Further Results on the Existence of Nash Equilibria in Discontinuous Games Philip J. Reny Department of Economics University of Chicago May 2009 (Preliminary Draft: Do not cite without permission)

Abstract We provide several generalizations of the main results in Reny (1999) for the existence of both pure and mixed strategy Nash equilibria in discontinuous games. We also provide an example demonstrating that one natural additional generalization is not possible.

1. Preliminaries There are N players. Each player i = 1; 2; :::; N has a pure strategy set, Xi ; a nonempty, compact subset of a topological vector space,1 and a payo¤ function ui : X ! R; where X=

N i=1 Xi :

This de…nes a game G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 :

Throughout, the product of any number of sets is endowed with the product topology. The symbol

i denotes “all players but i.”In particular, X

i

=

j6=i Xj ;

and x

element of X i : The graph of the vector payo¤ function is the subset of X = f(x; u) 2 X

i

denotes an

RN given by

RN j u = (u1 (x); :::; uN (x))g; and cl denotes its closure.

2. Results We present here, without proofs, several results on the existence of Nash equilibria in discontinuous games. Proofs are available from the author upon request and will be included in this paper in a subsequent revision, hopefully by the end of June 2009. The connection to the literature and the relevant references will also be included in a subsequent revision. Financial support from the National Science Foundation (SES-9905599, SES-0214421) is gratefully acknowledged. 1 We follow Royden (1988) and say that a linear vector space V endowed with a topology is a topological vector space if addition is continuous from V V into V; and multiplication by scalars is continuous from R V into V: In particular, unlike some other treatments, this de…nition does not require (although it of course permits) V to be Hausdor¤.

2.1. Pure Strategy Equilibria Throughout this section, we shall assume that for each player i; Xi is convex and that ui (xi ; x i ) is: (a) for each xi 2 Xi bounded below as a function of x

each x

i

2X

i

i

on X i ; 2 and (b) for

quasiconcave in xi on Xi :

A consequence of (a) is that, for each player i; the following is a well-de…ned real-valued function on X : 0

ui (x) = sup U 3x

inf ui (xi ; x i );

i

x0

i 2U

where the sup is taken over all neighborhoods, U; of x i : Moreover, ui (xi ; x i ) is, for each xi 2 Xi ; lower semicontinuous in x

i

on X

i

(see Reny (1999)).

De…nition 2.1. G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 has the lower single-deviation property if whenever x 2 X is not a Nash equilibrium, there exists x^ 2 X and a neighborhood U of x ; such that for all x0 2 U; there is a player i for whom ui (^ xi ; y i ) > ui (x0 ) for all y 2 U:

Theorem 2.2. If G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 has the lower single-deviation property, then G possesses a pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Remark 1. Theorem 2.2 generalizes Reny (1999) as the following result states. Theorem 2.3. If G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 is better-reply secure, then it has the lower single-deviation property. De…nition 2.4. G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 has the lower …nite-deviation property if whenever x 2 X is not a Nash equilibrium, there exists x1 ; :::; xK 2 X and a neighborhood U of x ;

such that for all x0 2 U; there is a player i and a k such that ui (xki ; y i ) > ui (x0 ) for all y 2 U:

Theorem 2.5. G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 has the lower …nite-deviation property if and only if it has the lower single-deviation property. De…nition 2.6. G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 has the conditional lower single-deviation property if whenever (x ; u ) 2 cl and x 2 X is not a Nash equilibrium, there exists x^ 2 X and a neighborhood U

V of (x ; u ); such that for all (x0 ; u(x0 )) 2 U

V; there is a player i for

0

xi ; y i ) > ui (x ) for all y 2 U: whom ui (^

Theorem 2.7. If the players’ payo¤ functions are bounded, then G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 has the lower single-deviation property if and only if it has the conditional lower single-deviation property. 2

One can in fact allow payo¤s to be unbounded, but this would require introducing the extended reals, since the limiting values of the payo¤ functions will come into play. A more elementary yet equivalent treatment of unbounded payo¤ functions (indeed, even those taking on in…nite values) results by …rst transforming the unbounded payo¤s, vi ; into bounded ones, ui ; via ui = exp vi =1 + exp vi , and then following our treatment.

2

2.2. Mixed Strategies We now drop assumptions (a) and (b) and the assumption of convex pure strategy sets from the previous section. Out of the need to calculate expected payo¤s, we shall assume throughout this section that each ui is both bounded and measurable. In addition, we shall assume that each Xi is a subset of a Hausdor¤ topological vector space. Consequently, because the Xi ’s are compact, if Mi denotes the set of (regular, countably additive) probability measures on the Borel subsets of Xi ; Mi is compact in the weak* topology.3 Extend each ui to M = R by de…ning ui (m) = X ui (x)dm for all m 2 M:

N i=1 Mi

Obviously, one can obtain theorems about the mixed extension of G by applying the

results for pure strategy equilibria in the previous section. We instead focus here on an additional result. De…nition 2.8. The mixed extension of G has the …nite deviation property if whenever m 2 M is not a Nash equilibrium, there exist m1 ; :::; mK 2 M and a neighborhood U of

m ; such that for all m0 2 U; there is a player i and a k such that ui (mki ; m0 i ) > ui (m0 ):

Theorem 2.9. If the mixed extension of G has the …nite deviation property, then G possesses a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Remark 2. The proof of Theorem 2.9 is straightforward.4 Nonetheless, it does generalize the mixed strategy existence result in Reny (1999) as stated in the next result. Theorem 2.10. If the mixed extension of G is better-reply secure, then the mixed extension of G has the …nite deviation property. (Indeed, one can take K = 1 in De…nition 2.8.)

3. An Example One might hope to improve upon the pure strategy results above in various ways. One possibility would be to replace the lower single-deviation property in Theorem 2.2 with the following single deviation property. 3

This follows from the Riesz representation theorem and Alaoglu’s theorem. See, for example, Dunford and Schwartz (1988). 4 Suppose, by way of contradiction that no Nash equilibrium exists. Then for every m 2 M; each player has …nitely many mixed strategies such that for every m0 in a neighborhood of m; one of these mixed strategies is a pro…table deviation from m0 for some player. The resulting open cover of M has a …nite subcover, by compactness, and so in fact each player has …nitely many mixed strategies –call them deviation strategies – such for every m in M some deviation strategy is a pro…table deviation from m for some player. However, by Nash’s theorem, the …nite game whose pure strategy set is the product of the players’…nite sets of deviation strategies has a Nash equilibrium, producing an element of M that no player can pro…tably deviate from using any of his deviation strategies. This contradiction completes the proof.

3

De…nition 3.1. G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 has the single deviation property if whenever x 2 X

is not a Nash equilibrium, there exists x^ 2 X and a neighborhood U of x ; such that for all x0 2 U; there is a player i for whom ui (^ xi ; x0 i ) > ui (x0 ):

Assume again that each player’s pure strategy set is convex and that (a) and (b) above hold. One might hope that the following is true. FALSE THEOREM. If G = (Xi ; ui )N i=1 has the single-deviation property, then G possesses a pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Unfortunately this theorem is false. The example below has the single deviation property but possesses no pure strategy Nash equilibrium. 3.1. Example. There are three players and each player’s pure strategy set is [0; 1]: For r 2 [0; 1]; de…ne, u0 (r) =

(

0;

if r > 0

1;

if r = 0

u1 (r) =

(

0;

if r < 1

1;

if r = 1

and de…ne

:

The players’payo¤s are de…ned by the following pair of tables.

1:rown2:col x 2 [0; 1=2]

y 2 [0; 1=3]

y 2 (1=3; 2=3)

y 2 [2=3; 1]

(u0 (x); u1 (y); u0 (z)) (u1 (x); u1 (y); u0 (z)) (u1 (x); u1 (y); u1 (z))

x 2 (1=2; 1] (u0 (x); u1 (y); u0 (z)) (u1 (x); u1 (y); u1 (z)) (u1 (x); u1 (y); u1 (z)) 3:table z 2 [0; 1=2]

1:rown2:col x 2 [0; 1=2]

[0; 1=3]

(1=3; 2=3)

[2=3; 1]

(u0 (x); u0 (y); u0 (z)) (u0 (x); u0 (y); u0 (z)) (u1 (x); u0 (y); u1 (z))

x 2 (1=2; 1] (u0 (x); u0 (y); u0 (z)) (u0 (x); u0 (y); u1 (z)) (u1 (x); u0 (y); u1 (z)) 3:table z 2 (1=2; 1]

The entry in each cell determines, for each player, which of the two functions, u0 ( ) or u1 ( ) on [0; 1]; describes his payo¤ as a function of his strategy choice, where the upper table is in e¤ect when player 3’s choice of z is in [0; 1=2] and the lower table is in e¤ect otherwise, and where the …rst coordinate of each entry corresponds to player 1, the second to player 2, and the third to player 3. 4

For example, if x 2 [0; 1=2]; y 2 (1=3; 2=3) and z 2 [0; 1=2]; then this identi…es the cell in

the upper table whose entry is (u1 (x); u1 (y); u0 (z)): Hence, player 1’s payo¤ is zero, because u1 (x) = 0 for all x 2 [0; 1=2]; and player 2’s payo¤ is also zero, because u1 (y) = 0 for all

y 2 (1=3; 2=3). Player 3’s payo¤ may be either zero or one. It is zero if z 2 (0; 1=2] because u0 (z) is zero there, but it is one if z = 0; because u0 (0) = 1:

The players’ strategy sets are compact and convex and their payo¤ functions are quasiconcave in their actions. To see the latter, notice that the functions u0 ( ) and u1 ( ) are quasiconcave on [0; 1] and that, …xing the other player’s strategies a player’s payo¤ as a function of his choice is either determined by u0 ( ) no matter what choice he makes or by u1 ( ) no matter what choice he makes. Next, it is easy to verify that if (x; y; z) is such that y < 2=3; then there is a neighborhood U of (x; y; z) such that for any (x0 ; y 0 ; z 0 ) in U; either player 1 can pro…tably deviate by choosing x^ = 0 or player 2 can pro…tably deviate by choosing y^ = 1 or player 3 can pro…tably deviate by choosing z^ = 0: Thus, (^ x; y^; z^) serves as single deviation in a neighborhood of any such (x; y; z): Similarly, it is easy to verify that if (x; y; z) is such that y > 1=3; then there is a neighborhood U of (x; y; z) such that for any (x0 ; y 0 ; z 0 ) in U; either player 1 can pro…tably deviate by choosing x^ = 1 or player 2 can pro…tably deviate by choosing y^ = 0 or player 3 can pro…tably deviate by choosing z^ = 1: Thus, (^ x; y^; z^) serves as single deviation in a neighborhood of any such (x; y; z): This shows both that the game has the single deviation property and that a Nash equilibrium fails to exist.

Theorem 3.2. Let X be a compact metric space and suppose that g : X ! R is u.s.c., f : X ! R is l.s.c., and g(x)

h : X ! R such that g(x)

f (x) for all x 2 X: Then there exists a continuous funciton

h(x)

f (x) for all x 2 X:

Proof. De…ne the correspondence H : X

R by H(x) = [g(x); f (x)]: Clearly, H is non-

empty-valued, compact-valued and convex-valued. Also, H is l.h.c. because for all a < b; fx 2 X : H(x) \ (a; b) 6= ;g = fx 2 X : g(x) < a and f (x) > bg; is open. Hence, by Michael’s selection theorem (see, e.g., Klein and Thompson, p.98, Theorem 8.1.8), H admits a continuous selection, h : X ! R: QED Corollary 3.3. If X be a compact metric space and f : X ! R is l.s.c., then for every " > 0 there is a continuous function h : X ! R such that for every x 2 X; f (y)

h(x) 5

f (x);

for some y within " of x: Proof. De…ne g(x) = inf f (z); where the in…mum is over all z 2 X whose distance from x is strictly less than ": Then g is u.s.c. and g exists a continuous h such that g(x)

f: Hence, by the previous theorem there

f (x) for all x 2 X: Moreover, for each x 2 X;

h(x)

because f; being l.s.c., achieves a minimum at some point y among all points whose distance from x is less than or equal to "; we have f (y)

g(x)

h(x)

f (x); as desired. QED

References Dunford, N., and J. T. Schwartz (1988): Linear Operators Part I: General Theory. New York: John Wiley and Sons. Reny, P. J. (1999): “On the Existence of Pure and Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibria in Discontinuous Games,”Econometrica, 67, 1029-1056. Royden, H. L. (1988): Real Analysis. New York: Macmillan.

6

Further Results on the Existence of Nash Equilibria ... - Semantic Scholar

University of Chicago. May 2009 ... *Financial support from the National Science Foundation (SES#9905599, SES#0214421) is gratefully ac# knowledged.

130KB Sizes 11 Downloads 358 Views

Recommend Documents

Further Results on Sensor Network Localization ... - Semantic Scholar
In the general model of sensor networks, there are usually some nodes named beacons, whose position in- formation is known. Those beacons have either GPS ...

On the Existence of Monotone PureStrategy Equilibria ...
25This definition of pure-strategy Bayesian–Nash equilibrium coincides, for example, with that ...... Defining bi(ti) to be the coordinatewise minimum of bi(ti) and.

On the Existence of Limit Admissible Equilibria in ...
Sep 8, 2017 - guaranteeing existence of Nash equilibrium (such as Reny's (1999) better-reply secu- rity). Moreover, it is not always the case that perfect equilibria are limit admissible. (see Carbonell-Nicolau (2011b)). Other solution concepts have

On the Existence of Symmetric Mixed Strategy Equilibria
Mar 20, 2005 - In this note we show that symmetric games satisfying these ... mixed strategies over A, i. e. the set of all regular probability measures on A.

liquid-liquid equilibria of the water- acetic acid ... - Semantic Scholar
The reliability of the experimental tie-line data was ascertained by using the ... improve recovery (Upchurch and Van Winkle, 1952;. Correa et al. ..... 308.15 K. Figure 11: Selectivity diagram at temperature values studied (free-solvent basis).

New Results on Decentralized Diagnosis of ... - Semantic Scholar
site; i.e., the decisions of the respective diagnosers will not require to be merged other than ..... It can be shown that it suffices to build diagnosers at each site.

The Existence and Uniqueness of Monotone Pure ... - Semantic Scholar
Jun 5, 2006 - of Athey (2001). Our contribution is to establish a simple condition that ensures both ... effect), and the strategy profile of its opponents (a strategic interaction). Our sufficient ...... Figure 1: Illustration of Theorem 1 since the

The Existence and Uniqueness of Monotone Pure ... - Semantic Scholar
Jul 25, 2010 - density of types is sufficiently flat, then the threshold player's ... strictly increasing in a player's type, with the rate of increase ..... payoffs, for player −i's two strategies, is no greater than ϕ2 times the distance between

Correlated Equilibria, Incomplete Information and ... - Semantic Scholar
Sep 23, 2008 - France, tel:+33 1 69 33 30 45, [email protected]. ..... no coalition T ⊂ S, and self-enforcing blocking plan ηT for T generating a.

FURTHER RESULTS ON THE H-TEST OF DURBIN ...
to give a new light on the distribution of the Durbin-Watson statistic under the null hypothesis as .... distributed ran- dom variables with zero mean and variance σ2 > 0. ..... in the multivariate framework to the content of Remark 3.2. Our goal is

on the difficulty of computations - Semantic Scholar
any calculation that a modern electronic digital computer or a human computer can ... programs and data are represented in the machine's circuits in binary form. Thus, we .... ory concerning the efficient transmission of information. An informa-.

Treewidth and Pure Nash Equilibria
1 Institute of Theoretical Computer Science, ETH Zurich,. CH-8092 Zurich .... implicitly provided in [19], that associates pure with approximate mixed equi- libria.

On Knowledge - Semantic Scholar
Rhizomatic Education: Community as Curriculum by Dave Cormier. The truths .... Couros's graduate-level course in educational technology offered at the University of Regina provides an .... Techknowledge: Literate practice and digital worlds.

On Knowledge - Semantic Scholar
Rhizomatic Education: Community as Curriculum .... articles (Nichol 2007). ... Couros's graduate-level course in educational technology offered at the University ...

Preliminary results with Hurricane Katrina - Semantic Scholar
Jul 14, 2006 - B.-W. Shen,1,2 R. Atlas,3 O. Reale,1,4 S.-J. Lin,5 J.-D. Chern,1,4 J. Chang,6,7 C. Henze ..... research tool to investigate some interesting topics both in ... gration and Visualization Office for strong support and use of computing,.

Further Results On Global Controllability of Affine ...
Aug 10, 2006 - The first class is planar affine nonlinear systems with one singular point, the second class is high-dimensional affine nonlinear systems with ...

Approximation and Characterization of Nash Equilibria ...
Mar 18, 2012 - file in a game with a continuum of players is a Nash equilibrium if and ...... ∂A; if A0,...,An are finitely many subsets of Z, then ∂(. ⋃n i=0. Ai) ⊆.

Existence of Nontrivial Equilibria in an Intermediation ...
The sole benefit provided by the intermediary is a listing service. This listing service reduces search costs for those consumers who choose to subscribe, and this listing service provides access to subscribers for those suppliers who choose to list.

The Impact of the Lyapunov Number on the ... - Semantic Scholar
results can be used to choose the chaotic generator more suitable for applications on chaotic digital communica- .... faster is its split from other neighboring orbits [10]. This intuitively suggests that the larger the Lyapunov number, the easier sh

On Decomposability of Multilinear Sets - Semantic Scholar
May 28, 2016 - Examples include quadratic programs, polynomial programs, and multiplicative ... †Graduate Program in Operations Research and Industrial ...

Dependence of electronic polarization on ... - Semantic Scholar
Dec 4, 2009 - rable with ours, as they also included Tb f electrons, with. UTb=6 eV on ... plane wave plus local-orbital method.22 In the b-c spiral case, as we ...

Long-term Nash equilibria in electricity markets
various long-term equilibria that can be analyzed with the appropriate tools. We present a ... The application of the proposed methodology is illustrated with several realistic ... their rivals; for regulators, because market power monitoring and.

Exploiting the Unicast Functionality of the On ... - Semantic Scholar
any wired infrastructure support. In mobile ad hoc networks, unicast and multicast routing ... wireless network with no fixed wired infrastructure. Each host is a router and moves in an arbitrary manner. ..... channel reservation control frames for u

the impact of young workers on the aggregate ... - Semantic Scholar
years, from various years of the Statistical Abstract of the United States. The following observations are missing: 16–19 year olds in 1995 and 1996; 45–54 year old men in Utah in 1994; and women 65 and over in. Delaware, Idaho, Mississippi, Tenn