INFORMED-PRINCIPAL PROBLEM WITH MORAL HAZARD, RISK NEUTRALITY, AND NO LIMITED LIABILITY ¨ CHRISTOPH WAGNER, TYMOFIY MYLOVANOV, AND THOMAS TROGER Abstract. We consider a principal agent moral hazard problem with risk-neutral parties and no limited liability in which the principal has private information. The principal’s private information creates signaling considerations that may distort the implemented outcome. These distortions can explain, e.g., efficiency wages (Beaudry 1994) and muted incentives (Inderst 2001). We show that in a large class of environments these distortions vanish if the principal is allowed to offer sufficiently rich contracts.

1. Introduction In the standard principal-agent model, the principal has no private information and the optimal contract can be found solving a constrained optimization problem. If the principal has private information, the model becomes a signaling game and the contract’s value is determined endogenously in equilibrium. The signaling incentives introduce novel distortions, which may explain, e.g., efficiency wages (Beaudry 1994) and muted incentives (Inderst 2001). We consider a principal-agent model with risk-neutral parties and no limited liability in which the principal has private information (her type) about the technology translating the agent’s effort into observables (Beaudry (1994), Inderst (2001)). This environment is useful for understanding distortions that can be generated by the privacy of the principal’s information since the benchmark environment in which the principal has no private information features no distortions: the optimal contract is to “sell the firm” to the agent (see e.g. Grossman and Hart (1983), Proposition 3(2)). Under asymmetric information, the value of the firm is uncertain to the agent and the environment becomes that of the informed principal (Myerson 1983, Maskin and Tirole 1992). The model, however, differs from the literature because there exists an ex-post verifiable variable, e.g., profit, that is correlated both with the agent’s effort and the principal’s private information. In Section 3, we consider environments in which the first best effort is constant across the principal type and provide two logically independent sufficient conditions under which the first best can be implemented. These conditions are (1) the first-best Date: May 23, 2014. This work has greatly benefited from detailed comments by J¨org Budde, Paul Heidhues, Daniel Kr¨ ahmer, Dezso Szalay, and Venuga Yokeeswaran. We are also grateful to Rafael Aigner, Carsten Dahremoller, Deniz Dizdar, Markus Fels, Fabian Herweg, Sebastian Kranz, Matthias Lang, Patrick Rey, Christian Seel, Axel Stahmer, and Philipp Strack. 1

2

¨ CHRISTOPH WAGNER, TYMOFIY MYLOVANOV, AND THOMAS TROGER

effort is the most costly action for the agent and (2) a linear independence condition on the distribution of the ex-post verifiable variable, which is satisfied generically if the support of the variable is sufficiently large. In Section 4, we allow the first-best effort to vary with the principal’s type and show that the first best can be implemented if a stronger linear independence condition holds, which is still generically satisfied if the support of the ex-post verfiable variable is sufficiently large. This result stands in contrast with the results in Beaudry (1994) and Inderst (2001), in which these independence conditions are violated. The independence conditions holds if the dimensionality of the support of the ex-post verfiable variable is sufficiently large relative to the dimensionality of the type and effort spaces. Hence, the dimensionality is the key to the distortions that can be caused by the signaling considerations and, in sufficiently rich contractual environments, the privacy of the principal’s information does not impose any costs on the principal. This observation can manifest itself in other moral hazard environments and, thus, it might prove useful when developing applications. The result that the principal implements the same outcome regardless of whether her information is private or publicly known to the agent has been observed in other environments. It holds in independent private value environments with riskneutral players. (Myerson 1985, Maskin and Tirole 1990, Tan 1996, Yilankaya 1999, Balestrieri 2008, Skreta 2009, Mylovanov and Tr¨oger 2014) if payoff functions satisfy a montononicty condition (Mylovanov and Tr¨oger 2014). The contracts that attain the first best are strongly neologism-proof (Maskin and Tirole 1992, Mylovanov and Tr¨oger 2012): they extract the entire surplus conditional on each type of the principal and cannot be dominated by any other contract. Severinov (2008) offers a full surplus extraction informed principal result in environments with adverse selection, no moral hazard, and correlated types. Fleckinger (2007) presents a full surplus extraction result for an informed principal in an environment with adverse selection, no moral hazard, and countervailing incentives. In addition to Beaudry (1994) and Inderst (2001), the informed principal problem with moral hazard is studied in Jost (1996), Bond and Gresik (1997), Mezzetti and Tsoulouhas (2000), Chade and Silvers (2002), and Kaya (2010), Karle and Staatz (2013), and Fong and Lee (2013). These papers feature risk-averse players, allow for dynamic interaction, impose limited liability constraints, or introduce moral hazard on the part of the principal. 2. Model There is a principal (i = 0) and an agent (i = 1) who operate a firm. The principal has a type t which is a random variable with support on T = {t1 , . . . , tτ } and distribution λ0 = (λ1 , . . . , λτ ). The agent can choose effort a ∈ A = {a1 , . . . , am }, which determines the distribution of signal s with support on S = (s1 , . . . , sn ) ∈ Rn and distribution f (t, a) = (f1 (t, a), . . . , fn (t, a)) ∈ Rn . In addition, the parties can exchange a monetary payment w ∈ R from the principal to the agent. Principal type and agent action are private, signal and payment are public and verifiable.

INFORMED-PRINCIPAL PROBLEM WITH MORAL HAZARD

3

Parties are risk-neutral and have private values, with the payoff functions u0 (s, w) = π(s) − w, u1 (a, w) = w − c(a), where π(s) is the expected profit of the firm conditional on s and c(a) is the cost of effort a. If the players cannot agree on a mechanism, they obtain disagreement payoffs normalized to 0. This is without loss of generality since we can always subtract the disagreement payoffs from the payoffs from the basic outcomes. 2.1. First-best actions. Let a∗ (t) be the first-best action that maximizes the difference between expected firm profits f (t, a) · π and effort cost c(a)1 a∗ (t) := arg max f (t, a(t)) · π − c(a). A

Let U0∗ (t) = f (t, a∗ (t)) · π − c(a∗ (t)) denote the first-best payoff of the principal type t and let U∗0 = (U0∗ (t1 ), . . . , U0∗ (tτ )). We assume U∗0 ≥ 0, that is, each principal type generates a weakly positive surplus. In the benchmark environment without uncertainty about the principal’s type, each principal type can obtain U0∗ (t) by “selling the firm” to the agent. The contract makes the agent the residual claimant of the surplus by asking the agent to pay the principal the expected value of the firm, U0∗ (t), and transfers to the agent the property rights over the profits of the firm π. If the principal type is uncertain, selling the firm contract is not feasible because of adverse selection. The market can unravel, and the parties might fail to implement the efficient outcome (Inderst 2001). 2.2. The informed principal game. We consider a mechanism-selection game in which any mechanism as defined in Myerson (1983) may be proposed by the principal. The timing is as follows. After privately observing her type t, the principal offers a mechanism M . The agent decides whether or not to accept M . If M is accepted, then each player chooses her strategy (consisting of an action at each of her information sets; in particular, for the agent the strategy determines her choice of a ∈ A at each path of the play) in M , outcome s is realized, and payment w specified by M is implemented. If the agent rejects M , then the disagreement outcome is implemented. A perfect-Bayesian equilibrium for the mechanism-selection game specifies (i) for each type of the principal, an optimal (possibly randomized) mechanism proposal, (ii) for each mechanism, a belief about the principal’s type that is computed via Bayes rule if the mechanism is proposed by at least one type, and (iii) for each mechanism, a strategy-profile that is a sequential equilibrium in the continuation game that follows the proposal of the mechanism. 1For

simplicity, we assume that this action is unique; extension to multiple efficient actions poses no difficulty.

¨ CHRISTOPH WAGNER, TYMOFIY MYLOVANOV, AND THOMAS TROGER

4

2.3. Direct mechanisms. Equilibrium outcomes can be described by direct mechanisms. A direct mechanism ρ is a mapping from the principal’s announcements of her type into effort recommendation to the agent and the payment profile conditional on the realized signal and the recommended effort ρ(·) = (α(·), w(·)), α(·) : T0 → A, w(·) : T0 × A → Rn , where A is the set of probability distributions over A. With some abuse of notation, we use α(a|t) to denote the probability of recommending a after report t and w(s|a, t) to denote the payment conditional on signal s, recommendation a, and report t. Given a direct mechanism ρ, the expected payoff of type t of the principal if she announces type tˆ is denoted XX U0ρ (tˆ, t) = (π(s) − w(s|a, tˆ))fs (t, a)α(a|tˆ). A

S

Similarly, given a direct mechanism ρ and a belief λ about the principal, the expected payoff of the agent who chooses effort a ˆ if he is recommended to choose a is denoted XX α(a, t)λt U1ρ,λ (ˆ a, a) = −c(ˆ a) + w(s|a, t)fs (t, a ˆ) P . ˆ T α(a, t)λtˆ s T We will use shortcuts U0ρ (t) := U0ρ (tˆ, t) and U1ρ,λ (a) := U1ρ,λ (a, a). An allocation ρ is called λ-feasible if (i) truthful reporting by the principal and obedience by the agent are an equilibrium and (ii) the agent’s expected payoff is larger than or equal to zero ∀t, tˆ ∈ T : U0ρ (t) ≥ U0ρ (tˆ, t), (1) ∀a, a ˆ ∈ supp α(·) :

U1ρ,λ (a) ≥ U1ρ,λ (ˆ a, a), X X ρ,λ U1 (a)α(a|t)λt ≥ 0. T

(2) (3)

A

A mechanism is feasible if it is λ0 -feasible; that is, for prior beliefs we drop reference to λ. By the revelation principle, any equilibrium outcome can be represented by a feasible direct mechanism. 2.4. Strongly neologism-proof mechanism. Given mechanisms ρ and ρ0 and a belief λ, we say that ρ is λ-dominated by ρ0 if ρ0 is λ-feasible and 0

∀t ∈ supp(λ) :

U0ρ (t) ≥ U0ρ (t),

∃ t ∈ supp(λ) :

U0ρ (t) > U0ρ (t).

0

The domination is strict if “>” holds for all t ∈ supp(λ). Definition 1. A mechanism ρ is strongly neologism-proof if (i) ρ is feasible and (ii) ρ is not λ-dominated for any full support belief λ.2 2The

definition in (2012) includes provisions about types who obtain the highest feasible payoff. In our environment, there are no such types because payments can be arbitrarily high.

INFORMED-PRINCIPAL PROBLEM WITH MORAL HAZARD

5

Strong neologism-proofness is introduced in (Mylovanov and Tr¨oger 2012) and is a generalization of the concept of “strongly unconstrained Pareto optimal” (SUPO) allocations of Maskin and Tirole (1990). Clearly, if there exists λ-feasible mechanism with the first-best payoffs U0∗ for the principal, it is strongly neologism-proof. 2.5. Perfect Bayesian equilibrium. Mylovanov and Tr¨oger (2012), Proposition 1, show that strongly neologism-proof allocations are perfect-Bayesian equilibrium allocations. Their result is obtained for the environments without private actions; extending the argument to the environments in which the parties have private actions and the mechanism makes private recommendations is direct and omitted. Proposition 1 (Mylovanov and Tr¨oger (2012)). Any strongly neologism-proof mechanism describes a perfect-Bayesian equilibrium outcome of the mechanism-selection game. Corollary 1. If the first-best payoffs U∗0 are feasible in some direct mechanism, these payoffs can be obtained in a perfect-Bayesian equilibrium outcome of the mechanismselection game. 3. First best: single action In this section, we consider the environment in which the first-best action is independent of the principal’s type. A example of such an environment is a model with two levels of effort, shirking and working hard, in which working hard is efficient action for each principal type A = {0, 1} with f (t, 1) · π − c(1) > f (t, 0) · π − c(0) (t ∈ T ). The results below establish sufficient conditions for the existence of a perfect Bayesian equilibrium in which each principal type obtains her first-best payoff or, equivalently, existence of a feasible mechanism in which the agent undetakes the firstbest effort a∗ and is paid the expected wage of c(a∗ ). In order to illustrate our construction, let t ∈ arg minT U0∗ (t) be the principal type with the minimal value of the firm. We define a mechanism in which the principal sells the firm to the agent conditional on t = t by setting w(s|a, t) = c(a∗ )+π(s)−f (t, a∗ )·π and keeps the firm and pays a fixed wage w(s|a, t) = c(a∗ ) otherwise. This mechanism is incentive compatible for principal type t because she obtains her fist-best payoff regarldess of her report. It is also incentive compatible for all other types t 6= t because all reports tˆ 6= t yield the first-best payoff of U0∗ (t), while a deviation to tˆ = t sells the firm at the lower price of U0∗ (t). The mechanism is non-transparent for the agent in the sense that the agent cannot infer the type of the principal and, hence, the wage before choosing his from the mechanism’s recommendation to take action a∗ . The agent incentive constraints are satisfied with a slack conditional on type t and violated otherwise. It follows that if t is sufficiently likely, the mechanism is incentive compatible of the agent. Otherwise, the argument is more involved and includes “overselling” the firm conditional on type

6

¨ CHRISTOPH WAGNER, TYMOFIY MYLOVANOV, AND THOMAS TROGER

t such that the incentive constraints for the agent conditonal on this type are satisfied with a sufficiently large slack. The proof of Proposition 2 extends this construction by allowing general contracts that generate slack in the agent’s incentive constraints in addition to “sell the firm” contract. Proposition 2. Assume that the first-best effort is constant in type, a∗ (t) = a∗ and that there exists type t and vector k = (k1 , . . . , kn ) such that f (t, a∗ ) · k = 0, f (t, a∗ ) · k ≥ 0 for all t 6= t, and f (t, a) · k < 0 for all a 6= a∗ . Then, there exists a perfect Bayesian equilibrium in which each principal type obtains her first-best payoff. Proof. Consider direct mechanism ρ that always recommends action a∗ and pays ( c(a∗ ) + γk(s), if t = t; w(s|a∗ , t) = c(a∗ ), otherwise, where γ > 0 is some positive number to be determined. By definition of k, we have f (t, a∗ ) · k = 0, implying f (t, a∗ ) · w(a∗ , t) = c(a∗ ). Hence, the mechanism satisfies agent’s participation constraint (3) and implements the first-best payoff U∗0 . The mechanism satisfies incentive compatibility constraints for the principal (1). Indeed, type t obtains the same payoff regardless of he report, U0ρ (t, tˆ) = f (t, a∗ ) · π − c(a∗ ) = U0∗ (t) = U0ρ (t). For types t 6= t, (1) writes f (t, a∗ ) · (π − c(a∗ )) ≥ f (t, a∗ ) · (π − w(a∗ , t)) or, equivalently, (f (t, a∗ ) − f (t, a∗ )) · w(a∗ , t) = γf (t, a∗ ) · k ≥ 0. where the last inequality holds by definition of k. The agent’s payoff from following the recommendation of the mechanism is equal to 0, while the payoff from choosing any effort a 6= a∗ is X (4) f (t, a) · w(a∗ , t) − c(a) = c(a∗ ) − c(a) + γλt f (t, a) · k T ∗

A c(a) Since f (t, a) · k < 0 by definition of k, setting γ > c(aλt)−min ensures that the |f (t,a)·k| expression in (4) is non-positive, (2) is satisfied, and mechanism ρ is feasible.

Corollary 2. Assume that the first-best effort is constant in type and is the most costly action for the agent, i.e., a∗ (t) = a∗ and c(a∗ ) ≥ c(a) for all a ∈ A. Then, there exists a perfect Bayesian equilibrium in which each principal type obtains her first-best payoff.

INFORMED-PRINCIPAL PROBLEM WITH MORAL HAZARD

7

Proof. Let t ∈ arg minT U0∗ (t) be a type with the lowest amount of surplus and define k(s) = π(s) − f (t, a∗ ) · π.3 By construction, f (t, a∗ ) · k = 0. Furthermore, f (t, a∗ ) · k = (f (t, a∗ ) − f (t, a∗ )) · π ≥ 0 by definition of t. Finally, f (t, a) · k = (f (t, a) − f (t, a∗ )) · π < 0 by assumption that a∗ is the unique first-best action and c(a) ≤ c(a∗ ). Thus, the conditions of Proposition 2 are satisfied. Corollary 3. If the first-best effort a∗ (t) = a∗ is constant in type and there exists t ∈ T such that vectors {f (t, a∗ )}t∈T and {f (t, a)}a∈A\{a∗ } are linearly independent, there exists a perfect Bayesian equilibrium in which each principal type obtains her first-best payoff. Proof. Fix  > 0 and consider the system of linear equations in k f (t, a∗ ) · k = 0, t ∈ T, and f (t, a) · k = , a ∈ A\{a∗ }. By assumption, vectors {f (t, a∗ )}t∈T and {f (t, a)}a∈A\{a∗ } are linearly independent and therefore there exists a solution. By construction, the solution satisfies the conditions of Proposition 2. Observe that a necessary condition for linear independence of vectors {f (t, a∗ )}t∈T and {f (t, a)}a∈A\{a∗ } is that n ≥ τ + m − 1. 4. First best: different actions In this section, we allow for the first-best effort to vary in type and assume it is distinct for each principal type. Therefore, in any mechanism that implements the first best, the agent will infer the principal type after the effort recommendation and, unlike in the case of a constant first-best effort considered in the previous section, the principal cannot exploit uncertainty about the wage in order to relax the agent’s incentive constraint. As a result, the mechanism implementing the first-best outcome must provide incentives and extract the entire surplus from the agent conditional on each principal type. Naturally, this requires a somewhat stronger condition on the environment. Proposition 3. If for all t ∈ T there exist vector k(t) = (k1 (t), . . . , kn (t)) such that such that f (t, a∗ (t)) · k(t) = 0, f (tˆ, a∗ (t)) · k(t) ≥ 0 for all tˆ 6= t, and f (t, a) · k(t) < 0 for all a 6= a∗ (t). Then, there exists a perfect Bayesian equilibrium in which each principal type obtains her first-best payoff. Proof. The proof follows the proof of Proposition 2 and is relegated to the Appendix. 3Note

that if we set w(s|a∗ , t) = c(a∗ ) + k(s), then π − w(s|a∗ , t) = U0∗ (t) is constant and the mechanism conditional on t is “sell the firm”.

8

¨ CHRISTOPH WAGNER, TYMOFIY MYLOVANOV, AND THOMAS TROGER

Corollary 4. If for all t ∈ T the vectors {f (tˆ, a∗ (t))}tˆ∈T and {f (t, a)}a∈A\{a∗ (t)} are linearly independent, there exists a perfect Bayesian equilibrium in which each principal type obtains her first-best payoff. Proof. The proof is analogous to that of Corollary 3 and is skipped. 5. Conclusions In this paper, we provide sufficient conditions under which the privately informed principal obtains the same payoff as when her information is commonly known. The conditions hold if the dimensionality of the support of the ex-post verfiable variable is sufficiently large relative to the dimensionality of the type and effort spaces. The observation that assumptions about the relative dimensionality of the effort, the principal type, and the ex-post verifiable information determine whether principal private information creates signaling distortions can prove useful in studying applications in other moral hazard environments. Appendix Proof of Proposition 3. Consider direct mechanism ρ that always recommends action a∗ and pays w(s|a∗ (t), t) = c(a∗ ) + γ(t)ks (t), where γ(t) > 0 is some positive number to be determined. By definition of k(t), we have f (t, a∗ (t)) · k = 0, implying f (t, a∗ (t)) · w(a∗ (t), t) = c(a∗ (t)). Hence, the mechanism satisfies agent’s participation constraint (3) and implements the first-best payoff U∗0 . Incentive compatibility constraints for the principal (1) can be written as f (t, a∗ (t)) · (π − c(a∗ (t))) ≥ f (t, a∗ (tˆ)) · (π − w(a∗ (tˆ), tˆ)) for all tˆ = 6 t or, equivalently, U0∗ (t) − (f (t, a∗ (tˆ)) · π − c(a∗ (tˆ))) ≥ −γ(t)f (t, a∗ (tˆ)) · k(tˆ) for all tˆ = 6 t Observe that the left-hand side is positive by since a∗ (t) is the first-best effort and the right-hand side is negative by definition of k(tˆ). Thus, (1) is satisfied. The agent’s payoff from following the recommendation of the mechanism is equal to 0, while the payoff from choosing any effort a 6= a∗ (t) is f (t, a) · w(a∗ (t), t) − c(a) = c(a∗ (t)) − c(a) + γ(t)f (t, a) · k(t) ∗

(5)

A c(a) Since f (t, a) · k(t) < 0 by definition of k(t), setting γ(t) > c(a |f(t))−min ensures that (t,a)·k(t)| the expression in (5) is non-positive, (2) is satisfied, and mechanism ρ is feasible. 

INFORMED-PRINCIPAL PROBLEM WITH MORAL HAZARD

9

References Balestrieri, F. (2008): “A modified English auction for an informed buyer,” mimeo. Beaudry, P. (1994): “Why an Informed Principal May Leave Rents to an Agent,” International Economic Review, 35(4), 821–832. Bond, E. W., and T. A. Gresik (1997): “Competition between asymmetrically informed principals,” Economic Theory, 10(2), 227–240. Chade, H., and R. Silvers (2002): “Informed principal, moral hazard, and the value of a more informative technology,” Economics Letters, 74(3), 291–300. ´mer, J., and R. P. McLean (1988): “Full Extraction of the Surplus in Bayesian and DomiCre nant Strategy Auctions,” Econometrica, 56(6), 1247–1257. Fleckinger, P. (2007): “Informed principal and countervailing incentives,” Economics Letters, 94(2), 240–244. Fong, Y., and F. Z. X. Lee (2013): “Signaling by An Expert,” . Grossman, S. J., and O. D. Hart (1983): “An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem,” Econometrica, 51(1), 7–45. Inderst, R. (2001): “Incentive Schemes as a Signaling Device,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 44(4), 455–465. Jost, P.-J. (1996): “On the Role of Commitment in a Principal-Agent Relationship with an Informed Principal,” Journal of Economic Theory, 68(2), 510–530. Karle, H., and C. Staatz (2013): “Signaling Quality with Initially Reduced Royalty Rates,” . Kaya, A. (2010): “When Does It Pay To Get Informed?,” International Economic Review, 51(2), 533–551. Maskin, E., and J. Tirole (1990): “The principal-agent relationship with an informed principal: The case of private values,” Econometrica, 58(2), 379–409. (1992): “The principal-agent relationship with an informed principal, II: Common values,” Econometrica, 60(1), 1–42. Mezzetti, C., and T. Tsoulouhas (2000): “Gathering information before signing a contract with a privately informed principal,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18(4), 667–689. Myerson, R. B. (1983): “Mechanism design by an informed principal,” Econometrica, 51(6), 1767–1798. (1985): “Analysis of Two Bargaining Problems with Incomplete Information,” in Game Theoretic Models of Bargaining, ed. by A. Roth, pp. 59–69. Cambridge University Press. ¨ ger (2012): “Informed-principal problems in environments with Mylovanov, T., and T. Tro generalized private values,” Theoretical Economics, 7, 465–488. (2014): “Mechanism design by an informed principal: Private-values with transferable utility,” . Riordan, M. H., and D. E. M. Sappington (1988): “Optimal Contracts with Public Ex Post Information,” Journal of Economic Theory, 45(1), 189–199. Severinov, S. (2008): “An efficient solution to the informed principal problem,” Journal of Economic Theory, 141(1), 114–133. Skreta, V. (2009): “On the informed seller problem: optimal information disclosure,” Review of Economic Design, 15(1), 1–36. Tan, G. (1996): “Optimal Procurement Mechanisms for an Informed Buyer,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(3), 699–716. Yilankaya, O. (1999): “A note on the seller’s optimal mechanism in bilateral trade with two-sided incomplete information,” Journal of Economic Theory, 87(1), 125–143.

Informed Principal Problem with Moral Hazard, Risk ...

Given a direct mechanism ρ, the expected payoff of type t of the principal if she ..... informative technology,” Economics Letters, 74(3), 291–300. Crémer, J., and ...

173KB Sizes 2 Downloads 257 Views

Recommend Documents

Dynamic risk sharing with moral hazard
Oct 24, 2011 - the planner prevents both excessive aggregate savings and excessive aggregate borrowing. ... easy to securitize loans and sell them in the derivatives market, hence transferring ... hazard and access to insurance markets.

The Principal-Agent Relationship with an Informed ...
contract "designer" (proposer) and refer to the party that accepts or refuses ..... We call the solution to this program an "unconstrained Pareto optimum" (the.

The Principal-Agent Relationship with an Informed ...
We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms ... ment trying to elicit consumers' preferences for a public good has private ..... contract that allows her to choose from the allocation ,.u= {1i}ln 1 (of co

The Principal-Agent Relationship with an Informed ...
incentive-compatible allocations that guarantee the agent at least the utility he gets from ... ment trying to elicit consumers' preferences for a public good has private .... and verifiable actions,5 belongs to a compact, convex subset of R;fl; t is

Informed-principal problems in environments with ...
Jun 3, 2011 - a speculator's prior beliefs, in environments with heterogeneous priors, in- ..... can be taken sequentially as would be for example in a model in ...

Monitoring, Moral Hazard, and Turnover
Mar 5, 2014 - than bad policy). 6 Summary and conclusions. Endogenous turnover acts as a disciplining device by inducing the politicians in office to adopt ...

Monitoring, Moral Hazard, and Turnover
Mar 5, 2014 - U.S. Naval Academy. E-mail: ..... There is a big difference between the outcomes in the mixed-strategy equilibria (with ..... exists in the data.

Dynamic Moral Hazard and Stopping - Semantic Scholar
Jan 3, 2011 - agencies “frequently” to find a wide variety of workers. ... 15% and 20% of searches in the pharmaceutical sector fail to fill a post (Pharmafocus. (2007)). ... estate agent can affect buyer arrival rates through exerting marketing

Dynamic Moral Hazard and Stopping - Semantic Scholar
Jan 3, 2011 - agencies “frequently” to find a wide variety of workers. ... 15% and 20% of searches in the pharmaceutical sector fail to fill a post (Pharmafocus. (2007)). ... estate agent can affect buyer arrival rates through exerting marketing

Asymmetric awareness and moral hazard
Sep 10, 2013 - In equilibrium, principals make zero profits and the second-best .... contingencies: the marketing strategy being a success and the product having adverse ...... sufficiently likely, e.g. the success of an advertisement campaign.

Impatience and dynamic moral hazard
Mar 7, 2018 - Abstract. This paper analyzes dynamic moral hazard with limited liability in a model where a principal hires an agent to complete a project. We first focus on moral hazard with regards to effort and show that the optimal contract frontl

special moral hazard report -
Instructions: 1. This Report is to be completed where the Sum under consideration is in excess of Rs. 25 lakhs. 2. Before completion of the report the reporting official should satisfy himself regarding the identity of the proposer. He should meet hi

Bayesian Persuasion and Moral Hazard
while in the latter case, the student is skilled with probability 3/10. The student's disutility of work is c = 1/5. Because the student's private effort determines the distribution of his type, the school must be concerned with both incentive and in

Dynamic Moral Hazard and Project Completion - CiteSeerX
May 27, 2008 - tractable trade-off between static and dynamic incentives. In our model, a principal ... ‡Helsinki School of Economics and University of Southampton, and HECER. ... We can do this with some degree of generality; for example, we allow

Bayesian Persuasion and Moral Hazard
Suppose that a student gets a high-paying job if and only if the market believes that the student is skilled with at least probability 1/2. This arises, for example, if.

moral hazard terrorism (last version).pdf
Whoops! There was a problem loading this page. moral hazard terrorism (last version).pdf. moral hazard terrorism (last version).pdf. Open. Extract. Open with.

Moral Hazard and Costly External Finance
Holmstrom, B. and J. Tirole (1997) “Financial Intermediation,. Loanable Funds, and ... Since the framework is so simple, there isn't really debt vs equity just external finance. • Recall in the data notes, I introduced a reduced form convex cost

Divide and Conquer Dynamic Moral Hazard
slot machines to pull in a sequence of trials so as to maximize his total expected payoffs. This problem ..... With probability. 1−λp0, the agent fails and the game moves to period 1 with the agent's continuation value ..... principal's profit can

Repeated Moral Hazard and Recursive Lagrangeans
Apr 11, 2011 - Society 2008 in Milan, 14th CEF Conference 2008 in Paris, 7th ... to the original one, promised utilities must belong to a particular set (call it the.

Skin in the Game and Moral Hazard
the originate-to-distribute (OTD) business model, which features zero issuer. 1 The fact .... At the start of period 2, the interim period, Nature draws q and then O.

Mitigation deterrence and the moral hazard of solar.pdf
Mitigation deterrence and the moral hazard of solar.pdf. Mitigation deterrence and the moral hazard of solar.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu.

moral hazard terrorism (last version).pdf
moral hazard terrorism (last version).pdf. moral hazard terrorism (last version).pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying moral hazard ...