ECONOMIC COMMENTARY

Number 2011-11 June 29, 2011

Labor Market Rigidity, Unemployment, and the Great Recession Murat Tasci and Mary Zenker Countries with very flexible institutions and labor market polices, like the U.S., experienced substantial increases in unemployment over the course of the Great Recession, while countries with relatively rigid institutions and strict labor market policies, like France, fared better. However, this better short-term performance comes with a tradeoff: Evidence suggests that flexible labor markets keep unemployment lower in the long run.

The recent recession that hit the global economy resulted in substantial contractions in GDP among major industrialized countries, but their labor market outcomes varied significantly. For example, the U.S. and France experienced similar declines in GDP during the recession. While unemployment in the U.S. shot up about 5 percentage points over that period, France saw an increase of only about 1.5 percentage points. Looking over the last 25 years, however, the average unemployment rate is much lower in the U.S. than in France (5.9 percent versus 9.6 percent). What explains these differences in labor market outcomes? We argue that some of this divergence is due to differences in labor market institutions and the policies that regulate labor market interactions. Labor markets with very flexible institutions and policies, like the U.S., experienced substantial increases in unemployment over the course of the recession. Meanwhile, countries with relatively rigid institutions and strict labor market policies, such as large continental European countries, fared better. However, this smoother short-term performance comes with a tradeoff; evidence suggests that flexible labor markets manage to keep unemployment lower in the long run. Labor Market Rigidity and Unemployment: Theory The unemployment rate is the main indicator of the labor market’s health, and economic theory provides an intuitive framework for understanding the forces that determine its level: At any time, there are flows into and out of unemployment, which we call job-finding and -separation rates, respectively (for more evidence on how these flow rates map into long-run unemployment rates, see Tasci and Zaman 2010). By affecting these flow rates, labor-market institutions and policies influence both short- and long-term unemployment rates. In every labor market, workers and firms are regulated by institutions and policies that affect

ISSN 0428-1276

these flow rates, such as minimum wages, unemployment insurance, severance pay, advance notice, labor taxes, and so on. The observed unemployment rate is affected by all the incentives and disincentives implied by these arrangements. Consider unemployment insurance, which cushions workers against unemployment risk by providing some income if they lose their job. On the one hand, this is much-needed financial assistance during a jobless spell. On the other, it may also give unemployed workers an incentive to turn down job offers that they would otherwise find acceptable, thereby reducing the job-finding rate. As a result, all else equal a higher level of unemployment compensation will increase an economy’s long-run unemployment rate. Similarly, employment-protection measures might provide a disincentive to create jobs. For instance, continental European countries have very strict laws against firing employees and hiring temporary workers. Conceivably, employers in those countries would have less flexibility to adjust their workforces in the face of a recession. A direct effect might be a muted increase in the separation rate. Although this might mitigate an increase in the unemployment rate during bad times, firms that anticipate the firing restriction might hesitate to hire in the first place, even in good times; this behavior would increase unemployment by lowering hiring (job-finding) rates. Another example—one that gets a lot of attention—is taxation of labor income. Some researchers think that by effectively reducing the return from market work, labor-income taxes distort workers’ behavior. Most continental European countries also have high labor-income taxes. To simplify the discussion going forward, we divide countries, somewhat arbitrarily, into two groups according to how rigid their labor markets are. We call labor markets that have strict-

er requirements governing employment relationships rigid, and labor markets with more lenient requirements flexible.

ployment responses. Although Italy and Greece experienced similar-sized GDP shocks, Italy’s unemployment rate ticked up only slightly, whereas Greece’s rose more than 5 percentage points. Germany is unusual in that its 7 percent decline in GDP was accompanied by a decrease in its unemployment rate!

The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) publishes an “Overall Strictness of Employment Protection” index that allows us to categorize countries as rigid or flexible. The index provides a measure of the general strictness of the labor market in a country with respect to the processes and costs involved when firing workers or hiring temporary employees. The U.S. has maintained the same index value, 0.21, for the entire period over which the index is available. European countries tend to have a much higher index value, with 2.5 being the average value over that period for the EU-15 countries (15 countries that made up the European Union before May 2004).

It’s impossible to tell from the unemployment rate alone, however, what else might be happening in the labor market to explain such data. For example, Germany’s unemployment rate declined, but those who are employed might be working less. That response would not be captured explicitly in the unemployment rate. In fact, when we look at the relevant data, we see that the length of the average work week in Germany actually plummeted throughout the recession.

Economic theory suggests that rigid labor markets, all else equal, will have higher unemployment rates and lower rates of churning. However, labor market rigidities might dampen the fluctuations in the unemployment rate in the short run, since workers and firms in rigid markets will have a harder time adjusting to rapidly changing economic conditions, especially around the turning points of the business cycle. We will provide some evidence in support of these arguments by looking at data from some OECD countries during the last recession and over a longer period.

So far, we have assumed that labor markets respond to aggregate economic activity, with higher unemployment rates following contractions in real output. But all economies might not respond to aggregate conditions in the same way. Since rigid labor markets might have responded differently to the contraction in output than more flexible labor markets during the Great Recession, we first plot the change in countries’ unemployment rates and their level of overall strictness (using the OECD’s indicator) and see how the relationship plays out (figure 2).

Labor-Market Rigidity and Unemployment during the Great Recession As we noted above, the recent recession translated into exceptionally bad performance in world output. According to the International Monetary Fund, after growing at a rate of 4.2 percent every year between 2000 and 2007, world output rose only 2.8 percent in 2008 and contracted by 0.5 percent in 2009. This might have been the first time since World War II that the world economy actually shrank.

Our sample countries vary widely in the strictness of their employment protection, taking values between 0.2 and 3.4 (the OECD average is 1.9). The United States has the lowest employment protection score of the countries in the sample. Correspondingly, its unemployment rate response is one of the strongest on the chart. The trend line suggests a somewhat negative relationship: As employment protection increases, the unemployment rate response becomes more muted. This relationship is even stronger if we exclude Spain, Ireland, Greece, and Portugal, which all had deep fiscal crises on top of the recession. Nevertheless, this relation-

Looking at the sample of countries in figure 1, we see that similar-sized GDP shocks yielded a wide range of unem-

Figure 1. Changes in GDP and Unemployment Percent change in real GDP 15 GDP Unemployment rate 10

Percentage point change in unemployment rate 15 10

Figure 2. Employment Protection and Unemployment Percentage point change in unemployment rate 12 All sample countries Excluding Spain, Greece, Portugal, Ireland 10

5

5

8

0

0

6

–10 –15 –20

Ireland Iceland Mexico Finland Japan Slovenia Hungary Denmark Sweden Greece Italy Germany UK Czech Republic Netherlands Austria Norway Spain U.S. Belgium France Portugal Canada New Zealand

–5

–5

Ireland

U.S.

4

–10

2

–15

0

–20

-2

Iceland

Greece

Denmark Hungary Czech Republic Sweden Canada Finland Slovenia France New Zealand Italy Austria Portugal Norway Mexico Japan Belgium Netherlands Germany

U.K.

0 Notes: GDP is measured from country-specific peak to country-specific trough. Unemployment is measured over the same period as GDP. Sources: International Monetary Fund;Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).

Spain

1 2 3 Overall strictness of employment protection

Note: Unemployment is measured over country-specific GDP peak and trough. Employment protection is averaged from 2005 to 2008. Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).

4

ship ignores the variance in the severity of the recession across countries. To understand how the severity of the recession interacted with the degree of employment protection, we plot the change in the unemployment rate against the decline in GDP and calculate a trend line for each of the two types of countries, rigid and flexible (figure 3). The flexible countries exhibit labor markets whose responses vary with the depth of the GDP decline: The more severe contractions are associated with larger increases in the observed unemployment rate. In the rigid countries, when GDP reductions increase in severity, the labor market does not recalibrate accordingly. One should interpret these results cautiously because a small sample for a particular episode does not necessarily generalize to other episodes. Nevertheless, this casual correlation suggests that, in countries with relatively strict employment protection, increasingly large declines in GDP fail to yield additional increases in the unemployment rate. Labor Market Rigidity and Unemployment: Long-Term Evidence Do we see higher unemployment rates in countries with more rigid labor markets over the long run? Coming into the 1980 recession, the EU-15 countries actually maintained an unemployment rate lower than that of the U.S. However, coming out of the recession, unemployment in those countries remained elevated, whereas the U.S. experienced a cyclical decline and return to trend. Since then, EU-15 unemployment has been trending around 3 percentage points higher than the U.S. (see figure 4). Economists attribute some of this divergence to the so-called “skill-biased technical changes” that occurred throughout the 1980s, along with labor-market rigidities (Blanchard, 2006; Ljungqvist and Sargent, 2008). Skillbiased technical change is a shift in production technology that favors skilled over unskilled labor by increasing its relative productivity and, therefore, its relative demand. In the face of skill-biased technical change, recently displaced workers face the prospect of large human capital losses. Because generous unemployment benefits tend to increase the duration of unemployment spells, they may exacerbate human capital losses. One artifact of a rigid labor market is the prevalence of long-term unemployment, which contributes to an elevated trend unemployment rate in the long run. The U.S. and EU-15 labor markets have drastically different shares of long-term unemployed workers (figure 5). The share rose steadily throughout the 1970s and 1980s in the EU and has remained elevated. While the share has been trending up slightly in the U.S., the majority of the unemployed are short term. For workers, skill-biased technical change might mean that the rate of skills depreciation accelerates during periods of unemployment, so long-term unemployment is particularly damaging. Increasingly, rapid technological change is difficult for unemployed workers in any type of

Figure 3. Changes in GDP and Unemployment Percentage point change in unemployment rate 12 10

Rigid countries Flexible countries

Spain

Ireland

8

Flexible countries

6

Greece Canada Iceland U.S. Czech Republic Hungary New U.K. Denmark Rigid countries Zealand Sweden Austria France Mexico Finland Italy Norway Japan Portugal Germany Slovenia Belgium Netherlands

4 2 0 –2 0

5

10 Percent decline in GDP

15

Notes: GDP is measured from country-specific peak to country-specific trough. Unemployment is measured over the same period as GDP. Sources: International Monetary Fund;Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).

Figure 4. Unemployment Rate 12 EU-15 10 8 U.S. 6 4 2 0 1970

1976

1982

1988

1994

2000

2006

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions. Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).

Figure 5. Unemployed One Year or More Percent of total unemployed 60 EU-15 50 40 30 20 U.S. 10 0 1975

1981

1987

1993

1999

2005

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions. Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Research Department P.O. Box 6387 Cleveland, OH 44101

PRSRT STD U.S. Postage Paid Cleveland, OH Permit No. 385

Return Service Requested: Please send corrected mailing label to the above address. Material may be reprinted if the source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted material to the editor at the address above.

labor market. Skill-based technical change, combined with a rigid labor market, creates a particularly precarious situation for the long-term unemployed. For instance, generous unemployment benefits might inadvertently enable workers to stay unemployed longer than they would otherwise have done. But as these displaced workers stay unemployed longer, they lose more human capital and valuable skills because of technical change. This loss in turn makes them less desirable to potential employers.

these flows over short and long time horizons, institutions play a nontrivial role in the labor market. In the short term, rigid labor markets may help prevent spikes in the unemployment rate, but they tend to keep trend unemployment higher than flexible labor markets in the long term. Therefore, when examining labormarket performance, the effect of these institutions on both long- and short-term dynamics should be taken into account. References “European Unemployment: The Evolution of Facts and Ideas,” by Olivier Blanchard. Center for Economic Policy Research, Economic Policy, vol. 21, no. 45 (January 2006).

In the past decade, some EU countries have instituted labormarket reforms (partly reflected in their declining values in the employment protection index), which may help to account for some of the decline in their unemployment rates. For example, Portugal’s initial employment protection rating was 4.15, but it has gradually decreased to 3.15. Italy had an initial reading in 1985 of 3.57, but currently it is 1.89. Finland and Greece also have lower employment protection rankings now than they did in the mid1980s. At the same time, some countries, like the UK, Ireland, and France, increased their protection as measured by the index.

“Two Questions about European Unemployment,” by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas J. Sargent. Econometrica, vol. 76, no. 1 (January 2008).

Conclusion Movements of workers in and out of jobs, which we call jobfinding and separation flows, determine to some extent the path of the unemployment rate in any given economy. By affecting

“Unemployment after the Recession: A New Natural Rate?” by Murat Tasci and Saeed Zaman. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentary, no. 2010-11 (September 2010).

“Long-Term Changes in Labor Supply and Taxes: Evidence from OECD Countries, 1956–2004,” by Lee E. Ohanian, Richard Rogerson, and Andrea Raffo. 2008. Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 55 (2008).

Murat Tasci is a research economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and Mary Zenker is a research analyst at the Bank.The views they express here are theirs and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or Board staff. Economic Commentary is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request to [email protected] or fax it to 216.579.3050. Economic Commentary is also available on the Cleveland Fed’s Web site at www.clevelandfed.org/research.

Labor Market Rigidity, Unemployment, and the Great Recession

Jun 29, 2011 - reducing the return from market work, labor-income taxes .... Economic Commentary is published by the Research Department of the Federal ...

460KB Sizes 0 Downloads 271 Views

Recommend Documents

Labor Market Rigidity, Unemployment, and the Great Recession - Core
Jun 29, 2011 - sample. Correspondingly, its unemployment rate response is one of the strongest on the chart. The trend line suggests a somewhat negative .... placed workers face the prospect of large human capital losses. Because generous unemploymen

Labor Market Rigidity, Unemployment, and the Great ... - CiteSeerX
Jun 29, 2011 - insurance, severance pay, advance notice, labor taxes, and so on. The observed unemployment .... the European Union before May 2004). Economic theory suggests that .... Economic Commentary is published by the Research Department of the

The Labor Market in the Great Recession
ing the distinctive severity of the downturn, recent data have seen the outflow rate reach ...... Figure 15 addresses this question by presenting time series for a range of outflow ...... In fields where good labor is scarce, vacancies may stay unfil

Wage Rigidity and Labor Market Dynamics in Europe ...
Sep 8, 2009 - eral equilibrium business cycle model with search frictions in the labor market, .... imprecise degree of wage rigidity for new hires. 3 ...

THE GREAT RECESSION IN THE UK LABOUR MARKET
unemployment, GDP in the UK has fallen by 6 per ..... rise in the inflow rate into unemployment plus the .... 6. Actual vs. flow steady-state unemployment rates.

Unemployment compensation finance and labor market ...
model of a rigid labor market that includes firing costs, temporary jobs and a minimum wage in order ..... However, computing a wage-posting equilibrium in a.

Uncertainty and the Great Recession
Jun 7, 2017 - Economic Experts, email: [email protected]; ... shocks on GDP growth and the unemployment rate during the Great ..... blue shaded areas: 68% and 95% confidence bands, respectively, constructed using a recursive design w

The Great Depression and the Great Recession
conducting an open market sale of securities because excess reserves .... were dominated by financial systems in which a small number of very large banks ... countries in South America and Central Europe accumulated mismatches ... business leaders on

Unemployment Insurance and Labor Reallocation!
Sorbonne. Email: franck.malherbet@uni%bocconi.it, Address: Via Salasco 5, 20136 Milano,. Italy. ..... mass of the unemployed workers or the mass of vacant jobs is nil. The instan% .... will choose the sector in which they will be best off.

Reconstructing the Great Recession
interlinkages account for a large share of the actual changes in aggregate employment and .... accounts for a significant share of growth of employment (between 29 and 61 percent) and GDP. (between 8 percent and ... market failures and price-adjustme

Understanding the Great Recession!
Aug 18, 2014 - Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person ... that the model does reasonably well at accounting for the dynamics of twelve ... for the relatively small decline in inflation with only a moderate ..... In ad

Understanding the Great Recession
Aug 25, 2014 - Model must provide empirically plausible account of: ñ standard macro- and labor market data. Novel features of labor market ñ Endogenize labor force participation. ñ Derive wage inertia as an equilibrium outcome. Estimate model usi

Financial Shocks, Firm Credit and the Great Recession
Sep 18, 2017 - We start with a real business cycle model and add (i) a financial friction that ...... independent coffee shop and Starbucks would be impacted.

Hiring Policies, Labor Market Institutions, and Labor ...
workers across existing jobs to obtain better matches between workers ... Arizona State, Maryland, Wharton, Toronto, California at San Diego, Texas, and. Rice for comments. Rogerson acknowledges support from the National Science. Foundation. ... ploy

The (un)importance of geographical mobility in the Great Recession
Stanford University, Economics Department, 579 Serra Mall, Stanford, CA ... years, measure job-related mobility more carefully, and account for the fact that ...

Trade and Labor Market Dynamics - CiteSeerX
Aug 25, 2015 - Taking a dynamic trade model with all these features to the data, and ...... Appliance (c14); Transportation Equipment (c15); Furniture and ...

Heterogeneous Information and Labor Market ...
†Email: [email protected]. 1 .... 4In the benchmark calibration, firm-specific shocks are also slightly more persistent than aggregate shocks. Since hiring decisions ...

Labor and Market Economy.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Labor and ...

Labor market and search through personal contacts
May 3, 2012 - Keywords: Labor market; unemployment; job search; social network. ..... link between workers in time period t is formed with probability. 10 ...

Heterogeneous Information and Labor Market ...
eliminate this discrepancy between the data and model-predicted movements. ..... Substituting in (5), integrating over all i and ignoring the constant terms ...... In practice, the ability of an individual firm to forecast conditions in the labor mar

Growth and Labor Market Composition
Sep 11, 2017 - workers earn a positive return for staying at the same firm for additional .... from the Labor Force Survey, whose survey design is similar to that of the .... They conclude that in Japan starting a career as a temporary worker has a.

Fraternities and Labor Market Outcomes
Jan 7, 2011 - Estimation. Conclusion. Fraternities. We study the situation where productivity irrelevant activity is job market relevant. Fraternity membership is more than "club good": too expensive; many people mention them on resumes. Sergey V. Po

Inter-generational Redistribution in the Great Recession
Sep 28, 2010 - The SCF is the best source of micro data on the assets and ... two-thirds of business, farm or self-employment income, social .... on data from Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac) shows much smaller declines in house values.

Nominal Wage Rigidity in Village Labor Markets
thank Prasanta Nayak for outstanding field assistance and Lakshmi Iyer for sharing the World Bank data. This project .... 5A notable exception is Card (1990), who examines union workers whose nominal wages are explic- itly indexed to ... such explana