Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Optimal investment under multiple defaults: a BSDE-decomposition approach Huyˆen PHAM∗ ∗ LPMA-University Paris Diderot, CREST and Institut Universitaire de France

Joint work with: Ying Jiao (LPMA-University Paris Diderot), Idris Kharroubi (University Paris Dauphine)

SAFI Conference Ann Arbor, May 18, 2011 Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

The financial problem

• Investment problem in an assets portfolio subject to defaults and contagion risk I

Multi defaults times ↔ multi credit names: in particular, some assets may not be tradable anymore after default.

I

Contagion effects: loss in one asset → losses on the other assets

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Modelling of multiple defaults events Assets model Examples

Multiple defaults times and marks On a probability space (Ω, G, P): • Reference filtration F = (Ft )t≥0 : default-free information Progressive information provided, when they occur, by: • a family of n random times τ = (τ1 , . . . , τn ) associated to a family of n random marks ζ = (ζ1 , . . . , ζn ). I

τi default time of name i ∈ In = {1, . . . , n}.

I

The mark ζi , valued in E Borel set of Rp , represents a jump size at τi , which cannot be predicted from the reference filtration, e.g. the loss given default.

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Modelling of multiple defaults events Assets model Examples

Progressive enlargement of filtrations The global market information is defined by: G = F ∨ D1 ∨ . . . ∨ Dn , where Di is the default filtration generated by the observation of τi and ζi when they occur, i.e. Di = (Dti )t≥0 ,

Dti = σ{1τi ≤s , s ≤ t} ∨ σ{ζi 1τi ≤s , s ≤ t}.

→ G = F ∨ Fµ , where Fµ is the filtration generated by the jump random measure µ(dt, de) associated to (τi , ζi ).

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Modelling of multiple defaults events Assets model Examples

Successive defaults For simplicity of presentation, we assume that τ1 ≤ . . . ≤ τn Remark. The general multiple random times case for (τ1 , . . . , τn ) can be derived from the ordered case by considering the filtration generated by the corresponding ranked times (ˆ τ1 , . . . , τˆn ) and the index marks ιi , i = 1, . . . , n so that (ˆ τ1 , . . . , τˆn ) = (τι1 , . . . , τιn ). Notation: For k = 0, . . . , n, τ k = (τ1 , . . . , τk )

valued in

∆k = {(θ1 , . . . , θk ) : 0 ≤ θ1 ≤ . . . ≤ θk },

ζ k = (ζ1 , . . . , ζk )

valued in

Ek,

with the convention τ 0 = ∅, ζ 0 = ∅. Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Modelling of multiple defaults events Assets model Examples

Decomposition of G-adapted and predictable processes Lemma Any G-adapted process Y is represented as: Yt

=

n X

1{τk ≤t<τk+1 } Ytk (τ k , ζ k ),

(1)

k=0

where Ytk is Ft ⊗ B(∆k ) ⊗ B(E k )-measurable.

Remarks. • A similar decomposition result holds for G-predictable processes: < ↔ ≤, and Y k is P(F) ⊗ B(∆k ) ⊗ B(E k )-measurable in (1). • Extension of Jeulin-Yor result (case of single random time without mark). • We identify Y with the n + 1-tuple (Y 0 , . . . , Y n ). Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Modelling of multiple defaults events Assets model Examples

• Portfolio of N assets with G-adapted value process S: St

=

n X

1{τk ≤t<τk+1 } Stk (τ k , ζ k ),

k=0

where S k (θ k , ek ), θk = (θ1 , . . . , θk ) ∈ ∆k , ek = (e1 , . . . , ek ) ∈ E k , indexed F-adapted process valued in RN + , represents the assets value given the past default events τ k = θ k and marks at default ζ k = ek .

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Modelling of multiple defaults events Assets model Examples

Change of regimes with jumps at defaults • Dynamics of S = S k between τk = θk and τk+1 = θk+1 : dStk (θ k , ek ) = Stk (θ k , ek ) ∗ (btk (θ k , ek )dt + σtk (θ k , ek )dWt ), where W is a m-dimensional (P, F)-Brownian motion, m ≥ N. • Jumps at τk+1 = θk+1 :  k k Sθk+1 (θ , e ) = S (θ , e , e ) , − (θ k , ek ) ∗ 1N + γθ k+1 k+1 k k k+1 k+1 θ k+1 k+1

γ k vector-valued in [−1, ∞)N .

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Modelling of multiple defaults events Assets model Examples

Exogenous counterparty default • One default time τ (n = 1) inducing jumps in the price process S of N-assets portfolio: St

= St0 1t<τ + St1 (τ, ζ)1t≥τ ,

where S 0 is the price process before default, governed by dSt0 = St0 ∗ (bt0 dt + σt0 dWt ) and S 1 (θ, e), (θ, e) ∈ R+ × E , is the indexed price process after default at time θ and with mark e: dSt1 (θ, e) = St1 (θ, e) ∗ (bt1 (θ, e)dt + σt1 (θ, e)dWt ), Sθ1 (θ, e)

=

Sθ0

∗ (1N + γθ (e)). Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

t ≥ θ,

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Modelling of multiple defaults events Assets model Examples

Multilateral counterparty risk

• Assets family (e.g. portfolio of defaultable bonds) in which each underlying name is subject to its own default but also to the defaults of the other names (contagion effect). I number of defaults n = N number of assets S = (P 1 , . . . , P n ) I

τi default time of name P i , and ζi its (random) recovery rate (P i is not traded anymore after τi )

I

τi induces jump on P j , j 6= i.

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Admissible control strategies • A trading strategy in the N-assets portfolio is a G-predictable process π = (π 0 , . . . , π n ): π k (θ k , ek )

is valued in

Ak closed convex set of RN ,

denoted π k ∈ PF (∆k , E k ; Ak ), and representing the amount invested given the past default events (τ k , ζ k ) = (θ k , ek ), k = 0, . . . , n, and until the next default time. I The set of admissible controls: AG = A0F × . . . × AnF , where AkF includes some integrability conditions

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Wealth process • Given an admissible trading strategy π = (π k )k=0,...,n , the controlled wealth process is given by: Xt

=

n X

1{τk ≤t<τk+1 } Xtk (τ k , ζ k ), t ≥ 0,

k=0

Xk

where is the wealth process with an investment π k in the assets of price S k given the past defaults events (τ k , ζ k ). I Dynamics between τk = θk and τk+1 = θk+1 :  dXtk (θ k , ek ) = πtk (θ k , ek )0 btk (θ k , ek )dt + σtk (θ k , ek )dWt . I Jumps at default time τk+1 = θk+1 : Xθk+1 (θ k+1 , ek+1 ) = Xθk− (θ k , ek ) + πθkk+1 (θ k , ek )0 γθkk+1 (θ k , ek , ek+1 ). k+1 k+1

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Value function • Value function of the optimal investment problem: h i V0 (x) = sup E U(XTx,π ) , x ∈ R. π∈AG

where U is an utility function. Remark. One can also deal with running gain function, involving e.g. utility from consumption, and utility-based pricing with credit derivative.

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Usual global approach

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

(when all Ak are identical)

• Write the dynamics of assets and wealth process in the global filtration G → Jump-Itˆo controlled process under G in terms of W and µ (random measure associated to (τk , ζk )k ). • Use a martingale representation theorem for (W , µ) w.r.t. G under intensity hypothesis on the default times I Derive the dynamic programming Bellman equation in the G filtration → BSDE with jumps or Integro-Partial-differential equations: Ankirchner et al. (09), Lim and Quenez (10), Jeanblanc et al (10).

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Our solutions approach • Find a suitable decomposition of the G-control problem on each default scenario → sub-control problems in the F-filtration I

by relying on the F-decomposition of G-processes,

I

density hypothesis on the defaults

I Backward system of BSDEs in Brownian filtration I

Get rid of the jump terms and overcome the technical difficulties in BSDEs with jumps

I

Existence, uniqueness and characterization results in a general formulation under weaker conditions

I Explicit description of the optimal strategies and impact of the defaults Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Density hypothesis on defaults

• There exists αT (θ, e), FT ⊗ B(∆n ) ⊗ B(E n )-measurable, s.t.   (DH) P (τ , ζ) ∈ dθde FT = αT (θ, e)dθη(de) where dθ = dθ1Q . . . dθn is the Lebesgue measure on Rn , and η(de) =η1 (de1 ) n−1 k=1 ηk+1 (ek , dek+1 ).

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Comments on density hypothesis • Standard hypothesis in the theory of initial enlargement of filtrations, see Jacod (85). Insider problems in finance • Density approach introduced in progressive enlargement of filtrations for credit risk modelling by El Karoui, Jeanblanc, Jiao (09,10) successive defaults without marks: I

More general setting than intensity approach: one can express the intensity of each default time in terms of the density. Semimartingale invariance property (H’) holds and Immersion hypothesis (H) (martingale invariance property) is not required.

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Auxiliary survival density k , F ⊗ B(∆ ) ⊗ B(E k )-measurable, • Let us define αT T k n = α , k = 0, . . . , n − 1, by recursive induction from αT T Z ∞Z k+1 k αT (θ k , ek ) = αT (θ k , θ, ek , e)dθηk+1 (ek , de), T

E

so that   P τk+1 > T |FT =

Z ∆k ×E k

k αT (θ k , ek )dθ k η(dek ),

where dθ k = dθ1 . . . dθk , η(dek ) = η1 (de1 ) . . . ηk (ek−1 , dek ).

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Decomposition result

The value function V0 is obtained by backward induction from the optimization problems in the F-filtration: h i Vn (x, θ, e) = ess sup E U XTn,x )αT (θ, e) Fθn π n ∈AnF

h  k Vk (x, θ k , ek ) = ess sup E U XTk,x αT (θ k , ek ) π k ∈AkF

Z

T

+ θk

Z

Vk+1 Xθk,x + πθkk+1 .γθkk+1 (ek+1 ), θ k+1 , ek+1 k+1 E i ηk+1 (ek , dek+1 )dθk+1 Fθk .

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs



Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Trading strategies and wealth process Control problem F-decomposition

Comments

• This F-decomposition of the G-control problem can be viewed as a nonlinear extension of Dellacherie-Meyer and Jeulin-Yor formula, which relates linear expectation under G in terms of linear expectation under F, and is used in option pricing for credit derivatives. • Each step in the backward induction ←→ stochastic control problem in the F-filtration (solved e.g. by dynamic programming and BSDE)

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

BSDEs formulation • Consider an utility function: U(x) = − exp(−px), p > 0, x ∈ R. and assume that F = FW Brownian filtration generated by W . I Then, the value functions Vk , k = 0, . . . , n, are given by  Vk (x, θ k , ek ) = U x − Yθkk (θ k , ek ) , where Y k , k = 0, . . . , n, are characterized by means of a recursive system of (indexed) BSDEs, derived from dynamic programming arguments in the F-filtration. Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

BSDE after n defaults

Ytn (θ, e) =

Z T 1 ln αT (θ, e) + f n (r , Zrn , θ, e)dr p t Z T − Zrn .dWr , t ≥ θn , t

with a (quadratic) generator f n : o np z − σtn (θ, e)0 π 2 − b n (θ, e).π . f n (t, z, θ, e) = inf n π∈A 2 Remark. Similar BSDE as in El Karoui, Rouge (00), Hu, Imkeller, M¨ uller (04), Sekine (06), for default-free market Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

BSDE after k defaults, k = 0, . . . , n − 1 Ytk (θ k , ek ) =

1 k ln αT (θ k , ek ) p Z T Z k k k + f (r , Yr , Zr , θ k , ek )dr − t

T

Zrk .dWr , t ≥ θk ,

t

with a generator f k (t, y , z, θ k , ek )

=

np z − σtk (θ k , ek )0 π 2 − btk (θ k , ek ).π 2 π∈Ak Z  1 + U(y ) U π.γtk (ek+1 ) − Ytk+1 (θ k , t, ek , ek+1 ) p E o ηk+1 (dek+1 ) . inf

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

BSDE characterization of the optimal investment problem Theorem. Under standard boundedness conditions on the coefficients of the model (b, σ, γ, α), there exists a unique solution (Y, Z) = (Y 0 , . . . , Y n , Z 0 , . . . , Z n ) ∈ S∞ × L2 to the recursive system of quadratic BSDEs. The initial value function is  V0 (x) = U x − Y00 , and the optimal strategies between τk and τk+1 by np Ztk − (σtk )0 π 2 − btk .π πtk ∈ arg min k 2 π∈A Z o  1 k + U(Yt ) U π.γtk (e) − Ytk+1 (t, e) ηk+1 (ek , de) . p E Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Technical remarks

• Existence for the system of recursive BSDEs: quadratic term in z + exponential term in y : I

Kobylanski techniques + approximating sequence + convergence

• Uniqueness: verification arguments + BMO techniques • We don’t need to assume boundedness condition on the portfolio control set

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Default times density • Two defaultable assets with default times (τ1 , τ2 ) ⊥ F. I τi ; E(ai ), and dependence of (τ1 , τ2 ) via a copula function: P[τ1 ≥ θ1 , τ2 ≥ θ2 ] = C (P[τ1 ≥ θ1 ], P[τ2 ≥ θ2 ])  (Gumbel example) = exp − ((a1 θ1 )β + (a2 θ2 )β )1/β , I

β ≥ 1 ↔ nonnegative correlation between τ1 and τ2 . Density of (τ1 , τ2 ): ατ (θ1 , θ2 ) = a1 a2 e −a1 θ1 −a2 θ2

I

∂2C (e −a1 θ1 , e −a2 θ2 ) ∂u1 ∂u2

Density of ranked default times and index marks (ˆ τ1 , τˆ2 , ι1 , ι2 ): α(θˆ1 , θˆ2 , i, j) = 1{i=1,j=2} ατ (θˆ1 , θˆ2 ) + 1{i=2,j=1} ατ (θˆ2 , θˆ1 ). Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Defaultable assets • Before any default: BS model for the two assets with drift b 0 = 0.02, volatility σ 0 = 0.1, correlation ρ. • At default τi of asset i = 1, 2: I

Asset i drops to zero (no more traded)

I

Asset j jumps by relative size γ ∈ (−1, ∞): γ < 0 ↔ loss, and γ > 0 ↔ gain, and then follows a BS model with coefficients b 1 = 0.01, σ 1 = 0.2, until its default.

• Investment horizon T = 1.

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

BSDEs as ODEs (I)

Y 2 (θ, i, j)

=

Yt1,i (θ1 )

=

1 ln α(θ, i, j), θ = (θ1 , θ2 ) ∈ ∆2 , i, j ∈ {1, 2}, i 6= j p 1 1 β ln ai + (β − 1) ln θ1 + ln((ai θ1 )β + (aj t)β ) p β Z T  − ((ai θ1 )β + (aj t)β )1/β + f 1,i (s, Ys1,i , θ1 )ds, t

where f 1,i (t, y , θ1 )

=

inf

np

π∈R

2

|σ 1 π|2 − b 1 π +

Huyˆ en PHAM

o 1 −p(y −π) e α(θ1 , t, i, j) , p

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

BSDEs as ODEs (II)

Yt0

=

T − (a1β + a2β )1/β + p

Z

T

f 0 (s, Ys0 )ds,

t

where f 0 (t, y )

= π=(π

np (σ 0 )0 π 2 − b 0 .π 2 2 ,π )∈R o 1,2 1 2 1 −py  −p(−π1 +π2 γ−Yt1,1 (t)) + e e + e −p(π γ−π −Yt (t)) . p

inf2 1

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Value function V 0 (t) for different jump sizes

0

ï0.5

Vt

0

ï1

ï1.5 a=ï0.5 a=0 a=0.5 a=1 Merton

ï2

ï2.5 0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

t

Figure:

Value function V 0 (t): a1 = a2 = 0.01, β = 2

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Optimal strategy in function of jump size for various default intensities

2.5 2 1.5

/(0)

1 0.5 0 ï0.5

Merton intensity=0.01 intensity=0.1 intensity=0.3

ï1 ï1

Figure:

ï0.5

0 a

0.5

1

optimal strategy by varying intensity a1 = a2 , and fixed β = 2 Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Optimal strategies in both assets by varying jump sizes and default intensities

Table:

Optimal strategies π ˆ 1 and π ˆ 2 before any defaults with various γ and default intensities.

γ a1 = 0.01, a2 = 0.1, β = 2 π ˆ1 π ˆ2 a1 = 0.1, a2 = 0.1, β = 2 π ˆ1 π ˆ2 a1 = 0.3, a2 = 0.1, β = 2 π ˆ1 π ˆ2

−0.5

−0.1

0

0.5

1

Merton

0.462 −1.047

1.659 −0.709

1.892 −0.498

2.621 0.623

2.832 1.168

2 2

−0.353 −0.353

−0.210 −0.210

−0.147 −0.147

0.556 0.556

2 2

2 2

−1.723 −0.132

−1.719 0.453

−1.647 0.521

−0.697 1.121

1.293 2.707

2 2

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Optimal strategies in both assets by varying correlation parameters

Table:

Optimal strategies π ˆ 1 and π ˆ 2 before any defaults with various ρ and β. a1 = 0.01, a2 = 0.1 γ ρ = 0, β = 1 π ˆ1 π ˆ2 ρ = 0, β = 2 π ˆ1 π ˆ2 ρ = 0.3, β = 1 π ˆ1 π ˆ2 ρ = 0.3, β = 2 π ˆ1 π ˆ2

−0.5

−0.1

0

0.5

1

Merton

0.228 −0.867

0.942 −0.452

1.099 −0.278

1.966 0.856

2.459 1.541

2 2

0.462 −1.047

1.659 −0.709

1.892 −0.498

2.621 0.623

2.832 1.168

2 2

0.492 −0.959

1.081 −0.504

1.188 −0.348

1.715 0.519

2.025 1.052

1.539 1.539

0.863 −1.235

1.939 −0.817

2.077 −0.626

2.399 0.216

2.450 0.627

1.539 1.539

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Concluding remarks (I) • Beyond the optimal investment problem considered here, we provide a general formulation of stochastic control under progressive enlargement of filtration with multiple random times and marks: I

Change of regimes in the state process, control set and gain functional after each random time

I

Includes in particular the formulation via jump-diffusion controlled processes

• Recursive decomposition on each default scenario of the G-control problem into F-stochastic control problems by relying on the density hypothesis Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Introduction Multiple defaults risk model Optimal investment problem Backward system of BSDEs Numerical illustrations Conclusion

Concluding remarks (II)

• F-decomposition method → another perspective for the study of controlled diffusion processes with (finite number of) jumps, (quadratic) BSDEs with (finite number of) jumps → Get rid of the jump terms I

obtain comparison theorems under weaker conditions

I

Alternative approach for numerical schemes of BSDEs with jumps

→ Recent works by Kharroubi and Lim (11 a,b).

Huyˆ en PHAM

Multiple defaults risk and BSDEs

Optimal investment under multiple defaults: a BSDE ...

Multiple defaults risk model. Optimal investment problem. Backward system of BSDEs. Numerical illustrations. Conclusion. Trading strategies and wealth process. Control problem. F-decomposition. Usual global approach (when all Ak are identical). • Write the dynamics of assets and wealth process in the global filtration G.

350KB Sizes 0 Downloads 244 Views

Recommend Documents

Optimal Investment under Credit Constraint
We characterize the optimal investment decision, the financing and ...... [6] Dixit, A. and R. Pindyck, 1994, Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton University.

Optimal Static Hedging of Defaults in CDOs
The residual hedge error dependence on recovery uncertainty and ..... These insights come at the cost of extra effort in (1) solving the optimization problem to.

Optimal Static Hedging of Defaults in CDOs
These reference bonds can default, and in the event of default recover a fraction .... c. rT f h. ,T t. W i i i i i i. T i i i i τ ττ τ ττ. ∆. 0. 0 exp exp. :,0 at default exp exp. : ]0[ ...... tend to drive the upfront payment on the equity

Optimal Monetary Policy under Commitment with a Zero ...
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City or the Federal Reserve System. 2CEPR, London ... A calibration to the U.S. economy suggests that policy should reduce nominal interest .... directly into account the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates.6 ...

Optimal Multiple Surfaces Searching for Video/Image Resizing - A ...
Content-aware video/image resizing is of increasing rel- evance to allow high-quality image and video resizing to be displayed on devices with different resolution. In this paper, we present a novel algorithm to find multiple 3-D surfaces simultaneou

Optimal Recommendations under Attraction, Aversion ...
to post on servers or to redistribute to lists, requires prior specific permission ...... (MF) amounts to constructing profiles ui ∈ Rd, vj ∈ Rd that are solutions to: min.

On Optimal Investment for a Behavioural Investor in ...
Mar 5, 2013 - The issue of well-posedness is a recurrent theme in related papers (see ..... We add a comment on the case α+ = α− assuming, in addition, that ...

Non-concave optimal investment and no-arbitrage: a ...
Jul 20, 2016 - the existence of an optimal portfolio in a (generically incomplete) discrete-time financial market model with finite time horizon. Key words: no-arbitrage condition ; non-concave utility functions; optimal investment. AMS 2000 subject

Iterative Learning Control for Optimal Multiple-Point Tracking
on the system dynamics. Here, the improved accuracy in trajectory tracking results has led to the development of various control schemes, such as proportional ...

Optimal Monetary Policy under Incomplete Markets and ...
complete risk$sharing, providing a rich yet tractable framework for monetary policy ...... We will show that for a big set of parameter values, this last term is relatively .... 19Our estimates of σ from long$term U.S. and U.K. GDP data, range from 

Optimal Social Security Reform under Population Aging ...
Aug 27, 2010 - model of life-cycle consumption and labor supply, where social .... lifespan of a household is ¯T years, and the life cycle consists of two phases: ...

Optimal scheduling of pairwise XORs under statistical ...
Network Coding for Unicast Wireless Sessions: Design, Implementation, and Performance Evaluation,” in ACM SIGMETRICS, 2008. [3] E. Rozner, A. Iyer, ...

Probabilistic LMP Forecasting under AC Optimal Power Flow Framework
segment i is considered to be a straight (linear) line, with slope ai and intercept bi. The LMP–load curve is extended to include two extra segments in Fig. 2.

Optimal Social Security Reform under Population Aging ...
Aug 27, 2010 - -11)s6. (22) where s is model age. The 2001 U.S. Life Tables in Arias (2004) are reported up to actual age 100 ... an optimal or welfare-maximizing OASI tax rate of 10.6%.6 .... Figure 4: Gross replacement rates: Model Vs. U.S..

Optimal Taxation with Endogenous Default under ...
Jul 17, 2015 - of Economics, 530-1 Evans # 3880, Berkeley CA 94720, Email: .... By doing this, we endogenize the ad hoc government credit limits imposed in ...

Optimal Mobile Sensor Motion Planning Under ...
Keywords: Distributed parameter system, sensor trajectory, motion planning, RIOTS ... (Center for Self-Organizing and Intelligent Systems) at Utah State Univ. He obtained his ...... sults, in 'Proc. SPIE Defense and Security Symposium on Intelligent

Optimal Monetary Policy and Transparency under ...
Online appendix to the paper. Optimal Monetary Policy and Transparency under Informational Frictions. Wataru Tamura. February 10, 2016. Contents.

Optimal scheduling of pairwise XORs under statistical overhearing ...
and thus extends the throughput benefits to wider topolo- gies and flow scenarios. ... focus on wireless network coding and study the problem of scheduling ...

Optimal Monetary Policy under Model Uncertainty ...
Jun 3, 2013 - Washington, DC 20551, Email: [email protected]. ..... we consider an ad hoc functional form for households' income, f : X × S → R, that ...

Utility-Optimal Dynamic Rate Allocation under Average ...
aware applications that preserves the long-term average end- to-end delay constraint ...... Service Management, IEEE Transactions on, vol. 4, no. 3, pp. 40–49,.