

0.18

0.2

1

0.12 0.3 0.1

R&D ratios and exit rate

cash ratios

0.25

0.2

0.15

0.1

1.92

1.94

1.96

1.98

2

2.02

2.04

2.06

2.08

0.04

0 1.9

2.1

0.12

0.25

0.1

R&D ratios and exit rate

0.3

0.2

cash ratios

0.06

0.02

0.05

0 1.9

0.08

0.15

0.1

0.05

0 0.4

1.92

1.94

1.96

1.98

2

2.02

2.04

2.06

2.08

2.1

0.08

0.06

0.04

0.02

0.45

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7

0.75

0 0.4

0.8

c

0.45

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

c

F

F

Figure 3: Comparative Statics III. This figure plots the effects of linear equity issuance costs λ1 , elasticity of substitution σ, and fixed operating costs cF on (i) cash-to-firm value ratio, (ii) R&D-to-firm value ratio, and (iii) exit rates.

36

Table 1: Model Parameterizations Table 1 summarizes the parameters used to solve the model at annual frequency. Panel A reports the parameters calibrated separately from data or borrowed from other studies. Panel B presents estimation results by taking parameters in Panel A as given and jointly matching nine selected data moments. Standard errors are presented in parentheses. Panel A: Parameters Calibrated Separately Real risk-free rate (r) Elasticity of substitution (σ) Dividend tax (τd ) Statutory corporate income tax (τc ) R&D tax credits (τrd )

0.03 2.00 0.15 0.35 0.06

Panel B: Parameters Estimated by SMM Fixed costs of external finance (λ0 ) Linear costs of external finance (λ1 ) Fixed adjustment cost (γ0 ) Convex adjustment cost (γ2 ) Innovation efficiency (δ) Knowledge spillover (θ) Innovation volatility (ρ) Fixed operating cost (cF ) Wage cost (w)

37

0.0456 0.1198 0.0570 2.3018 0.1959 0.5789 0.7578 0.6583 0.2265

(0.0003) (0.0300) (0.0198) (0.7006) (0.0019) (0.0017) (0.0069) (0.0058) (0.0008)

Table 2: Simulated Model Moments: Targeted Moments Table 2 reports both data and corresponding model moments. Data moments are calculated based on a sample of Compustat high-tech firms over the period 2000-2014. Moments

Data

Model

(i) R&D: 25th percentile of R&D-to-firm value ratio 75th percentile of R&D-to-firm value ratio Serial correlation of within-firm R&D-to-firm value ratio Fraction of firms with zero R&D investment

0.022 0.100 0.519 0.020

0.035 0.082 0.536 0.020

(ii) Cash: 25th percentile of cash-to-firm value ratio 75th percentile of cash-to-firm value ratio Serial correlation of within-firm cash-to-firm value ratio Correlation with R&D-to-firm value ratio

0.061 0.250 0.693 0.368

0.057 0.259 0.631 0.285

(iii) Market competition: Exit rate

0.019

0.019

38

Table 3: Simulated Model Moments: Nontargeted Moments Table 3 presents nontargeted moments for R&D-to-firm value ratio and cash-to-firm value ratio. Data moments are calculated based on a sample of Compustat high-tech firms over the period 2000-2014. Moments

Data

Model

(i) R&D: Industry average R&D-to-firm value ratio Cross-sectional dispersion of R&D-to-firm value ratio Industry median R&D-to-firm value ratio 1-percentile of R&D-to-firm value ratio 5-percentile of R&D-to-firm value ratio 10-percentile of R&D-to-firm value ratio 90-percentile of R&D-to-firm value ratio 95-percentile of R&D-to-firm value ratio 99-percentile of R&D-to-firm value ratio

0.082 0.109 0.048 0.000 0.003 0.008 0.182 0.260 0.513

0.084 0.113 0.052 0.000 0.031 0.035 0.156 0.239 0.603

(ii) Cash: Industry average cash-to-firm value ratio Cross-sectional dispersion of cash-to-firm value ratio Industry median cash-to-firm value ratio 1-percentile of cash-to-firm value ratio 5-percentile of cash-to-firm value ratio 10-percentile of cash-to-firm value ratio 90-percentile of cash-to-firm value ratio 95-percentile of cash-to-firm value ratio 99-percentile of cash-to-firm value ratio

0.193 0.212 0.135 0.000 0.008 0.021 0.425 0.582 1.012

0.219 0.200 0.226 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.418 0.534 0.976

39

Table 4: Local Role of R&D Features Table 4 summarizes the effects of each key R&D feature on firms’ R&D and cash choices locally, by changing the value of each parameter by 5% in the direction which enhances or strengthens the mechanism. The arrows beside each parameter indicates whether the parameter increases or decreases to strengthen the mechanism. The percentage change in average firm value compared to the benchmark model is reported in the last column. Cash

R&D

Firm Value

Mean

1st quartile

3rd quartile

Median

1st quartile

3rd quartile

Benchmark Model

0.219

0.057

0.259

0.052

0.035

0.082

R&D Adjustment Costs Fixed adjustment cost (γ0 ↑ 0.0599) Convex adjustment cost (γ2 ↑ 2.417)

0.219 0.218

0.057 0.057

0.259 0.259

0.053 0.052

0.035 0.035

0.082 0.082

0.1% −0.2%

Innovation Uncertainty Innovation efficiency (δ ↓ 0.186) Innovation volatility (ρ ↓ 0.720)

0.218 0.237

0.096 0.082

0.271 0.294

0.050 0.051

0.033 0.035

0.083 0.082

16.6% 3.4%

Externality Knowledge spillover (θ ↑ 0.608)

0.233

0.062

0.294

0.050

0.035

0.080

2.0%

Financial Frictions Fixed equity-issuance cost (λ0 ↑ 0.0479) Linear equity-issuance cost (λ1 ↑ 0.126)

0.225 0.220

0.061 0.057

0.297 0.260

0.052 0.052

0.035 0.035

0.082 0.082

0.5% −0.2%

Market Competition Elasticity of substitution (σ ↑ 2.100) Fixed operating costs (cF ↑ 0.691)

0.072 0.177

0.000 0.020

0.026 0.205

0.061 0.058

0.046 0.040

0.094 0.103

−41.5% −18.2%

40

% change

Table 5: Local Role of R&D Features: Robustness Table 5 summarizes the effects of each key R&D feature on firms’ R&D and cash choices when we change the value of each parameter such that the average firm value increases by 1%. Cash

R&D

Mean

1st quartile

3rd quartile

Median

1st quartile

3rd quartile

Benchmark Model

0.219

0.057

0.259

0.052

0.035

0.082

R&D Adjustment Costs Fixed adjustment cost (γ0 ↑ 0.0616) Convex adjustment cost (γ2 ↓ 1.944)

0.230 0.218

0.068 0.056

0.259 0.258

0.052 0.054

0.035 0.036

0.083 0.083

Innovation Uncertainty Innovation efficiency (δ ↓ 0.195) Innovation volatility (ρ ↓ 0.750)

0.231 0.235

0.060 0.061

0.258 0.288

0.052 0.052

0.035 0.035

0.081 0.081

Externality Knowledge spillover (θ ↑ 0.592)

0.242

0.061

0.287

0.052

0.035

0.081

Financial Frictions Fixed equity-issuance cost (λ0 ↑ 0.0483) Linear equity-issuance cost (λ1 ↓ 0.108)

0.226 0.232

0.066 0.064

0.297 0.259

0.052 0.052

0.035 0.035

0.082 0.081

Market Competition Elasticity of substitution (σ ↓ 1.997) Fixed operating costs (cF ↓ 0.655)

0.228 0.226

0.056 0.056

0.257 0.257

0.052 0.053

0.036 0.036

0.080 0.080

41

Table 6: Global Role of R&D Features Table 6 summarizes the effects of each key R&D feature on firms’ R&D and cash choices globally, by shutting down each feature alternately. We set adjustment costs (γ0 and γ2 ), knowledge spillover (θ), and financial frictions (λ0 and λ1 ) to be zeros. We lower the levels of innovation efficiency (δ), innovation volatility (ρ), and market competition (σ and cF ) such that each of these parameters changes firm value by 25%. The arrows beside each parameter indicates whether the parameter increases or decreases to shutdown the mechanism. The percentage change in average firm value compared to the benchmark model is reported in the last column. Cash Mean

R&D

% change

Firm Value

Median

1st quartile

3rd quartile

0.052

0.035

0.082

% change

Benchmark Model

0.219

R&D Adjustment Costs Fixed adjustment cost (γ0 ↓ 0) Convex adjustment cost (γ2 ↓ 0) Both adjustment costs (γ0 and γ2 ↓ 0)

0.210 0.204 0.232

-4.11% -6.85% 5.94%

0.058 0.063 0.060

0.035 0.029 0.024

0.078 0.086 0.086

3.3% 1.8% 9.8%

Innovation Uncertainty Innovation efficiency (δ ↑ 0.212) Innovation volatility (ρ ↑ 1.330)

0.173 0.103

-21.0% -53.0%

0.061 0.057

0.043 0.042

0.102 0.089

−25% −25%

Externality Knowledge spillover (θ ↓ 0)

0.139

-36.5%

0.084

0.055

0.147

−25.8%

Financial Frictions Fixed equity-issuance cost (λ0 ↓ 0) Linear equity-issuance cost (λ1 ↓ 0)

0.147 0.154

-32.9% -29.7%

0.060 0.059

0.039 0.039

0.103 0.100

−1.5% −1.6%

Market Competition Elasticity of substitution (σ ↓ 1.947) Fixed operating costs (cF ↓ 0.595)

0.165 0.154

-24.7% -29.7%

0.046 0.047

0.036 0.033

0.071 0.073

25% 25%

42

Table 7: Policy Implications: R&D Tax Credits Table 7 summarizes the model’s implications for R&D tax credits. Panel A reports the average productivity implied by our benchmark model with and without R&D tax credits. Panel B shows the effects of R&D features on the transmission of tax incentives, by shutting down each mechanism alternately. We set adjustment costs (γ0 and γ2 ), knowledge spillover (θ), and financial frictions (λ0 and λ1 ) to be zeros. We lower the levels of innovation efficiency (δ), innovation volatility (ρ), and market competition (σ and cF ) such that each of these parameters changes firm value by 25%. The arrows beside each parameter indicates whether the parameter increases or decreases to shutdown the mechanism. Average productivity (τrd = 0)

Average productivity (τrd = 0.06)

Percentage change

Panel A: Benchmark Specification Benchmark model

1.190

1.232

3.5%

Panel B: Channel Exploration Fixed adjustment cost (γ0 ↓ 0) Convex adjustment cost (γ2 ↓ 0)

1.200 1.214

1.248 1.256

4.0% 3.5%

Knowledge spillover (θ ↓ 0)

1.268

1.286

1.4%

Innovation efficiency (δ ↑ 0.212) Innovation volatility (ρ ↑ 1.330)

1.152 1.095

1.187 1.157

3.0% 5.7%

Fixed equity-issuance cost (λ0 ↓ 0) Linear equity-issuance cost (λ1 ↓ 0)

1.175 1.174

1.237 1.237

5.3% 5.4%

Elasticity of substitution (σ ↓ 1.947) Fixed operating costs (cF ↓ 0.595)

1.197 1.161

1.236 1.237

3.3% 6.5%

43

R&D Dynamics and Corporate Cash

effective policy tools that the government can use to boost productivity given that R&D is a key driver of productivity and ... compare the average cash ratios for high-tech firms with and without foreign income. Interestingly ... the model and validate it by demonstrating its ability to match relevant data moments. We then use the ...

466KB Sizes 0 Downloads 168 Views

Recommend Documents

R&D Dynamics and Corporate Cash - SSRN
Firms in R&D intensive industries hold more cash than firms in R&D non-intensive industries. Potential explanations in the literature for the high cash holdings of R&D intensive firms include. R&D adjustment costs, financial frictions, knowledge spil

R&D Dynamics and Corporate Cash - NUS Risk Management Institute
Our estimate, therefore, provides a reference for future quantitative studies concerning R&D. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents additional empirical evidence on the positive R&D-cash correlation. Section 3 lays o

Accounting for the Corporate Cash Increase
have much correlation with the aggregate fluctuations in the business cycle.3 ... interpreted in a causal fashion, then cash flow volatility only accounts for ...... view of Algorithms and Comparison of Software Implementations,” Journal of Global.

RD-C.pdf
Page 1. Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... RD-C.pdf. RD-C.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying RD-C.pdf.

cash balance - Kravitz Cash Balance Design
Small and mid-size businesses are driving Cash Balance growth: 87% of ... Cash Balance Plans: Company Contributions to Employee Retirement Accounts. 7 ..... program that will achieve the plan sponsor's goals while passing all IRS tests ...

2209 Briarcliff Rd
Florida Atlantic University, Boca Raton, FL. August 2011 - May 2014. • Dual Enrolled. • 4.0 GPA. Suncoast Community High School, Riviera Beach, FL. August 2009 - May 2014. • Participant in the 4-year computer science ... Jefferson Wang jwang660

M80 RING RD -
MERLYNSTON CREEK. ANDERSON RD. M. C. B. R. Y. D. E. S. T. M80 RING RD. GREENSBOROUGH. JUKES RD. CAMP RD. MAJOR RD. LYNCH RD. S. A. G.

Cash Transfers and Consumption
Email: [email protected]. ‡The SMERU Research Institute, Jl. Cikini Raya No. 10A ..... regions of Indonesia that are bound up in these FE but are unrelated to ad-.

Administration and Corporate Management
AdministrationDivisionChart_ema357745_v2.13 as of 1 May 2018. Administration and Corporate Management. Division. Divisions. Services / Offices.

Susan and Elaine Cash copy.pdf
merit. She pointed out how educators. often don't demonstrate confidence that. these students can achieve. My spirit. shaken, I contracted with Pivot Learning. Partners, whose model for closing the. achievement gap included coaching for. school and d

LH and RD Juice Bar Card.pdf
We want to know. YOU and your most. creative ideas. ... LH and RD Juice Bar Card.pdf. LH and RD Juice Bar Card.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Details.

Real Estate Purchase and Sale Agreement-92 Repton Rd. .pdf ...
Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Real Estate Purchase and Sale Agreement-92 Repton Rd. .pdf. Real Estate Purchase ...

Corporate Cash Hoarding: The Role of Just-in-Time ...
On average, this switchover accounts for a 4.1 percentage point increase in the cash-to-assets ratio, which is ... The build-up of cash reserves over the past few years by U.S. businesses has captured consid- erable attention from academic ... An inc

Cash-FlowFinal.pdf
Sign in. Loading… Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect ...

Cash burns: An inventory model with a cash-credit choice
Further information is available online at http://www.nber.org/papers/w21110.ack ... Cash is used whenever the agent has enough of it, credit is used when cash ...

Cash Journal.pdf
00002014 07/18/2016 1,703,869.65 APP 005 JH BUILDING JH BUILDING APP 005 1,703,869.65 BRANCO ENTERPRISES INC. 00002103 07/05/2016 969.29. 17676 ONSTOT WAGES 969.29 FREEMAN HEALTH SYSTEM. 00002103 07/05/2016 969.29. 17676 ONSTOT WAGES 969.29 FREEMAN H

cash flow.pdf
cash and noncash investing and financing transaction during a period. Key words: Analysis Cashflow source information and decision maker. PENDAHULUAN.

Task Dynamics and Resource Dynamics in the ...
source-dynamic components that have not been considered traditionally as ... energy for the act (Aleshinsky, 1986; Bingham, 1988; Bobbert,. 1988; Van Ingen .... As an alternative explanation, Kugler and Turvey (1987) suggested that periods ...

Corporate social policy and corporate social work
Effective corporate social policy and social work business are an important prevention of social .... Questionnaires were prepared and evaluated in SPSS (Statistical Package for the Social. Sciences) .... Personnel work in small businesses.

Enthusiast RD 5 Big Willow.pdf
Sign in. Loading… Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect ...

RD MOF 2016.pdf
Sign in. Page. 1. /. 2. Loading… Page 1 of 2. Page 1 of 2. Page 2 of 2. Page 2 of 2. RD MOF 2016.pdf. RD MOF 2016.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In.

EV-RD-M780-3180A.pdf
... appearance, finish, size, etc. © Shimano Inc. A. Absence of mark indicates non-interchangeability. Specifications are subject to change without notice. 7. 9. INTERCHANGEABILITY SHIMANO. CODE NO. DESCRIPTION ITEM. NO. RD-M980. RD-M663. Page 1 of