International risk sharing and the transmission of productivity shocks Quantitative issues

Giancarlo Corsetti

March 2013

Introduction

• In the previous lecture we have seen that the market allocations in standard open economy models (specialization in production, CES consumption aggregator, home bias in consumption) tend to be very similar under complete and incomplete markets, for values of the trade elasticity that are not far from unity, on either side (or more generally, in a region around (DGAP ) in which  is not far from 2a1 (2aH +   1) on either side) – regardless H of the persistence of shocks.

• This is because, in that region of trade elasticities, terms of trade tend to provide automatic insurance against productivity risk, whether or not financial markets are complete.

• The allocation with complete/incomplete markets look considerably dierent however if either

— trade elasticities are low enough or — trade elasticities are suciently large and shocks are suciently persistent (or non stationary).

• In what follows, we reconsider the transmission mechanism analyzed in the analytical lecture (and the main conclusions above) in a quantitative framework with production, capital accumulation, traded and non-traded goods (flexible prices). The model is in Corsetti, Dedola Leduc (2008).

1

International business cycle: key stylized facts

Evidence on the international business cycle: US versus the rest of the industrial world (EU, Japan and Canada), 1970-2001. Data (as well as artificial time series) are HP (Hodrick-Prescott) filtered. Output Consumption Investment and Employment • all positively correlated across countries: correlation US vs. OECD-average: Y(.68), C(.6), I(.25), E(.54) • Consumption is less correlated than output (.6 vs. .68) – most IRBC models predicts the opposite: this is one essential dimension of the so called ‘quantity puzzle’.

Net Export • Correlation between real (constant price) net export and GDP is negative (-.48).

— Note real net exports are countercyclical independently of changes in the value of net exports due to equilibrium movements in the terms of trade, i.e. X-M versus NX(=X-TOT*M)/P. • Volatility (standard deviation) of Import ratio (ratio of import to nonexported tradable output) is 4.94; Volatility of net export over GDP is .64.

— A possible issue with calibrating a low elasticity is that imports may become too smooth.

International price volatility: level and ranking

• Real exchange rates (RER) is more volatile than Terms of trade (TOT).

— Relative to St.Dev. of GDP, the st.dev. of RER and TOT is 3.90 and 1.68. — Ranking is dicult to match in most models

• RER and TOT are positively correlated (.86)

Correlation between relative consumption and RER (Backus-Smith-Kollmann)

• Correlation is negative (-.71). • Same pattern emerges with the TOT (-.74).

— This is at odds with model predicting high risk sharing, unless marginal utility is assumed to vary randomly (taste shocks).

Correlation between relative output and RER/TOT is also negative (-.19; -.33)

Nominal and real exchange rate and local-currency prices • Nominal and real exchange rates are highly correlated (.9-1) • Correlation between nominal (real) ER and TOT is positive. • Correlation between nominal exchange rate and import prices is positive but not perfect (.4)

— Exchange rate pass-through on import prices incomplete • Correlation between nominal exchange rates and the CPI is close to zero or negative (local currency price stability).

Standard deviation relative to GDP

Standard deviation (a) relative to GDP Consumption Investment Employment

0.94 4.33 1.19

(b) absolute (in percent) Import ratio Real net exports / GDP

4.94 0.64

Cross-correlations Between Foreign and Home GDP Consumption Investment Employment between real net exports and GDP

0.68 0.60 0.25 0.54 -0.48

RER TOT nontradables price

3.90 1.68 0.86

Cross-correlations Between RER and Relative GDPs Relative consumptions Real net exports Terms of trade

-0.19 -0.71 0.60 0.52

Between TOT and Relative GDPs Relative consumptions Real net exports

-0.33 -0.74 0.67

2

Model (Corsetti Dedola Leduc 2008) • 2 symmetric countries each specialized in the production of a traded and nontraded good (YH, YN and YF, YN) • One pure-discount bond (incomplete asset markets). Without loss of generality, this is denominated in home currency – the model is real: currencies only provide units of account. • Firms either produce goods or distribute them: Perfectly competitive firms in both sectors • Bringing one unit of traded goods to consumer requires  units of a the nontraded good: Leontief technology

Firms: intermediate good sector Firms in the traded and nontraded goods sectors choose labor and capital to maximize profit:  H = P H,tYH,t  WtLH,t  RtKH,t  N = PN,tYN,t  WtLN,t  RtKN,t,

where a bar denotes wholesale prices, and 1  LH 1  ZNKN LN,

YH = ZHKH YN =

Firms: distribution Firms in the distribution sector buy traded intermediate goods and distribute them to consumers using nontraded goods (services) in fixed proportions. There is no value added in the process. Consumers thus pay PH,t = P H,t + PN,t. PF,t = P F,t + PN,t.

Investment goods versus consumption goods As opposed to consumer goods, investment goods require no distribution service. In the baseline calibration, investment only requires domestically produced inputs. In a variant of the model, investment requires also imports.

Households preferences and budget constraint

E

Ct  CT =

h h

1'

aT

(a H )

8 1
: t=0

U [Ct, `t] exp 4

1'

CT,t' + aN

1



2

t1 X

 =0

CN,t'

(CH ) + ( a F )

i1

1

'

39 = 5  (Ct, `t) ;

' < 1,

,

i1   (C F ) ,

 < 1 with ! = 1/ (1  )

PH,tCH,t + PF,tCF,t + PN,tCN,t + BH,t+1 + P H,tIH,t  Wt`t + RtKt + (1 + rt)BH,t. Kt+1 = IH,t + (1   )Kt.

General arguments for modelling distribution services

1. Evidence on distributive trade is pervasive (see Burstein et al. 2002)

2. Local costs can account for a low elasticity of consumer prices with respect to the exchange rate: Posit that the law of one price holds at the dock, P F,t = EP F,t. Then @PF,t/PF,t @P F,t/P F,t

=

1 P F,t + PN,t

the larger the share of distribution, the lower this elasticity.

3. Distributive trade helps addressing the quantity puzzle via ‘complementarity’: a correlated increase in the consumption of tradables across borders triggers an increase in the production of non-tradables (required to provide distribution services) in both countries.

4. Moreover, to the extent that the elasticity of substitution between tradable goods and distribution services is lower than one (the Cobb-Douglas case), distribution has also important implications for the trade elasticity. Because of distribution costs, the relative price of imports in terms of Home exports at the consumer level does not coincide with the terms of trade P F,t/P H,t– as in most standard models: PF,t

P F,t + PN,t

1  aH = = PH,t aH P H,t + PN,t

CH,t CF,t

!1

!

(1)

Define the distribution margin in steady state: P µ= N PH

By log-linearizing, we get:

\ T OTt =

  1 d Cd  C H,t F,t ! (1  µ)

(2)

where the terms of trade T OT is measured at the producer-price level so that ! (1  µ) can be thought of as the producer price elasticity of tradables. Clearly, both ! and µ impinge on the magnitude of the international transmission of country-specific shocks through the equilibrium changes in the terms of trade. A low trade elasticity does not necessarily imply strong complementarity in preferences or production.

A specific potential advantage of modelling non tradables and distribution Consumer price level is quite insulated from exchange rate movements, and the model may fit the ranking of volatility between RER and TOT 





c  d \t = (1  µ) (2aH  1) T \ b RER OTt + µ Pd N,t  PN,t +  qt  qt



(3)

where 0 <  < 1 and qt represents the relative price of non-tradables. The expression decomposes the movements of RER into movements in TOT terms of trade and in the relative price of non-traded goods. Clearly if µ = 0 (absent distribution, i.e. no wedge between producer and consumer prices) and  = 0 (absent movements in the price of non-tradables across countries, the model would not replicate the empirical ranking of volatility.

Incomplete asset markets and endogenous discount factor If markets are complete, relative wealth is constant and the model has a unique steady state. With incomplete markets, without some additional assumptions, the wealth distribution in the deterministic steady state would be indeterminate and the first-order approximation around it would contain a unit root. In turn, this unit root would imply that the wealth distribution in the approximate solution to the stochastic economy does not converge to a stationary distribution. All this despite the stationarity of the shocks. Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe [2003] discusses several alternative ways to ensure that the model has a unique steady state in spite of incomplete markets: costs of holding bonds (e.g. Heatcoate and Perri [2003]), borrowing constraint (e.g. CKM), and endogenous discount factor (e.g. Mendoza and this model).

3

Calibration

 Distribution costs = 50% of consumer prices (Burstein, Neves, & Rebelo [2002]) aH Imports = 5% of GDP (average of US data 1960-2002) – HOME BIAS is high aT Nontraded goods = 53% of consumption as in US data

1/ (1  ') Tradables/nontradables elasticity of substitution set to 0.74 (Mendoza [1991])  Utility is CRRA, with coecient of relative risk aversion equal to 2

3.1

Fundamental uncertainty: productivity and taste shocks

Productivity: Consistent with our model and other open-economy studies (e.g., Backus, Kehoe and Kydland [1995]), we identify technology shocks with Solow residuals in each sector, using annual data in manufacturing and services from the OECD STAN database. Since hours are not available for most other OECD countries, we use sectoral data on employment.

• Disturbances to technology are assumed to follow a trend-stationary AR(1) process 0

Z = Z + u,

(4)

 }0 , u  (u , u , u , u ) with variance-covariance where Z  {ZH, ZF, ZN, ZN H F N N matrix V (u), and  is a 4x4 matrix of coecients describing the autocorrelation properties of the shocks. Since the economic structure is assumed symmetric across countries, the autocorrelation and variance-covariance matrices of the above sectoral process is also assumed to be symmetric. Shocks may be correlated contemporaneously (via u), or may have spillover eects on other countries/sectors via the o-diagonal elements of . This is what accounts for the global component of shocks, either contemporaneous or with a transmission with lags.

• AR coecient is .82 for tradables, .96 for nontradables; • notable positive spillovers from nontradables shocks.

In a variant of the model, productivity shocks are assumed to be symmetric also across sectors, i.e. Z  {Z, Z }0 – labelled ‘macro shocks’. • Taste shocks are calibrated following Stockman and Tesar [1995], assuming that they are uncorrelated across countries and have a standard deviation and serial correlation equal to the largest between the two productivity shocks, 0.0089 and 0.961, respectively.

The model is run with productivity shocks only (IRBC) or with both shocks at the same time.

Issues in calibration: elasticity of substitution In previous lecture, we have seen that the behavior of the model hinges crucially on the elasticity of substitution. However, there is considerable uncertainty about aggregate trade elasticities: U.S. estimates range from 0.4 to 2.5 (see Hooper et al. 2000). Micro studies point to even larger values. 2 calibration strategies suggested by theoretical considerations in first lecture:

1. set elasticity in the model as to match a set of moments

2. set high values from trade studies and analyze the implications of persistent shocks.

3.2

Calibrating !: first approach

Suppose one set tradables elasticity of substitution ! to match RER volatility relative to output, which in the US is:  (RER) = 3 .9  (Y )

Consistent with theory, one gets low values of ! . However, the calibration will not be unique: there will be two (low) values for ! matching the condition, implying two dierent transmission mechanisms: (a) positive for the higher value (b) negative for the lower value. Need to use additional moments.

Calibrating ! matching volatility and trade flows Simulated method of moments: choose ! to minimize the distance, between model and data, of the following (equally weighed) four moments: (i) the volatility of the real exchange rate, (ii) the volatility of the terms of trade, (iii) the correlation between the real exchange and the output ratio, and (iv) the correlation between the real exchange rate and net exports. Note: GMM estimators remains unbiased and consistent, even if an optimal weighting matrix is not used – see the textbook by Greene [1997], page 525.

Rationale • Matching the first two moments, addresses the following issue: do large international price movements amplify wealth eects and the consumption risk of productivity shocks? It may well be possible that volatility in the data is not high enough to generate the mechanism illustrated in the first lecture. • There are two transmission mechanisms through which price volatility can generate low risk sharing: the third moment helps discriminating between the two. • Including the fourth moment mimics the comovements between relative prices and intertemporal trade in the data.

Estimated low elasticity The procedure yields an estimate of ! equal to 0.85.

• Given the calibrated value of µ, the implied trade price elasticity is below 1/2, well within the range of available macro estimates, but at odds with some micro evidence.

3.3

Calibrating !: Second approach

The first lecture showed that strong relative wealth eects driving a wedge between the complete-markets and the incomplete-markets allocation could be generated by persistent shocks, provided the elasticity is suciently high. In a second calibration, set the trade elasticity equal to 4 based on the estimates in the trade literature, namely, by Bernard, Eaton, Jensen, and Kortum [2003]. Given the size of the distribution sector, this means ! = 8.

Calibrating a high ! with low and high persistence of shocks

• Not surprisingly, with ! = 8, the data-based estimated shocks are not persistent enough to generate strong wealth eects.

• The model is then run raising the persistence of the process driving tradables productivity shocks to 0.99, while shutting down technological spillovers to keep the process stationary. As a check,also assume a macro shock with high persistence (as in Baxter 1995).

4

Results (low elasticity, estimated shocks) • Model: First-order Taylor series expansion around the deterministic steady state. The model is simulated using King and Watson [1998]’s algorithm. Model’s statistics are computed by logging and filtering the model’s artificial time series using the HP filter and averaging moments across 100 simulations. Consistently with the data, changes in all real aggregate variables (e.g. GDP) are computed using constant (steady-state) prices. • The table below reports the results for the first calibration of the model, with a relatively low trade elasticity (<1/2). The table reports the data, and statistics for the baseline with incomplete and complete markets (bond economy and Arrow Debreu), and for the baseline augmented with taste shocks.

Low elasticity Standard shocks

Data

Baseline Bond Arrow-Debreu Economy Economy

Baseline with taste shocks Bond Arrow-Debreu Economy Economy

Standard deviation relative to GDP RER TOT nontradables price

3.90 1.68 0.86

2.99 2.42 0.77

0.73 0.83 0.51

2.94 2.45 0.76

0.99 1.07 0.48

-0.19 -0.71 0.60 0.52

-0.54 -0.24 0.96 0.99

0.21 0.98 -0.62 0.16

-0.55 -0.30 0.93 0.99

-0.28 -0.29 0.57 0.59

-0.33 -0.74 0.67

-0.55 -0.27 0.97

0.87 0.31 0.63

-0.56 -0.40 0.97

0.11 -0.54 0.82

Cross-correlations Between RER and Relative GDPs Relative consumptions Real net exports Terms of trade

Between TOT and Relative GDPs Relative consumptions Real net exports

Low Elasticity Standard Shocks

Data

Baseline Bond Arrow-Debreu Economy Economy

Baseline with Taste Shocks Bond Arrow-Debreu Economy Economy

Standard deviation (a) relative to GDP Consumption Investment Employment

0.94 4.33 1.19

0.48 3.20 0.53

0.48 3.21 0.52

0.53 3.13 0.59

0.67 2.91 0.85

4.94 0.64

1.62 0.17

0.55 0.03

1.63 0.18

0.81 0.13

0.68 0.60 0.25 0.54 -0.48

0.38 0.30 0.45 0.45 -0.38

0.39 0.37 0.45 0.49 0.21

0.38 0.16 0.45 0.35 -0.39

0.33 -0.01 0.44 0.16 -0.28

(b) absolute (in percent) Import ratio Real net exports / GDP

Cross-correlations Between Foreign and Home GDP Consumption Investment Employment between real net exports and GDP

• RER and TOT volatility is high (by calibration strategy)

— ‘high volatility’ is not necessarily evidence that the exchange rate is ‘disconnected’ from fundamentals.

• Negative Backus-Smith correlation between C/C  and RER

— not perfect per eect of intertemporal trade: negative on impact, positive over time. — Also, C/C  and Y /Y  are negatively correlated with T OT .

• RER more volatile than TOT

— TOT and RER are positively correlated, as in the data. — Volatility of the price of nontradables in the ball park

• High correlation of output driven by 2 factors

— positive correlation of innovations (mostly) — negative transmission mechanism: the Home TOT appreciation produce a negative wealth eect abroad, which make foreign consumers supply more labor and thus increases foreign output. This eect is however stronger at sectoral level, than in the aggregate.

• Consumption correlation remains positive because of cross-border spillovers, despite negative transmission

• Output is more correlated than consumption (complementarities due to distribution help)

• Real net exports are countercyclical. • Import ratio is not very volatile but comparable with standard models: with incomplete markets, a low elasticity does not reduce volatility.

5

Results (high elasticity, persistent shocks) • Standard AR shocks are not persistent enough to generate strong wealth eects. • Raising the autoregressive coecient close to .99 (while shutting down crosscountry spillovers) creates strong wealth eects (BS correlation is -.12), provided trade elasticity is large enough (above 4). • Dynamics adjustment of output (hump shaped) and TOT and RER (appreciation is followed by depreciation). • Model performance comparable to first calibration, except no volatility in international prices

High elasticity Persistent shocks

Data

Tradable Shocks Bond Arrow-Debreu Economy Economy

Aggregate Shocks Bond Economy

Standard deviation relative to GDP Real exchange rate Terms of trade Relative price of nontradables

3.90 1.68 0.86

1.60 0.70 0.67

0.95 0.50 0.55

0.35 0.39 0.06

Between real exchange rate and Relative GDPs Relative consumptions Real net exports Terms of trade

-0.19 -0.71 0.60 0.52

-0.55 -0.12 0.87 0.90

-0.21 0.97 -0.01 0.12

-0.69 -0.67 0.96 0.99

Between terms of trade and Relative GDPs Relative consumptions Real net exports

-0.33 -0.74 0.67

-0.66 -0.33 0.98

0.81 0.31 0.99

-0.71 -0.69 0.97

Cross-correlations

High elasticity Persistent shocks Data

Tradable shocks Bond Arrow-Debreu Economy Economy

Aggregate shocks Bond Economy

Standard deviation relative to GDP Consumption Investment Employment

0.94 4.33 1.19

0.58 2.86 0.30

0.48 2.86 0.49

0.76 1.90 0.2

4.94 0.64

3.63 0.30

2.91 0.16

1.25 0.12

0.68 0.60 0.25 0.54 -0.48

0.46 -0.01 0.28 0.80 -0.39

0.18 0.16 0.03 -0.43 0.50

0.28 0.17 0.03 0.54 -0.49

absolute (in percent) Import ratio Real net exports over GDP

Cross-correlations Between foreign and domestic GDP Consumption Investment Employment Between real net exports and GDP

6

Conclusions • Evidence that international consumption risk sharing is limited. Need for international business cycle models to account for possible large, uninsurable wedges between domestic and foreign wealth following shocks to fundamentals

• Equilibrium allocation in many standard specifications is not significantly away from the complete-market benchmark: the Backus-Smith puzzle is a crucial dimension to assess the performance of business cycle models.

Avenues of research ...

• Strong wealth eects from low trade elasticities • Persistent shocks with high trade elasticities

— hump-shaped output, or ‘news shocks’, or investment-specific shocks

• Distinguishing between short-run versus long-run elasticities. Dierent approaches: Firm Entry (Ruhl), Nested elasticities (Cooley and Quadrini), Deep Habits (Ravn, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe), Costumers as capital (Drosz).

• Wealth eects from financial frictions within a country.

International risk sharing and the transmission of ...

International risk sharing and the transmission of productivity shocks. Quantitative .... Local costs can account for a low elasticity of consumer prices with respect.

200KB Sizes 1 Downloads 265 Views

Recommend Documents

International risk sharing and optimal monetary policy in a small ...
commodity-exporting economy and the rest of the world. One can think intuitively of two alternative setups. On the one hand, under the assumption of complete and frictionless asset markets, such an economy may be perfectly insured against foreign-com

International Risk Sharing During the Globalization Era1
Feb 22, 2011 - 2 Corresponding Author: Akito Matsumoto: Research Department; 700 19th ... globalization has not improved the degree of international risk sharing.4 .... in consumption growth rates may be achieved through technology ... improvement on

The International Risk Sharing Puzzle is at Business ...
gramme for Research and Technological Development. Support from the Pierre Werner ... development of international economics. Our results emphasize the ...

Heterogeneity and the Formation of Risk-Sharing ...
Jul 29, 2014 - of Economics, email: [email protected]. ..... The good being assumed non-storable, the time subscript is dropped in the sequel. 7 ...

Social Security and Risk Sharing
Feb 6, 2008 - effects of social security, on the prices of long-lived assets and the stock of capital, and ... of interest to investigate under what conditions a pay-as-you-go social ...... negatively correlated, or the endowment when old is also hig

Money, Bargaining, and Risk Sharing
(DM) money's main role is as a means of payment, while in the CM it is ..... across any two consecutive CMs is given by the state in the latter of the two CMs,.

An experimental investigation of risk sharing and ...
May 2, 2014 - Department of Economics (AE1) and Netspar, Maastricht University, P.O. Box 616, 6200 MD,. Maastricht, the Netherlands e-mail: ... such as health policies, unemployment policies and pension schemes. ..... It would be interesting to inves

Imperfect Monitoring and Informal Risk Sharing: The ...
is 39.2% the amount corresponding to full risk sharing. There is a great deal of heterogeneity in contracts, as can be seen in Figure 3 Panel A in which I show the ...

On the Interaction between Risk Sharing and Capital ...
Feb 5, 2007 - Email addresses: [email protected] (Martin Barbie), .... produced by the technology is the only good in the economy and is used for.

Risk Sharing, Investment, and Incentives in the ...
Therefore, capital accumulation and growth would be faster in an economy without perfect insurance than in one with perfect insurance. This article explores the tradeoffs between insurance and growth in the neoclassical growth model with two agents a

On the International Transmission of Technology Shocks
Oct 8, 2008 - prototypical international business cycle model under complete and incomplete financial markets, .... line with the standard transmission mechanism. ..... rental rate of capital in terms of the local intermediate good, the problem ...

International Financial Transmission of the Fed's ...
not necessarily represent those of the Swiss National Bank. †Nikola ... Dynamic response of the UK yield curve to the Fed funds rate decisions is es- timated to be .... takes into account the number of days in the month affected by the change is.

International Trade, Risk and the Role of Banks
No analysis of other bank trade finance products - documentary credit. Niepmann, Schmidt-Eisenlohr (Fed, UIUC) ... (risk channel - additional to working capital channel). Transmission of financial shocks ..... Introduce a random multiplicative shock

International Trade, Risk and the Role of Banks
International trade is risky and takes time. Optimal payment contracts, Schmidt-Eisenlohr (2013). Cash-in-advance. Open account. Letter of credit. Some evidence on cash-in-advance versus open account: Antras and Foley. (2011), Hoefele et al. (2012),

International Trade, Risk and the Role of Banks
Jun 1, 2015 - these questions by exploiting unique information from the Society for Worldwide ..... A DC provides less security to the exporter than an LC. ... data is available, SWIFT messages basically capture all trade paid for with LCs.

Does risk sharing increase with risk aversion and risk ...
measures of risk sharing introduced above, and verify that they co-move. .... This paper is based on a chapter of my doctoral thesis at the Toulouse School of Economics. ... International business cycles with endogenous incomplete markets.

4-Risk-Sharing Financing of Islamic Banks; Better Shielded Against ...
(Mirakhor, 2010; The Kuala Lumpur Decla- ration, 2012; Askari et al., 2012; Iqbal .... Financing of Islamic Banks; Better Shielded Against Interest Rate Risk.pdf.

Policy Cooperation, Incomplete Markets and Risk Sharing, by ... - IMF
My plan for this presentation. • My talk takes an unusual tack. • I will focus at first on the difficulties of the problem I have worked on. • Focusing on those serves to ...

Efficient Risk Sharing with Limited Commitment and ...
Keywords: risk sharing, limited commitment, hidden storage, dynamic contracts ...... case whenever the basic model does not display perfect risk sharing and the ...

Recursive Risk Sharing: Microfoundations for ...
Next we turn to character- izing the risk-sharing problem in a recursive utility setting using a log-linearizion. The solution to this problem lets us explore the pricing kernel and the implied representative agent preferences. 2 Recursive Utility Pa

profit and risk sharing in islamic finance
banking institution in the framework of an isolated and ideal Islamic economy: but, in the ... failures, asset depreciation, faulty regulation, illiquidity, macroeconomic shocks and ... sharia compliance in the European financial Service industry.

The-Risk-Pivot-Great-Powers-International-Security-And-The ...
Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. The-Risk-Pivot-Great-Powers-International-Security-And-The-Energy-Revolution.pdf. The-Risk-Pivot-Gre

Exchange Rate Regime and International Transmission ...
Keywords: Exchange rate regime, Business cycle co-movement, Capital account openness, .... 10 Studies like Clark and van Wincoop (2001) and Baxter and Kouparitsas (2005) support the positive effect of trade on business .... variables, making the numb