Optimal Taxation and Monopsonistic Labor Market: Does Monopsony justify the Minimum Wage? Pierre Cahuc1 Ecole polytechnique, CREST-INSEE, IZA, CEPR

Guy Laroque Sciences Po, UCL, IZA

May 5, 2012

1

CREST-INSEE, Timbre J 360, 15, Boulevard Gabriel-Péri, 92245, Malako¤, France. Email: [email protected]. We thank Leif Danziger, Etienne Lehmann, Alan Manning, Emmanuel Saez, the editor and the associated editor of the Journal of Public Economic Theory, and participants in seminars at CREST, at the University of Oslo, in the conference Labor Markets: a transatlantic perspective (Paris, January 2008), and at the IZA conference on The Economics of the Minimum Wage for comments.

Abstract Does monopsony on the labor market in itself justify the implementation of a minimum wage when it would not be used in a competitive economy? This issue is studied in a model of optimal taxation. We …nd that there is no room for the minimum wage when there are a continuum of skills with no isolated mass point at the bottom of the wage distribution. Accordingly, in the empirically relevant situation, where there is a continuum of wages at the bottom of the distribution, the minimum wage is not helpful. Keywords: Minimum wage, Optimal taxation, Monopsony. JEL codes: H2, J3.

1

Introduction

A popular justi…cation of the minimum wage is that it strengthens the hand of the low skilled workers who are exploited by monopsonist employers. As stressed by Dolado et al. (2000), proponents of the minimum wage take the competitive working of the labor market as the exception, rather than the rule, arguing that in many reasonable instances “monopsony” corresponds to the rule. Then, the minimum wage seems to be useful because it increases both employment and the income of low wage workers. This view had a strong in‡uence on economic policy in the last …fteen years. For instance, in 1994, the OECD Jobs Study was arguing that there was a need to “reassess the role of statutory minimum wages as an instrument to achieve redistributive goals, and switch to more direct instruments” (OECD, 1994). Four years later, after the publication of a set of papers and a book arguing that minimum wage increases could bene…t low skilled employment according to the predictions of the monopsony model of the labor market (Card and Krueger, 1995), the perspective was quite di¤erent: the OECD Employment Outlook stressed that “a well-designed policy package of economic measures, with an appropriately set minimum wage in tandem with in-work bene…ts, is likely, on balance, to be bene…cial in moving towards an employment-centered social policy” (OECD, 1998). While recent research …nds a wide range of estimates on the overall e¤ects on low-wage employment of an increase in the minimum wage (Neumark and Wascher, 2008), the monopsony model remains in‡uential. For instance, the OECD argues that “the main impact of downward wage ‡exibility may be to worsen inactivity, unemployment and low-pay traps” (OECD, 2005, p 142). This leads to the idea that a minimum wage combined with in-work bene…ts helps to achieve the intended redistribution to low-wage workers because “by preventing wage levels at the bottom from falling, minimum wages prevent employers from “pocketing” the value of in-work bene…ts by lowering wages”, and moreover “higher wage levels at the bottom mean that the same inwork income can be attained with lower in-work bene…ts payments” (OECD, 2009, p 221). As a matter of fact, today, statutory or quasi-statutory minimum wages are in place in 21 OECD countries (Immervoll, 2007). An interpretation of the debate is that the practical justi…cation of a minimum wage is the existence of a large sector of monopsonist employers, while under perfect competition the scope for a minimum wage would be minimal. The purpose of our study is to address this precise question: does monopsony on the labor market in itself justify the implementation of a minimum wage? Our approach is theoretical and considers a situation where the government can use non linear taxes but no direct tools to promote competition. We consider the standard optimum tax environment of models of optimal taxation with labor

1

supply at the extensive margin. There is a large population of workers who have heterogeneous productivities and opportunity costs of work. The power of the government is limited by his lack of information on the characteristics of the private agents. We analyze the scope for minimum wages when labor markets are monopsonistic. In the absence of government intervention, wages and employment are lower than in the competitive equilibrium. Since the contributions of Robinson (1933) and Stigler (1946), it is known that when there is a single skill, the competitive allocation can be attained with a minimum wage when the labor market is monopsonistic. The competitive allocation can also be attained with wage subsidies1 …nanced by taxes on the pro…ts of the monopsony. In other words, a higher minimum wage means that the same in-work income can be attained with lower in-work bene…ts payments. Thereby, the minimum wage can be appropriate because it allows the government to save on wage subsidies. Our purpose here is to analyze how these results extend to a situation with heterogeneous skills, and whether the minimum wage allows the government to save subsidies. When skills are heterogeneous, the inability of the government to observe individual productivity reduces its power to redistribute income. But we …nd that taxes still seem to work: assuming that the distribution of work opportunity costs is independent of productivities, we show that there always exists a labor subsidy scheme that supports the second best competitive allocation, i.e. that undoes the wrongs of the monopsonist. In this context, we show that the minimum wage may allow the government to reduce the wage subsidies required to support this allocation when there is a …nite number of skills. However we …nd that there is no room of the minimum wage if there is a continuum of skills with no isolated mass point at the bottom of the wage distribution. Accordingly, in the empirically relevant situation, where there is a continuum of wages at the bottom of the distribution, the minimum wage is not helpful. The papers which look at the minimum wage in labor markets with imperfect competition typically ask whether increasing the minimum wage can improve employment or welfare in the absence of other policy tools.2 The e¢ ciency of the minimum wage when there are taxes has mostly been considered in labor markets with perfect competition.3 Most of the literature has adopted the standard Mirrlees (1971) model on optimal taxation with intensive labor supply, where individuals choose the number of hours they work and where the government observes earnings but neither hourly wages nor hours of work. It turns out that the minimum wage can be welfare improving when tax schemes are constrained or when there are speci…c assumptions made 1

Wage (or labor) subsidies are equivalent to in-work bene…ts to the extent that transfers have the same e¤ects whether they are given to the employer or to the employee. 2 See, among others Robinson (1933), Stigler (1946), Drazen (1986), Jones (1987), Manning, (1995, 2003), Rebitzer and Taylor (1995), Bhaskar and To (1999), Masters (1999), Cahuc et al. (2001), Flinn (2006). 3 The paper of Hungerbühler and Lehmann (2009), where the usefulness of the minimum wage is analyzed in a search and matching model, is an exception.

2

to allow the government to observe skills at the bottom of the income distribution (Allen, 1984, Guesnerie and Roberts, 1987, Boadway and Cu¤, 2001). However, as stressed by Guesnerie and Roberts (1987) and more recently by Lee and Saez (2008), informational inconsistencies arise when a minimum wage is introduced in the Mirrlees model because the minimum wage implementation requires observing hourly wages. But if hourly wages were directly observable, then the government could achieve the …rst best by conditioning taxes and transfers on hourly wage and the minimum wage would obviously not be useful. This informational inconsistency leads us to focus on labor supply at the extensive margin where the agents’ decision is zero-one, to work or not to work, as in the studies of Diamond (1980), Beaudry et al. (2009), Saez (2002), Hungerbühler and Lehmann (2009), Choné and Laroque (2005, 2011) and Laroque (2005). Lee and Saez (2008) have studied the consequence of the minimum wage in this type of model assuming perfect competition on the labor market and two skill levels. They derive precise conditions on the shape of the rationing scheme on the labor market under which a minimum wage can be a useful complement to taxes in a competitive environment. They …nd that the minimum wage is useful under the assumption that workers who involuntary lose their job because of the minimum wage are those with the highest opportunity cost of work.4 They also show that the minimum wage cannot improve upon the optimal tax/transfer allocation if workers who lose their jobs because of the minimum wage have the same opportunity cost of work as those who keep their job. A reasonable interpretation of this result is that there is little scope for the minimum wage when the labor market is competitive. From this perspective, it is worth studying the situation where labor markets are imperfectly competitive. The paper is organized as follows. The model with heterogeneous skills and opportunity costs of work is presented in section 2. Section 3 describes the optimal tax schemes when the labor market is monopsonistic. Technically, the contribution of the paper is to adapt the standard principal agent setup where the principal is the government and the agents are the tax payers to a situation where there is a third party, the monopsonist, who sets wages. Compared with laissezfaire, apart from the allocative distortions (wage and employment are lower than under perfect competition), the monopsonist’pro…ts create a speci…c redistributive issue which we analyze in two stages. First, in section 4, we assume that the government has full power to tax the pro…ts 4 They argue that this situation can arise if workers with a low surplus from working at the minimum wage can sell their job to unemployed workers with a high surplus. However, there is little empirical evidence of such a Coasian bargaining. Another important di¤erence with our approach is that Lee and Saez do not analyze the incentive compatibility of the tax scheme for the employers because they assume that the government observes the productivity of workers rather than their wage only, as it is assumed in our framework. Accordingly, in Lee and Saez’s model, employers cannot increase wages above the minimum wage to bene…t from more generous wage subsidies, since the government can force employers to pay the minimum wage to low productive workers.

3

of the monopsonist. We then prove that there is a labor tax schedule that implements the second best allocation of the competitive model. Taxing pro…ts and giving employment subsidies yield the optimal allocation. Since any modi…cation to this allocation is detrimental, the only scope for the minimum wage is to allow the government to save on subsidies: if labor at the bottom of the wage distribution is subsidized, mandating a minimum wage may allow the government to save subsidies. It follows that the minimum wage can be useful when there is a …nite number of skills or when there is a continuum number of skills with an isolated mass point at the bottom of the wage distribution. On the other hand, there is no room for a minimum wage when there is a continuum of skills with no isolated mass point at the bottom of the wage distribution. Second, in section 5, we introduce a simple model of monopsonistic competition with free entry to investigate what happens when the taxation of pro…ts is limited by information constraints. We consider an economy with a large number of identical islands, which only di¤er by i.i.d. entry costs. The government implements corporate subsidies (or taxes) on top of the labor tax schedule. Strikingly, the previous results extend to this setup. Finally, section 6 provides some concluding comments.

2

The model

We consider an economy made of a continuum of agents of measure 1. A typical agent is described by a couple of exogenous characteristics, denoted by

= (!; ). The …rst component

! denotes her productivity when working full time in market activities, producing an undi¤erentiated desirable commodity. The second component, , is a …xed cost of participating in the labor market, also measured in commodity units. In the economy there are pro…t maximizing …rms that allow the transformation of the agents’labor into the commodity, and a benevolent government with a redistributive social aim, who can raise taxes or distribute subsidies and set a minimum wage. The general structure of the economy and the distribution of agents’ characteristics are common knowledge. The labor market works as follows. The government cannot observe the individual characteristics: it only sees whether an agent works or not, and in the former case, the wage paid by her employer. An employer observes the productivities y’s of his employees, but not their opportunity costs of work. When she works, the type-(!; ) agent produces a quantity y, at most equal to ! (the opportunity cost of work (!

is …xed : it does not depend on the di¤erence

y)). When working and producing y, an employee gets a net wage W (y), possibly subject

to a minimum wage constraint W (y)

W . The tax schedule, denoted by T (W ) (if negative,

the absolute value of T is a subsidy to work), yields a labor cost C(W ) = W + T (W ).

4

Production may generate pro…ts. For the sake of simplicity, after tax pro…ts, if any, are supposed to be dissipated by the owners of the …rms with no contribution to social welfare. Under full information, we consider both the normal case where pro…ts are taxed away in a lump sum fashion and the situation where they are not taxed at all. In section 5 we introduce an information based model of pro…t taxation. The tax receipts are used to give a subsistence income r to the unemployed agents. We assume that ! and distributions of

are independently distributed in the population. The cumulative

and ! are denoted F ( ) and G(!) respectively. F has support [ ; ] and a

continuous derivative denoted f , strictly positive everywhere on the support. The productivity distribution G, which may have mass points, has its support included in the interval [!; !]. We suppose 0

<

1 and 0

!
1:

Part of the analysis carries through with an unrestricted distribution for the couple ( ; !), involving mass points and correlation between the two characteristics: we shall point out speci…cally when the independence assumption is needed. The agents have a simple choice criterion, linear in income. They decide to produce an output y rather than stay on the dole whenever their …nancial incentive to work, W (y) larger than their work opportunity cost . Their choice follows u(W; r; ; !) = max [r; W (y)

]:

0 y !

r; is

from:5 (1)

If y(!) denotes the production of the agents of productivity ! who work, the proportion of agents of productivity ! that are employed is F [W (y(!))

r].

The preferences of the government are represented by a social welfare function Z Z (u(W; r; ; !)) dF ( ) dG(!); where

is a non decreasing concave function.

To be feasible, the quadruple (W; T; r; y) must satisfy the budget constraint of the government. When the pro…ts of the …rms are not taxed, the budget constraint takes the form Z ! Z ! T fW (y(!))g F [W (y(!)) r] dG(!) = r f[1 F [W (y(!)) r]g dG(!): !

(2)

!

The left hand side represents the collected taxes, while the right hand side measures the unemployment bene…ts. When the …rms pro…ts are taxed away, the government collects taxes T and 5

In case of indi¤erence between several maxima, we suppose that the worker chooses the largest production.

5

pro…ts y T W on each job, so that the budget constraint becomes: Z ! Z ! fy(!) W (y(!))g F [W (y(!)) r] dG(!) = r f[1 F [W (y(!)) !

r]g dG(!):

(3)

!

The sequence of decisions is such that the government …rst announces its policy, the tax function and the subsistence income at the beginning of the period, while anticipating the budget constraint. Then the …rms choose the net wage function which relates productivity to net wage. Finally the workers decide on their labor supply.

3

Second best tax schemes with monopsonistic labor markets

We de…ne second best allocations. Formally, a second best optimum is a quadruple (W; T; r; y), such that 1. the workers choose whether to work or not, and the amount they produce y(!), taking as given (W; r), according to max [r; W (y)

0 y !

];

(4)

2. the monopsonist chooses the net wage, taking as given (T; r), and anticipating the reactions of the workers to its choice, by maximizing Z ! max [y(!) W (y(!)) T (W (y(!)))] F [W (y(!))

r]dG(!);

(5)

!

3. the government chooses (T; r), anticipating the behavior of the monopsonist and of the workers, maximizing the social welfare function: Z (Z !

W (y(!)) r

(W (y(!))

!

)dF ( ) + f1

F [W (y(!))

subject to the feasibility constraint Z ! fy(!) W (y(!)) + rg F (W (y(!))

)

r]g (r)

r) dG(!) = r;

dG(!);

(6)

(7)

!

when pro…ts are taxed, or Z ! fT (W (y(!))) + rg F (W (y(!))

r) dG(!) = r;

(8)

!

when they are not. We assume that the government chooses a continuous and bounded below tax function T:

6

In order to simplify the resolution of this problem, it is useful to remark that one can restrict the analysis to net wages that increase with productivity.6 This implies that at a second best optimum, without loss of generality: 1. the monopsonist can choose a net wage function W that is non decreasing with respect to productivity; 2. the government can choose a tax schedule T such that the function x ! x + T (x) is everywhere non decreasing;

3. all the employees work at their full productivity !: These properties imply that any second best allocation can be reached with non decreasing net wage and cost schedules. At a second best optimum individuals work at their full time productivity and the net wage is a non decreasing function of productivity in the competitive environment. These properties also hold when the labor market is dominated by a monopsonist.

4

Monopsony with full taxation of pro…ts

We consider a monopsony whose pro…ts can be fully taxed by the governement. We prove that the government can bypass the monopsonist and implement the second best allocation of the competitive economy by using employment subsidies. Then we analyze the role of the minimum wage.

4.1

The optimal tax schedule

In order to understand the role of the monopsony, it is useful to …rst describe how taxes are optimally set in a competitive environment. The gouvernment observes the production ! of the workers and sets a net wage function W (!): Constant returns to scale ensure zero pro…ts. Thus, when monopsonistic pro…ts can be fully taxed, the only di¤erence between the competitive and monopsony problems comes from the (possible) restrictions imposed by the behavior of the monopsonist (5). As a consequence, the second best optima of the monopsonistic economy cannot Pareto dominate those of the competitive economy. They can at best coincide with them if the government manages to undo the wrongs caused by the monopsonist. We are going to show that this is indeed the case. 6

This point is proved in our working paper, Cahuc and Laroque (2007).

7

The Lagrangian of the program of the government in a competitive economy is Z (Z W (!) r

!

(W (!)

L =

)) dF ( ) +

(r)f1

F [W (!)

r]g

!

+ f[!

W (!) + r]F [W (!)

r]

)

rg dG(!);

(9)

to be maximized over (W (:); ; r), for non decreasing W ’s. Let [! inf ; !] be the endogenous set of productivities for which there are a positive number of employees at the optimum. The Lagrangian can be rewritten equivalently as L

(r)

= r+ Z ! ( !

+

(10)

W (!) + r +

! inf

Z

)

W (!) r

(W (!) ) (r) dF ( ) F [W (!) F [W (!) r]

r] dG(!):

Now, the objectives of the government (10) and of the monopsonist (5) are aligned provided that to any value W; W > r + ; of the net wage corresponds a value C(W ) = W + T (W ) of the labor cost such that C(W ) = W

r

Z

W r

(W

) F [W

(r) r]

Note that C can take any value when wages are smaller than r +

dF ( ):

(11)

since nobody works for such

wages. Therefore Theorem 1 The second best optimal allocations in a monopsonistic economy where the pro…ts can be fully taxed are identical to that of a competitive economy. An optimum in the monopsonistic economy can be implemented through a continuous tax wedge T (W ) which satis…es T (W ) = where rc and

c

rc

1 c

Z

W rc

(W F [W

) dF ( ) rc ]

(rc )

for W

rc + ;

are respectively the optimal subsistence income and marginal cost of public funds

of the competitive economy. Theorem 1 states that all allocations that can be reached in a competitive economy can also be reached, with di¤erent tax schedules, when the labor market is monopsonistic. It is a striking result which means that the government can systematically undo the wrongs caused by the monopsonist at no cost. It is easily checked that the tax function T is continuous and

8

negative on its domain W

rc + . Employment subsidies are e¢ cient because they counteract

the natural inclination of the monopsonist to reduce its demand for labor.7 It should be stressed that Theorem 1 relies on the independence of the distributions of productivities and work opportunity costs. Indeed, in case of dependence, the argument does not go through: the number of workers, that is equal to F (W (!) a function F (W (!)

r) in equation (10), becomes

rj!) that depends on !: Then, the expression of the cost that aligns the

objective of the government and the monopsonist, de…ned in equation (11), has no economic meaning since it depends on the unobserved !. It would be of interest to know whether Theorem 1 extends to situations where productivity is correlated with work opportunity cost. We do not have a general answer to this question. However, there is an extreme polar case which is easily dealt with: this is the situation where the work opportunity cost is a continuous increasing function of productivity, say a(!). It can be shown that the …rst best optimum consists in putting to work all individuals of productivity ! greater than or equal to a(!), while distributing income equally to everyone at a level Z r= [! a(!)]dG(!): ! a(!)

The government can implement this optimum in a monopsonistic economy, when the monopsony pro…ts are taxed away. Let C(W ) = W

r (compare with (11)). Then the monopsonist pays the

workers at the lowest acceptable net wage, W (!) = a(!) + r, and employs all individuals who bring a non negative pro…t, i.e. such that ! as in the …rst best

4.2

C(W (!)) = !

a(!)

0, the same individuals

optimum.8

The minimum wage

One can sustain the second best optimum of the competitive economy with the above system of taxes and subsidies. Any modi…cation to this allocation would be detrimental. Therefore, the only scope for the minimum wage is to allow the government to save on subsidies: if labor at the bottom of the wage distribution is subsidized, mandating a minimum wage may allow to save subsidies. This only makes sense if there is a non negligible mass of workers at the bottom of the second best wage distribution, W (! inf ). This happens when W (! inf ) > rc + 7

(see Choné and

Note that the function C(W ); de…ned in (11), can have decreasing parts. The construction of Lemma 1 allows us to de…ne an equivalent non decreasing cost function C(W ) = minx W C(x). It is easy to see that the associated tax schedule, T; is also negative, as the original function T , for all W > rc + : 8 In the case where labor supply is in…nitely elastic one might think that minimum wages are justi…ed because monopsonistic employers take subsidies in their pocket instead of giving wage increases. Actually, in that case, the monopsonist always sets the net wage at the reservation level a(!) + r, whatever the labor tax or subsidy. Employment subsidies serve to implement the optimal level of employment, and the minimum wage is not needed. Indeed the objectives of the monopsonist and of the government are aligned when the elasticity of labor supply is in…nite as far as the determination of the net wage is concerned.

9

Laroque, 2011, for example). Let us denote by W = W (! inf ) the minimum wage and by Tinf the (negative) tax at the minimum wage. To save on the subsidies, we need Tinf to be bigger than T (W ): To sustain the second best optimum, the monopsonist must prefer paying the minimum wage W to the low skilled ! inf workers, rather than a higher wage which might bring larger subsidies. This condition can be written formally as ! inf for all !, !

W

Tinf F (W

rc )

! inf

W

T (W ) F (W

rc ); W = W (!);

(12)

! inf , such there are workers of productivity !.

Let us suppose that the support of the distribution of second best wages contains a non negligible interval [W (! inf ); W + ]. Then, by continuity, taking the limit on the right for a wage W going to W ; using the fact that F (W

rc ) is positive since it is assumed that there is a non

negligible mass of workers at the minimum wage, we get Tinf

lim T (W ) =

T (W ):

(13)

W !W

Since we need Tinf to be bigger than T (W ); there is no scope for the minimum wage. Let us summarize this argument: Theorem 2 Assume that the support of the distribution of second best wages contains a non negligible interval [W (! inf ); W + ]: A minimum wage does not allow the government to save on the subsidies that support the second best optimum. The assumption made in Theorem 2 is not always ful…lled: the support of the distribution of wages may have an empty intersection with an open interval, say (W (! inf ); W + ); so that nobody is paid wages that belong to the interval (W (! inf ); W + ). Indeed, this is always the case when there is a …nite number of skills, and this may also happen when the distribution of productivities has full support. While the limit of T (W ) in (13) is still well de…ned, it is not relevant any more: From (12), the only values of T (W ) that are of interest are those of the second best optimum. So, there may exist a value of Tinf > T (W ) which satis…es condition (12). In that case, the government can use the minimum wage to save on wage subsidies. Theorem 2 shows that while the minimum wage can be useful when the number of skills is …nite, this is not the case in the empirically relevant situation where the support of the distribution of wages contains a non negligible interval at its lower end.

5

Entry and limits on corporate taxes

We have so far assumed that pro…ts are entirely taxed away, as is consistent with the fact that the government knows the pro…t level. A justi…cation of the minimum wage could be that the 10

government cannot fully tax pro…ts. We now look at this issue in a very stylized and simple framework. To put limits to the power of the government to tax …rms while keeping with the spirit of optimal taxation models à la Mirrlees, we introduce additional information asymmetries which allow the …rms to keep some rents. A simple and illustrative way to proceed is to consider a situation where the government regulates a continuum of separate local labor markets. In all these labor markets, there is the same distribution of workers as the one of the previous section: these markets work independently and there is no labor mobility across markets. Firms have to pay an entry cost9 h; which is drawn independently across labor markets with the c.d.f. H. The government, which observes net wages as before but not the entry costs of the …rms, announces the same tax schedule (T; r) over the whole territory, with additionally a lump sum subsidy s ( s is the level of the tax when s is negative) given to the …rms to help them pay their costs. Given our informational assumption, the subsidy can only be constant, identical across labor markets. The economy works as follows: …rst the government announces the full tax and subsidy schedule common to all markets; second the random entry costs and productivity are drawn; the …rms decide to operate when the sum of their expected pro…ts and subsidy exceeds the entry cost; …nally production is undertaken and wages are paid in the markets which operate; in the other markets, nobody works and everyone gets the subsistence income r. When labor markets are competitive operating pro…ts are equal to zero under constant returns to scale and …rms decide to operate when s

h is non negative. The government

program then is max H(s)

[T ( );r;s]

Z

!

!

(Z

)

W (!) r

(W (!)

) dF ( ) + f1

F [W (!))

r]g (r)

+ [1 subject to the feasibility constraint Z ! f! W (!) + rg F (W (!) H(s)

dG(!) H(s)] (r);

r) dG(!) = r + sH(s):

!

Let

be the multiplier of the feasibility constraint, and for further reference denote (T c ; rc ; sc ;

c

)

a solution of the above program for the competitive economy. When the labor markets are monopsonistic, the …rms’operating pro…ts allow them to …nance some of the entry costs and the subsidy may be negative. The before tax operating pro…t

of

the typical …rm is =

Z

!

!

9

f!

W (!)

T (W (!))g F (W (!)

r) dG(!);

A positive value of h corresponds to an entry cost; a negative value can be interpreted as a rent of size jhj.

11

under (T; r). The …rm decides to operate when

+s

h is non negative, i.e. with probability

H( + s). The program of the government becomes max H( + s)

[T ( );r;s]

Z

!

!

(Z

)

W (!) r

(W (!)

) dF ( ) + f1

F [W (!))

r]g (r)

+ [1 subject to the feasibility constraint Z ! f! W (!) + rg F (W (!) H( + s)

dG(!)

H( + s)] (r);

r) dG(!) = r + ( + s)H( + s);

!

while the monopsonist sets a wage schedule according to Z ! f! S(!) T (S(!))g F (S(!) W ( ) = arg max S( )

Although the pro…t

r) dG(!):

!

; which depends on T; shows up in the objective and the feasibility

constraint of the government, this does not create di¢ culties since it only appears through the after tax pro…t

+ s: Indeed put

+ s = sc in the program of the government: ignoring the

behavior of the monopsony the solution of the program is then a competitive optimum (the government manages to tax away all monopsony pro…ts!). This allows us to transpose here the argument of Theorem 1. The objective of the government and of the monopsonist are aligned and yield the competitive net wage W c if one de…nes T m (W ) =

rc

Z

W (!) rc

(W c

) F [W

(rc ) dF ( ): rc ]

The pro…t of the monopsonistic …rm follows, and the value of sm is computed from sm = sc

m.

This implies that the government can reach the same allocation as in the competitive economy. It is worth noting that the function T m has the same analytical expression as in Theorem 1, although the values of the marginal costs of public funds and of the subsistence income are di¤erent. This implies that Theorem 2 applies even when pro…ts cannot be fully taxed. The incentive compatibility constraints take the form of (12) and (13), since the cost of entry appears on both sides of the inequalities. With the instruments adapted to its information structure, the government has all the necessary …scal tools to reach the second best optimum of the competitive economy and the minimum wage is of no help whenever the support of the distribution of wages contains a non negligible interval at its lower end.

12

6

Conclusion

In this paper we compare income redistribution in two economies which only di¤er by the functioning of their labor markets, competitive or monopsonistic. The government has a large range of instruments at its disposal, which includes wages and pro…ts taxes and the minimum wage. we show that there always exists a labor subsidy scheme that sustains the second best allocation of a competitive economy, i.e. that undoes the wrongs of the monopsonist. This result holds when abilities are distributed independently of work opportunity costs. It is also satis…ed when work opportunity cost is a deterministic increasing function of ability. We do not know how to handle the intermediate cases. When the heterogeneity of skills is accounted for, the minimum wage appears to be of no use to correct the transfers or ine¢ ciencies associated with the monopsony in economically relevant circumstances. The conclusion that monopsony does not justify the minimum wage does not mean that the minimum wage is useless as a part of e¢ cient redistributive schemes in all circumstances (indeed see Lee and Saez (2008) for a counter example). What we claim here is that in the absence of restrictions on the set of available tax instruments, a monopsony on the labor market can be dealt with without using a minimum wage in empirically relevant situations. Whether the minimum wage somehow can be useful in other circumstances is an open question. In particular, the minimum wage might be desirable if its administrative implementation costs are lower than the costs of collecting taxes and subsidies. More research is needed in this area.

References [1] Allen, S. (1987), “Taxes, Redistribution, and the Minimum Wage: A Theoretical Analysis”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 477-489 [2] Bhaskar, V. and To, T. (1999), “Minimum Wages for Ronald McDonald Monopsonies: A Theory of Monopsonistic Competition", Economic Journal, 109, 190-203. [3] Beaudry, P., Blackorby, C. and Szalay, (2009), “Taxes and Employment Subsidies in Optimal Redistribution Programs,” American Economic Review, vol 99, pp. 216-242. [4] Boadway, R. and Cu¤, K. (2001) “A Minimum Wage can be Welfare Improving and Employment-Enhancing”, European Economic Review, 45, 553-576. [5] Cahuc, P. and Laroque, G. (2007), “Optimal Taxation and Monopsonistic Labor Market: Does Monopsony Justify the Minimum Wage?”, IZA discussion paper n 2955: 13

[6] Cahuc, P., Zylberberg, A. and Saint-Martin, A. (2001), “The consequences of the minimum wage when other wages are bargained over”, European Economic Review, 45, 337-352. [7] Card, D. and Krueger, A. (1995), Myth and Measurement: The new economics of minimum wage, Princeton University Press. [8] Choné, P. and Laroque, G. (2005), “Optimal Incentives for Labor Force Participation”, Journal of Public Economics, 89, 395-425. [9] Choné, P. and Laroque, G. (2011), “Optimal Taxation in the Extensive Model”, Journal of Economic Theory, 146, 425-453. [10] Diamond, P. (1980), “Income Taxation with Fixed Hours of Work”, Journal of Public Economics, 13, 101-110. [11] Dolado, J., Felgueroso, F. and Jimeno, J. (2000), “The Role of the Minimum Wage in the Welfare State: An Appraisal”, IZA Discussion paper 152, published in Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, 136 (2000), 1-33. [12] Drazen, A. (1986), “Optimal Minimum Wage Legislation”, Economic Journal, 96, 774-784. [13] Flinn, C. (2006) “Minimum Wage E¤ects on Labor Market Outcomes under Search, Bargaining, and Endogenous Contact Rates”, Econometrica 74, 1013-1062. [14] Guesnerie, R., Roberts, R. (1987), “Minimum Wage Legislation as a Second-Best Policy”, European Economic Review, 31, 490-498. [15] Hungerbühler, M. and Lehmann, E. (2009), “On the optimality of a minimum wage: New insights from optimal tax theory”,Journal of Public Economics, vol 93, pp. 464–481. [16] Immervoll, H. (2007), “Minimum Wages, Minimum Labour Costs and the Tax Treatment of Low-wage Employment”, OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers n 46. [17] Jones, S. (1987), “Minimum Wage Legislation in a Dual Labor Market”, European Economic Review, 33, 1229-1246. [18] Laroque, G. (2005), “Income Maintenance and Labor Force Participation”, Econometrica, 73, 341-376. [19] Lee, D and Saez, E. (2008) “Optimal Minimum Wage Policy in Competitive Labor Markets”, NBER working paper n 14320.

14

[20] Manning, A. (1995), “How do We Know that Real Wages are Too High ?”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 1111-1125. [21] Manning, A. (2003), Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets, Princeton University Press. [22] Masters, A. (1999), “Wage posting in two-sided search and the minimum wage”, International Economic Review, 40, 809-826. [23] Mirrlees, J. (1971), “An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation,”Review of Economic Studies, 38, 175-208. [24] Neumark, D. and Wascher, W. (2008), Minimum Wages, MIT Press. [25] OECD, (1994), The OECD jobs study. Facts, Analysis, Strategies, Paris: OECD. [26] OECD, (1998), Employment Outlook, Paris: OECD. [27] OECD, (2005), Employment Outlook, Paris: OECD. [28] OECD, (2009), Employment Outlook, Paris: OECD. [29] Rebitzer, J. and Taylor, L. (1995), “The Consequences of Minimum Wage Laws, Some New Theoretical Ideas”, Journal of Public Economics, 56, 245-255. [30] Robinson, J., (1933), The Economics of Imperfect Competition, MacMillan, London. [31] Saez, E. (2002), “Optimal Income Transfer Programs: Intensive versus Extensive Labor Supply Responses,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1039-1073. [32] Stigler, G. (1946), “The Economics of Minimum Wage Legislation”, American Economic Review, 36, 535-543.

15

Optimal Taxation and Monopsonistic Labor Market

May 5, 2012 - 1CREST%INSEE, Timbre J 360, 15, Boulevard Gabriel%Péri, 92245, ... This view had a strong influence on economic policy in the last.

150KB Sizes 2 Downloads 277 Views

Recommend Documents

Optimal Taxation and Monopsonistic Labor Market
May 5, 2012 - employment according to the predictions of the monopsony model of the labor market (Card and. Krueger ...... wage, Princeton University Press.

Optimal Taxation and Monopsonistic Labor Market: Does ... - IZA
May 22, 2009 - To deal with this issue we choose a view point a priori favorable to the minimum wage: .... that there is no room for minimum wage. Second, in ...

Optimal Taxation and Monopsonistic Labor Market: Does ... - IZA
May 22, 2009 - 1CREST&INSEE, Timbre J 360, 15, Boulevard Gabriel&Péri, 92245, Malakoff, ... This view had a strong influence on economic policy in the last.

Optimal Taxation and (Female)-Labor Force ...
May 13, 2008 - Here (r − δ)(1 − τc) is the after-depreciation, after tax capital income, D are ..... We let the direct transfers Trt pick up the residual in the balanced ...

Optimal Taxation and (Female)-Labor Force ...
May 13, 2008 - seo,˜g. ̺(1 − qt,˜g. )(1 − ft,˜g. )qt,eo,˜g. −E∗εt,ee,˜g. − (1 − qt,˜g. )( ...... Table (4) gives the basic moments of the model and Figure(9) to Figure(4) ...

Optimal Redistributive Policy in a Labor Market with Search and ...
∗Email addresses: [email protected] and [email protected]. ... Our baseline optimization in the benchmark case suggests that applying the.

Optimal Labor Market Policy with Search Frictions and ...
reallocation of workers from low to high productivity jobs, hiring subsidies are .... ance in a search model where the accumulation of risk&free savings is the only .... of the results provided that the interest rate at which the planner can transfer

Optimal Redistributive Policy in a Labor Market with Search and ...
Heterogeneous, risk-averse agents look for a job in a labor market characterized by an aggregate ... ∗Email addresses: [email protected] and [email protected]. ...... E. Stiglitz, McGraw-Hill Book Co., London, New York.

Optimal Labor-Market Policy in Recessions
Nov 30, 2011 - as hiring subsidies, for example, are discussed intensively in the current ..... and identically distributed both across workers and across time and ...

Bargaining Frictions, Labor Income Taxation, and ... - CiteSeerX
Jan 12, 2010 - nological change and government intervention is the best candidate to account for the long term changes in hours ..... high levels of rigidity, in which employment is small, and very good prospects are unmatched, an increase in .... un

Optimal Taxation and Junk Food
Urbana, IL 61801, USA. Harry Tsang ... Grand Forks, ND 58202, USA. October ..... is available for expenditures on apples, bananas, oranges and other fresh.

Optimal Taxation and Social Networks
Nov 1, 2011 - We study optimal taxation when jobs are found through a social network. This network determines employment, which workers may influence ...

Labor-dependent Capital Income Taxation
Aug 13, 2010 - system that treats labor and capital income separately as a tax base. The reform ... In the proposed tax system, the reward for an additional work effort is not .... Preferences: Households rank a bundle of consumption and leisure acco

Labor-dependent Capital Income Taxation
Aug 13, 2010 - Abstract. Capital taxation which is negatively correlated with labor supply is proposed. This paper uses a life-cycle model of heterogeneous ...

The Impact of Migration in a Monopsonistic Labor Market
some extent compensated by the entry of new firms to the market, enticed by lower wages. The overall .... this disadvantage should dissipate with time, as migrants assimilate into the labor market (see e.g. Chiswick, ...... is the efficiency-weighted

Hiring Policies, Labor Market Institutions, and Labor ...
workers across existing jobs to obtain better matches between workers ... Arizona State, Maryland, Wharton, Toronto, California at San Diego, Texas, and. Rice for comments. Rogerson acknowledges support from the National Science. Foundation. ... ploy

Trade and Labor Market Dynamics - CiteSeerX
Aug 25, 2015 - Taking a dynamic trade model with all these features to the data, and ...... Appliance (c14); Transportation Equipment (c15); Furniture and ...

Heterogeneous Information and Labor Market ...
†Email: [email protected]. 1 .... 4In the benchmark calibration, firm-specific shocks are also slightly more persistent than aggregate shocks. Since hiring decisions ...

Labor and Market Economy.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Labor and ...

Labor market and search through personal contacts
May 3, 2012 - Keywords: Labor market; unemployment; job search; social network. ..... link between workers in time period t is formed with probability. 10 ...

Heterogeneous Information and Labor Market ...
eliminate this discrepancy between the data and model-predicted movements. ..... Substituting in (5), integrating over all i and ignoring the constant terms ...... In practice, the ability of an individual firm to forecast conditions in the labor mar

Growth and Labor Market Composition
Sep 11, 2017 - workers earn a positive return for staying at the same firm for additional .... from the Labor Force Survey, whose survey design is similar to that of the .... They conclude that in Japan starting a career as a temporary worker has a.

Fraternities and Labor Market Outcomes
Jan 7, 2011 - Estimation. Conclusion. Fraternities. We study the situation where productivity irrelevant activity is job market relevant. Fraternity membership is more than "club good": too expensive; many people mention them on resumes. Sergey V. Po