Optimal and Fair Transmission Rate Allocation Problem in Multi-hop Cellular Networks Cristiana Gomes1 and Jérôme Galtier2 1

2

MASCOTTE Project - INRIA, I3S, CNRS, Univ. Nice Sophia, France. [email protected] Orange Labs, Sophia-Antipolis, France. [email protected]

?

Abstract We deal with the rate allocation problem for downlink in a Multi-hop Cellular Network. A mathematical model is provided to assign transmission rates in order to reach an optimal and fair solution. We prove that under some conditions that are often met, the problem can be reduced to a single-hop cellular network problem. The validity of our proof is conrmed experimentally.

1 Introduction Multihop Cellular Network preserves the benet of conventional single-hop cellular networks where the service infrastructure is provided by xed bases, and also incorporates the exibility of ad-hoc networks where wireless transmissions through mobile stations in multiple hops is allowed [1]. In ad-hoc networks, nodes communicate with each other in a peer-to-peer way and no infrastructure is required. If direct communication is not feasible, the simplest solution is to replace a single long-range link with a chain of short range links by using a series of nodes between the source and the destination: this is known as multi-hop communication [2]. The cooperation between these two networks can be interesting as ad-hoc networks can expand the covered area whitout the high cost of cellular networks infrastructure. We address in this paper a bottleneck problem that summarizes the situation of many multi-hop cellular networks, as illustrated in Figure 1. In our work, a gateway - or base station (BS) - has entire access to the rest of the world and provides this service in a more privileged way to some specic nodes, the relay nodes (the white ones in Figure 1). Those nodes are themselves relaying the service to the nodes in the free zone, called the terminal nodes (the gray ones in Figure 1). It can happen that nodes in the free zone relay one another to get the nal service. In our model, the relay nodes and the gateway form a single-hop cellular network (the critical zone) that constrains the system. Each node has a utility function representing its degree of satisfaction based on the assigned rate transmission. The whole system is governed by the optimization of the sum of utility functions over all the nodes, as in [3,4]. We give a ?

C. Gomes is funded by CAPES, Brazil. This work has been partially supported by European project ist/fet aeolus and is part of the CRC CORSO with Orange Labs.

model that allows to transform the multi-hop network (Figure 1) into a singlehop network (Figure 2), by eventually modifying the utility functions on the relay nodes, as depicted in Figure 1. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section we discuss the related works. In section 3, we dene the problem, the adopted notation and the considered hypotheses. The section 4 shows how the problem can be reduced to a single-hop network. That is how the complete network utility functions can be replaced by a small set of dierent functions assigned to the relay nodes, in the context of a fair and optimal optimization. We push forward our results in section 5 by applying them to specic cases of fairness.

2 Related work This described scenario occurs in multi-hop networks as considered in [1,2]. Indeed, it is observed that often in these networks the bandwidth is constrained specically by a bottleneck around the gateway [5,6], conrming the fact that it is a representative area. Many real networks deal with this situation. For instance, using UMTS technology for the single-hop network [7,4,8], while the free zone is covered by WiFi or Bluetooth systems.

Free zone

Free zone

Critical zone

Critical zone

(BS)

(BS)

Figure 2. Multi-hop cellular network Figure 1. Multi-hop cellular network.

reduced in single-hop.

We show that there exists a set of utility functions that can be assigned to the relay nodes replacing the complete set of utility functions. It is due to the fact that the problem is convex under some conditions that are often met. Convex optimization techniques are important in engineering applications because a local optimum is also a global optimum in a convex problem. Rigorous optimality conditions and a duality theory also exist to check the solution optimality. Consequently, when a problem is cast into a convex form, the structure of the optimal solution, which often reveals design insights, can often be identied. Furthermore, powerful numerical algorithms exist to solve convex problems eciently.

We are interested in Pareto-optimal solutions, that is solutions where the utility of an individual cannot be improved without decreasing the utility of one or more other nodes. The fairness is a key issue in wireless networks, since the medium is shared among the nodes. In our problem, it implies that each ow going through a bottleneck receives a fair share of the available bandwidth. Our work admits the generalized fairness criterion as dened in [3] that can assume several criteria (see section 5 for more details), for example, the proportional fairness one. The proportional fairness has been studied in the context of the Internet ow due the similarity to the congestion control mechanism of the TCP/IP protocols, where each TCP's throughput is adapted as a function of the congestion. The work in [9] addresses the question of how the available bandwidth within the network should be shared between competing streams of elastic trac3 .

3 Model Denition We distinguish here three main types of nodes. The BS that is unique in our case, the relay nodes in R that have a limited link to the BS and the terminal nodes in Tr that are connected to the BS through an unique relay node r at the single-hop network. Note that multi-hops are allowed as long as connections between terminal nodes are given for free, that is the relay node has bandwidth enough for itself and its relayed terminals. The terminal nodes are considered sparsely distributed around the cell, thus interference is not a problem at the free zone. We focus on the downlink channel (from the BS to the relay nodes) considering a given xed bandwidth. Let αr be the rate of the downlink channel from the BS to relay node r. Let ρt be the downlink rate at each node t ∈ Tr . We consider the following hypotheses.

Hypothesis 1 All terminal nodes in Tr use an unique relay node r ∈ R. Hypothesis 2 We only consider interferences between the relay nodes in R. Note that the rst hypothesis allows multiple hops and routes in the free zone but imposes to gather all the trac of an individual node to a unique relay in the critical zone. The second hypothesis means also that the bandwidth is not limited in the free zone. We summarize the important denitions below.

Nodes Set

 BS : node representing the base station. We consider an unique BS .  R: set of relay nodes, directly connected to the BS by a limited link.  Tr : set containing the node r ∈ R and the set of terminal nodes relayed by r.

3

The elastic trac tolerates packet delays and losses and permits the nodes to adjust their rates in order to ll available bandwidth.

Variables

 pb,r : power of the signal emitted by the BS to the router r.  ρt : downlink rate for each node t ∈ Tr .  αr : downlink rate for each node r ∈ R, enough to attend all nodes t ∈ Tr . P αr =

t∈Tr

ρt .

Utility Functions

 Ut (ρt ): utility function at the node t ∈ Tr representing its degree of satisfaction. This function is non-decreasing with ρt .

 Ur (αr ): cumulative utility function at the node r ∈ R representing the maximum degree of satisfaction of the . Given that the bandwidth is P nodes in TrP αr , it is dened Ur (αr ) = max{ t∈Tr Ut (ρt ); t∈Tr ρt = αr }.

We deal with the optimal and fair transmission rate allocation problem P (problem (P) ), we have to nd a vector of the relay rates α that maximizes

r∈R Ur (αr ) with a fair sharing among the terminals, guarantying the existence of a vector of transmissions powers p = (pb,1 , pb,2 , ..., pb,|R| ).

In order to model interference in the critical zone, we focus on a commonly used denition of feasible rates which depends on both a target γ and a target interference level K . The packet sent by the BS is received by the relay node if the SINR (Signal to Interference plus Noise Ratio) is above a given threshold γ . The constants No and gb,r are given considering the network environment. Let No be the thermal noise and gb,r is the channel gain between the BS and the relay r. The variables pb,r represent the power of the signal emitted by the BS to the relay r. A vector of rates α = (α1 , α2 , ..., α|R| ) is considered a feasible solution if there exists a vector of transmissions powers p = (pb,1 , pb,2 , ..., pb,|R| ) that satises the following conditions for the SINR that a node connected to the BS experiences: P pb,rP gb,r αr γ 6 No +gb,r p 6 KNo . A vector of = SIN R , ∀r ∈ R and b,r r r∈R s6=r pb,s rates α is an optimal rate allocation if it is a solution to the following model on variables α and p:

Problem (P')

max

X

Ur (αr )

(1)

r∈R

subject to

αr γ 6

pb,r gb,r P , ∀r ∈ R No + gb,r s6=r pb,s X pb,r 6 KNo . r∈R

Since utility functions are non-decreasing, an optimal solution veries: pb,r gb,r P , ∀r ∈ R αr γ = No + gb,r s6=r pb,s

(2) (3)

which gives pb,r =

pb,r =

αr γ gb,r (No

+ gb,r

P s6=r

pb,s ), thus

X αr γ (No + gb,r pb,s − gb,r pb,r ), ∀r ∈ R. gb,r

(4)

s∈R

Moreover, increasing all the powers by the same factor allows to tighten constraints (3) while relaxing constraints (2). By optimality we have X pb,r = KNo r∈R

which, put into equation (4) gives pb,r = we obtain:

pb,r =

+ gb,r K) − gb,r pb,r ) and

αr γNo (1 + Kgb,r ) , ∀r ∈ R. gb,r (1 + αr γ)

Like in [7], we use the substitution P pb,r r∈R No 6 K , we can say:

αr =

αr γ gb,r (No (1

αr γ(1+Kgb,r ) gb,r (1+αr γ)

= dr . As

(5)

P r∈R

dr 6

dr gb,r , ∀r ∈ R. γ(1 + gb,r (K − dr ))

So, we obtain the following equivalent problem on variables dr :

Problem (P)

max

X

µ Ur

r∈R

dr gb,r γ(1 + gb,r (K − dr ))

¶ (6)

subject to

½P

r∈R dr 6 K dr > 0, ∀r ∈ R.

(7)

4 Theoretical approach with fairness and optimality In this section, the problem is how to dene the cumulative utility functions Ur (αr ) for each relay node r ∈ R in a way to represent the utility functions Ut (ρt ) of all nodes t ∈ Tr . Moreover, the available bandwidth of each relay node has to be shared with fairness among the nodes in Tr . Indeed, we prove that there exists a set of utility functions Ur (αr ) (cumulative functions) that can be assigned to the relay nodes replacing the complete set of utility functions and, it can be expressed analytically in most cases. Moreover, we show P that for any xed available bandwidth αr at each relay node, if the sum t∈Tr Ut (βt αr ) is maximized it converges to a fairness equilibrium. Thus, it is always possible to share αr fairly among the nodes in Tr . The fairness equilibrium point is dened by the utility function adopted. We consider the following technical assumption.

Technical Assumption 1 The nodes' utility functions Ut (.) are00 assumed to be strictly increasing concave functions and satisfy the condition Ut (x) 6

−1 x2 .

As said before the particular utility function Ur (αr ) is dened as follows:

Problem (Pr )

Ur (αr ) = max

X

(8)

Ut (ρt )

t∈Tr

subject to

αr =

X

(9)

ρt , ∀r ∈ R.

t∈Tr

We need the following lemma regarding how the rate αr assigned to a relay r ∈ R can be shared by all terminals it relays. Our objective is that given αr we can assign a fraction βt of αr for each terminal t ∈ Tr in a fair way.

Lemma 1 Given the vector ρ∗ = (ρ1 , ..., ρ|Tr | ) being the optimal solution for the 0

0

0

problem Pr , we consider a variable βt ∈ [0, 1], a xed feasible relay rate αr and 0 0 we dene ρt = αr βt . We obtain 0

0

0

0

Ut1 (βt1 αr ) = Ut2 (βt2 αr ), ∀t1 , t2 ∈ Tr .

Proof. Letting βt = for a r ∈ R: Problem (Pr0 )

ρt αr ,

we consider the following subproblem with a xed αr

max

X

(10)

Ut (βt αr )

t∈Tr

subject to

½

βt > 0, ∀t ∈ Tr P t∈Tr βt = 1.

(11)

We can say that it is a local version of the problem Pr , in a way that an optimal solution for Pr0 considering the optimal value for αr∗ = arg maxαr Ur (αr ) can be translated into a locally optimal solution for Pr . We can rewrite the constraints as:   −β P t 6 0, ∀t ∈ Tr βt 6 1 (12)  Pt∈Tr −β 6 −1 t t∈Tr Based on [10], the Lagrangian of this subproblem can be written as follow: Ã ! Ã ! X X X X L(β) = Ut (βt αr ) − λt (−βt ) − µ βt − 1 − ν −βt + 1 t∈Tr

t∈Tr

t∈Tr

t∈Tr

0

ρ

ρ

0

|Tr | with the lagrange multipliers λi > 0, µ > 0 and ν > 0. As β ∗ = ( αtr , ..., α ) r is necessarily a vector of optimal solutions for the Lagrangian. So it veries ∂L = 0 in β ∗ , ∀t ∈ Tr , which gives KKT's optimality conditions: ∂β t 0

0

αr Ut (βt αr ) + λt − µ + ν = 0, ∀t ∈ Tr . 0

Moreover, by KKT complementary slackness conditions λt βt = 0, ∀t ∈ Tr . 00 Note that under technical assumption 1, we have Ut (ρt ) → −∞ when ρt → 0 0+ for all t. We can deduce that Ut (ρt ) → +∞ and Ut (ρt ) → −∞ when ρt → 0+ for all t, making impossible the case where ρt = 0. So βt 6= 0, that gives λt = 0. 0 0 Hence αr Ut (βt αr ) − µ + ν = 0, ∀t ∈ Tr . We obtain 0

0

0

0

Ut1 (βt1 αr ) = Ut2 (βt2 αr ), ∀t1 , t2 ∈ Tr 0

0

As neither −µ nor ν depends on t, it means that Ut (ρt ) = C, ∀t ∈ Tr where C is a constant. ¥ We have then the following theorem regarding the maximum point of the function Ur .

Theorem 1 The function P Ur (αr ) for each r ∈PR is obtained as follows. Let 0 ht = (Ut )−1 and hr = t∈Tr ht , then Ur (αr ) = t∈Tr Ut ◦ ht ◦ h−1 r (αr ), ∀r ∈ R. 00

0

Proof. By Technical Assumption 1, we have Ut (x) < 0, ∀t ∈ Tr then Ut , ∀t ∈ Tr are strictly monotonic P decreasing functions. So these inverse functions ht , ∀t ∈ Tr exist. We set hr = t∈Tr ht . By Lemma 1 and reusing the notation for C , we have 0 0 hr (C) = β1 αr + ... + β|Tr | αr = αr . (13) Now, we can have Ur expressed by functions Ut . Indeed, we have from equa0 0 −1 tion (13), C = h−1 r ) and ρt = ht (C) r ). We derive Ut (ρt ) = r (αP P = ht ◦ hr (α−1 0 −1 Ut ◦ ht ◦ hr (αr ) and t∈Tr Ut (ρt ) = t∈Tr Ut ◦ ht ◦ hr (αr ). So, we can consider X Ur (αr ) = Ut ◦ ht ◦ h−1 r (αr ), ∀r ∈ R. t∈Tr 0

0

Making αr = αr∗ we obtain hr (C) = β1 αr∗ + ... + β|Tr | αr∗ = αr∗ and the solution for Pr0 is already optimal for Pr . ¥

5 Results In this section we show some results using our model for the problem P . To solve the model, we use a software library for nonlinear optimization of continuous systems, the Interior Point OPTimizer (IPOPT) that is part of the COIN-OR project. We used the modeling environment AMPL (A Mathematical Programming Language).

We show examples of utility functions and their cumulative representations conrming the validity of our proof experimentally. For the sake of simplicity, our examples consider a small network with 5 nodes: 2 relays and 3 terminals, as shown in Figure 3. 2 3 1

4 5

Figure 3. Example with 5 nodes. We consider the utility functions described below. The graphs P in Figures 4, 6 and 8 show the cumulative functions, that is using Ur (αr ) = t∈Tr Ut ◦ ht ◦ −1 h Pr (αr ), ∀r ∈ R. Figures in 5, 7 and 9 consider all utility functions and Ur (αr ) = t∈Tr Ut (ρt ). We study the obtained rate ρt varying gain gb,r (with xed target interference level K = 2). The graphs below show the evolution of the node rates as we increase the gain of the nodes.P We consider the same P gain for all relay nodes. 0 Recall that ht = (Ut )−1 , hr = t∈Tr ht and Ur (αr ) = t∈Tr Ut ◦ ht ◦ h−1 r (αr ). Consider ρt > 0 and ρt < 1.

 Ut (ρt ) = ct ln(ρt ) 0

ct ρt

So, ht (yt ) = ρt = yctt . Consider x = hr (y) = P 1 −1 t∈Tr ct that implies y = x t∈Tr ct = hr (x). It gives the cumulative y utility function: ³ ³ ´ P ´ P P Ur (αr ) = t∈Tr ct ln 1 Pct c = t∈Tr ct ln(αr )+ t∈Tr ct ln P ct ct .

Ut = P 1

ct 0 Ut

= yt , ρt =

=

ct yt .

t

t∈Tr

αr

t∈Tr

Relay 1 Relay 4

Rate transmission fraction

0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Gain

Figure 4. ³ Aggregated ´ P t∈Tr

ct ln

P ct

t∈Tr

ct

.

function

Ur (αr )

=

P t∈Tr

ct ln(αr )

+

Node 1 (ct=3) Node 2 (ct=4) Node 3 (ct=5) Node 4 (ct=1) Node 5 (ct=2) Relay 1 Relay 4

Rate transmission fraction

0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Gain

Figure 5. Considering multi-hop with Ur (αr ) =

P t∈Tr

ct ln(ρt ).

Ut (ρt ) and Ut (ρt ) =

√  Ut (ρt ) = ct ρt c2

0

c2

Ut (ρt ) = − 2√ctρt = yt , ρt = 4yt2 . So, ht (yt ) = ρt = 4yt2 . Consider x = t t qP P 1 2 = h−1 (x). It gives hr (y) = 4y12 t∈Tr c2t that implies y = 2√ c t r t∈Tr x the cumulative utility function: r qP P c2t 2√ “ ” Ur (αr ) = t∈Tr ct = √ 2 P t∈Tr ct αr . 1 2 4

2

√ αr

t∈Tr

ct

Relay 1 Relay 4

Rate transmission fraction

0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Gain

Figure 6. Aggregated function Ur (αr ) =

qP t∈Tr

√ c2t αr .

Node 1 (ct=3) Node 2 (ct=4) Node 3 (ct=5) Node 4 (ct=1) Node 5 (ct=2) Relay 1 Relay 4

Rate transmission fraction

0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Gain

Figure 7. Considering multi-hop with Ur (αr ) =

P t∈Tr

√ ct ρt .

 Ut (ρt ) =

Ut (ρt ) and Ut (ρt ) =

−ct ρt

q q 0 Ut (ρt ) = ρc2t = yt , ρt = yctt . So, ht (yt ) = ρt = yctt . Consider x = hr (y) = t ³P √ ´2 P √ ct t∈Tr 1 √ c that implies y = = h−1 t r (x). It gives the cumut∈Tr y x lative utility P function: −ct P √ Ur (αr ) = t∈Tr v = −( t∈Tr ct )2 α1r . u ct u t

! P √ ct 2 t∈Tr αr

Relay 1 Relay 4

Rate transmission fraction

0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Gain

P

Figure 8. Aggregated function Ur (αr ) = −(

t∈Tr



ct )2 α1r .

Node 1 (ct=3) Node 2 (ct=4) Node 3 (ct=5) Node 4 (ct=1) Node 5 (ct=2) Relay 1 Relay 4

Rate transmission fraction

0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Gain

Figure 9. Considering multi-hop with Ur (αr ) =

P t∈Tr

Ut (ρt ) and Ut (ρt ) =

−ct ρt .

Generalized fairness utility function Previously we saw some options of utility function respecting technical assumption 1. An interesting function was proposed by [3]:

Ut (ρt ) = ct

ρ1−κ t 1−κ

(14)

This function is interesting because it generalizes all the following important cases of fairness:

   

P The globally optimal allocation : when κ = 0, that is max t∈Tr ρt . The harmonic mean fairness : when κ = 2. The MaxMin fairness : when κ → ∞, max mint∈Tr ρt . P ρt1−κ = The proportional fairness : when κ → 1, max t∈Tr limκ→1 1−κ P P P e(1−κ) ln(ρt ) 1+(1−κ)ln(ρt ) , that is max t∈Tr ln(ρt ). t∈Tr limκ→1 t∈Tr 1−κ Q ∼ 1−κ It is equivalent to max t∈Tr ρt that in a convex framework represents the Nash Equilibrium.

The previous utility functions are in fact the utility function in (14) with a given κ (respectively κ = 1, κ = 12 and κ = 2). Considering directly the ρ1−κ t 1−κ ,

−1

0

we have: Ut (ρt ) = ct ρ−κ = yt , ρt = yctt κ . So, t 1 P κ P 1 ct κ t∈Tr ct ht (yt ) = ρt = yt . Consider x = hr (y) = that im1 t∈Tr ht = κ  y 1−κ ! Ã κ 1 1 P κ κ P c c ct  t∈Tr t t  . Thus Ur (αr ) = = plies h−1 1 r (x) = t∈Tr 1−κ x P function Ut (ρt ) = ct

κ t∈Tr ct x



1 1 P κ t∈Tr ct

«1−κ

P

1−κ κ

ct t∈Tr 1−κ ct

x1−κ , therefore we can derive a generalized fair-

ness utility function:

à Ur (αr ) =

X

!κ 1 κ

ct

t∈Tr

x1−κ . 1−κ

(15)

We show an example of our problem using the utility function in (14) for all nodes considering dierent values of κ.

0.04

Relay 1 Relay 4

Rate transmission fraction

0.035 0.03 0.025 0.02 0.015 0.01 0.005 0 0

0.5

1

1.5

2 2.5 k at (10)

3

Figure 10. Cumulative function Ur (αr ) =

0.04

4

³P

4.5

1

κ t∈Tr ct

´κ

x1−κ 1−κ .

Node 1 (ct=3) Node 2 (ct=4) Node 3 (ct=5) Node 4 (ct=1) Node 5 (ct=2) Relay 1 Relay 4

0.035 Rate transmission fraction

3.5

0.03 0.025 0.02 0.015 0.01 0.005 0 0

0.5

1

1.5

2 2.5 k at (10)

3

Figure 11. Considering multi-hop with Ur (αr ) = ρ1−κ t ct 1−κ .

3.5

4

P t∈Tr

4.5

Ut (ρt ) and Ut (ρt ) =

Figures 10 and 11 show the obtained rate ρt varying κ (with xed channel gain gb,r = 2, ∀r). Figure 10 shows the rates considering the cumulative function in (15). Figure 11 shows the rates of all the nodes using the utility function in (14), note that each node has a dierent value for the constant ct . The gures in this section show that we obtain the same graph for the relay nodes in both approaches as we proved.

6 Conclusion and perspectives We have considered in this paper the transmission rate allocation problem for multi-hop cellular networks in a way to reach an optimal and fair solution. We show that it can be reduced to a single-hop problem by only changing the utility functions. We conrm the validity of our proof experimentally. Reducing multi-hop problems into problems with an unique cell (single-hop) has many advantages for the optimization problem. First we can reuse techniques that were designed basically for the one-cell case [7,4,11]. Second, we can identify bottlenecks, and in particular see if a congestion is due to the particular situation of a relay node, or to the specic utility function of the terminals it relays. Of course the question on implementing distributed algorithms based on those results remains open. We can wonder if a pricing strategy is achievable. Another question is what kind of intermediate capacity restrictions on the second (or more) hop(s) can be added if we want to keep the same good properties.

References 1. Y.-D. J. Lin and Y.-C. Hsu, Multihop cellular: A new architecture for wireless communications, in INFOCOM, 2000, pp. 12731282. [Online]. Available: citeseer.ist.psu.edu/lin00multihop.html. 2. F. Fitzek and M. Katz, Eds., Cooperation in Wireless Networks: Principles and Applications  Real Egoistic Behavior is to Cooperate!, ser. ISBN 1-4020-4710-X. Springer, Apr. 2006. 3. J. Mo and J. Walrand, Fair end-to-end window-based congestion control, IEEE/ACM Transactions on Networking, vol. 8, pp. 556567, 2000. 4. E. Altman, J. Galtier, and C. Touati, Fair power and transmission rate control in wireless networks, in Proc. of IEEE GlobeCom'02, Taipei, Taiwan, Nov. 2002. 5. J.-C. Bermond, J. Galtier, R. Klasing, N. Morales, and S. Perennes, Hardness and approximation of gathering in static radio networks, Parallel Processing Letters, vol. 16, no. 2, pp. 165184, June 2006. 6. C. Gomes, S. Pérennes, and H. Rivano, Bottleneck analysis for routing and call scheduling in multi-hop wireless networks, in 4th IEEE Workshop on Broadband Wireless Access (BWA), 4th Dec. 2008. 7. L. Yun and D. Messerschmitt, Power control for variable QoS on a CDMA channel, in IEEE MILCOM 1, 1994, pp. 178182. 8. J. Price and T. Javidi, Leveraging downlink for regulation of distributed uplink cdma, in GLOBECOM, 2006.

9. F. P. Kelly, A. Maulloo, and D. Tan, Rate control in communication networks: shadow prices, proportional fairness and stability, Journal of the Operational Research Society, Statistical Laboratory, University of Cambridge, vol. 49, pp. 237 252, 1998. 10. J.-B. Hiriart-Urruty and C. Lemaréchal, Fundamentals of Convex Analysis. Springer-Verlag New York, LLC, 2001. 11. J. Galtier, Adaptive power and transmission rate control in cellular CDMA networks, in Globecom, 2006.

Optimal and Fair Transmission Rate Allocation Problem ...

lular networks where the service infrastructure is provided by fixed bases, and also incorporates ... In section 3, we define the problem, the adopted notation and.

302KB Sizes 0 Downloads 246 Views

Recommend Documents

Utility-Optimal Dynamic Rate Allocation under Average ...
aware applications that preserves the long-term average end- to-end delay constraint ...... Service Management, IEEE Transactions on, vol. 4, no. 3, pp. 40–49,.

Fair Beamwidth Selection and Resource Allocation for ...
†School of ECE, College of Engineering, University of Tehran, Iran. ‡School of ... promising technology for supporting extremely high data rates in the next generation .... devices begin with finding the best sector-level beams through a sequence

Optimal Allocation Mechanisms with Single ... - Semantic Scholar
Oct 18, 2010 - [25] Milgrom, P. (1996): “Procuring Universal Service: Putting Auction Theory to Work,” Lecture at the Royal Academy of Sciences. [26] Myerson ...

Optimal Allocation Mechanisms with Single ... - Semantic Scholar
Oct 18, 2010 - We study revenue-maximizing allocation mechanisms for multiple heterogeneous objects when buyers care about the entire ..... i (ci,cLi)], where (pLi)z denotes the probability assigned to allocation z by pLi. The timing is as follows: S

Optimal sequential treatment allocation
Dec 12, 2017 - treatment) and obtaining more precise information later (by postponing the measurement). In addition, we argue that the desirability of a treatment cannot be measured only by its ex- pected outcome. A sensible welfare function must tak

Optimal Transmission Regulation in Restructured ...
Nov 3, 2013 - ity supply into three categories: power producers (generators), power deliverers (transmission firms), and ... up the generator and retailer functions to entry and competition while keeping the separate ...... find a statistically signi

Distributive Subband Allocation, Power and Rate ... - IEEE Xplore
in an orthogonal frequency-division multiple-access (OFDMA) cellular system with ... systems with imperfect CSIT in order to take into account of potential packet ...

Optimal Transmission Regulation in Restructured ...
affects the entire wholesale market that relies on transmission firms for fulfillment. I find ..... consumption results in suppliers charging less for their production. ...... The direct and indirect market effects can be seen as the dollar impact a

optimal allocation with ex-post verification and limited penalties
The proof of Lemma 2 is in the online appendix. By Lemma 2 and the assumption that v(x) ..... r∗ , is outside the domain [n−1 n. , 1], as n ≥ ¯n implies 1 r∗ > 1 n.

Optimal information transmission in organizations
upon this characterization to address a design problem: the determination of ... (a star-like organization), any problem could reach its solution in, at most, two ...

Exchange Rate Regime and International Transmission ...
Keywords: Exchange rate regime, Business cycle co-movement, Capital account openness, .... 10 Studies like Clark and van Wincoop (2001) and Baxter and Kouparitsas (2005) support the positive effect of trade on business .... variables, making the numb

Optimal Quantization and Bit Allocation for ...
Etienne Marcheret, Vaibhava Goel, Peder A. Olsen. IBM T. J. Watson Research, Yorktown Heights, NY, USA ... The first stage, level 1, relies on a set of Gaussians. G to convert an input d-dimensional feature vector xt to offset .... terms of the produ

optimal allocation with ex-post verification and limited penalties
social value of giving the prize to an agent is privately known by this agent. The ...... (19). Fn−1(xr) = (1 − c)r. The solution of problem (Pr) is thus. (20) gr(x) =.

Exchange Rate Misalignment, Capital Flows, and Optimal Monetary ...
What determines the optimal monetary trade-off between internal objectives (inflation, and output gap) and external objectives (competitiveness and trade imbalances) when inef- ficient capital flows cause exchange rate misalignment and distort curren

Exchange Rate Misalignment, Capital Flows, and Optimal Monetary ...
What determines the optimal monetary trade-off between internal objectives (inflation, and output gap) and external objectives (competitiveness and trade imbalances) when inef- ficient capital flows cause exchange rate misalignment and distort curren

Fair Energy Resource Allocation by Minority Game ... - Semantic Scholar
resource from electrical power-grid and renewable energy resource from solar .... Solar PV panel [1] to harvest solar energy with dependence between the ...

Home bias, exchange rate disconnect, and optimal ...
analytical solutions, these NOEM models are usually static with no price persistence, and ... the low exchange rate pass-through documented in the data.2 The short-run .... fluctuations into large and prolonged inflation fluctuations through the ...

On fair network cache allocation to content providers - Semantic Scholar
Apr 12, 2016 - theoretic rules outperform in terms of content access latency the naive cache ... With the advent of broadband and social networks, the In-.

Fair Energy Resource Allocation by Minority Game ...
resource from electrical power-grid and renewable energy resource from ... solar photovoltaic (PV) has been installed globally in 2010 [2][3]. Thus, there is an ...

On fair network cache allocation to content providers - Semantic Scholar
Available online 12 April 2016. Keywords: In-network caching ..... (i.e., possibly offering different prices to different classes) would be easily considered .... x ∈ Rn. + containing the cache space portion to allocate to each CP. (i.e., the value

Optimal sobolev norms and the Lp minkowski problem
W. Chen, Lp Minkowski problem with not necessarily positive data, to appear in .... Department of Mathematics, Polytechnic University, Brooklyn, NY 11201, USA.

Competitive Problem Solving and the Optimal Prize ...
The continuity guarantees that a VsmallV change of the timing or the prize size brings also VsmallV change in the payoff. When agent i makes the effort, he has to specify his problem solving method which determines the time to find a solution t-. The

Optimal Allocation Mechanisms with Single-Dimensional ... - DII UChile
Oct 18, 2010 - the allocation of “sponsored-link” positions on a search engine: Each .... virtual surpluses, the solution derived via pointwise optimization is not ...