Representative Annual Survival Probabilities for Heterogenous-Agent Economies∗ Espen Henriksen§

December 30, 2013

Abstract The world is in a constant state of demographic flux. These demographic changes have profound effects on economic growth, fiscal policy, returns to labor and capital, and asset prices. Dynamic heterogeneous-agent models are widely used to study these issues. An important input to these models are conditional survival probabilities at different ages. A shortcoming of many existing studies has, however, been that it is difficult to compare the calibration of structural parameters, elasticities and quantitive results of these heterogeneous-agent models those of representativeagent frameworks. Whereas the elasticity parameters of most economic models are estimated or calibrated to match moments at annual or higher frequency, conditional mortalities are reported for particular countries at particular points in time in five-year cohorts/intervals. This note proposes a transparent method to compute representative sequences of mortality at an annual frequency given reported and projected life expectancies. This allows for a more transparent economic analysis of aging and facilitates comparisons of elasticity estimates and results across models at different levels of aggregation. JEL Classification Codes: E13, J11. Keywords: life expectancy, mortality rates, population aging, heterogeneity, aggregation ∗ §

Thanks to David Backus and Thomas Cooley for helpful comments, and Ram Yamarthy for research assistance. University of California at Davis; [email protected].

The world is in a constant state of demographic flux. These demographic changes have profound effects on economic growth, fiscal policy, returns to labor and capital, and asset prices. Dynamic heterogeneous-agent models are widely used to study these issues. Demographic variables like mortality and life expectancy are an important ingredient in heterogenous agent models because they affect individual decisions, the composition and aggregation of individual decisions, and cohort distributions. A major shortcoming of many existing studies has been that it is difficult to compare the calibration of structural parameters and elasticities in these heterogeneous-agent models to the calibrated parameters and elasticities of representative-agent frameworks. It is also hard to compare and scrutinize the quantitative results across studies because they adopt different approaches to building in demographic variables. Mortality and life expectancy affect individuals’ decision, but conditional mortalities used in current studies are specific for particular countries at particular points in time, and are often reported at five-year cohorts/intervals. Economic data are usually reported at one-year or higher frequency. Most models and their elasticity parameters are therefore calibrated to match moments at this or higher frequency. There is no obvious way of comparing elasticity parameters and quantitative results of models with a five-year frequency with those of a one-year frequency. And even if survival probabilities were reported at an annual frequency in all countries, it would be hard to distinguish the effect of elasticity estimates from the particularities of the data. A precise formula for mortality at all ages is, obviously, impossible. In order to analyze the effect of aging, it is, however, necessary to have a parsimonious representation of how age-specific mortality evolves with life expectancy at birth. Using the observation that the logarithm of mortality rates are almost linear in age Lee and Carter (1992) proposed a principal-components-based model, which has become the “leading statistical model of mortality [forecasting] in the demographic literature” (Deaton and Paxson, 2004). Lee and Carter developed their approach on historical U.S. mortality data, 1933-1987. However, the method is now being applied to all-cause and causespecific mortality data from many countries and time periods (Girosi and King, 2008, p.34). It was

used as a benchmark for the Census Bureau population forecasts (Hollmann, Mulder, and Kallan, 2000), two U.S. Social Security Technical Advisory Panels, recommended its use, or the use of a method consistent with it (Lee and Miller, 2001), and the United Nations Population Forecast used it (Li and Gerland, 2011). This note proposes a transparent method to compute representative age-dependent survival probabilities as functions of life expectancy based on Lee and Carter (1992). This method makes it possible to compute representative sequences of mortality at an annual frequency given reported and projected life expectancies. This allows for a more transparent economic analysis of aging and facilitates comparisons of elasticity estimates and results across models at different levels of aggregation.

1

The Lee and Carter (1992) approach to forecast longevity

Lee and Carter (1992) suggested an approach to forecasting mortality changes for changes in longevity. Denoting the central death rate for age x in year t, m(x, t), Lee and Carter (1992) fit this matrix of death rates by the specification ln[m(x, t)] = ax + bx kt + εx,t ,

(1)

for appropriately chosen sets of age-specific constants, ax and bx , and time-varying index kt where kt+1 = kt + θ + t ,

(2)

This model evidently is underdetermined. k is determined only up to a linear transformation, b is determined only up to a multiplicative constant, and a is determined only up to an additive constant. Lee and Carter (1992) normalized the bx to sum to unity and the k, to sum to 0, which implies that the ax are simply the averages over time of the ln(mx,t ). The model cannot be fit by ordinary regression methods, because there are no given regressors; on the right side of the equation we have only parameters to be estimated and the unknown index k(t). As Lee and Carter (1992)

2

point out, the optima can be found via a singular value decomposition (SVD) of the matrix of centered age profiles.

2

Representative mortality for economic analysis

Whereas the evolution of longevity is a first-order question for demographers, there is not much economists can add to this question. As economists we are mainly concerned with understanding the economic implications of the demographic changes the demographers are predicting. With the life expectancies at birth that demographers report we would like to compute a transparent and representative sequence of one-year survival probabilities. The time-varying index kt can therefore be replaced by the reported life expectancy at birth e0 . It is well known among demographers that death rates increase exponentially with age, or, equivalently, that the logarithm of death rates increases linearly with age. It was previously assumed that mortality at advanced ages deviated from this log-linear relationship (“mortality deceleration”), but as noted by among others Keilman (1997) official statistics have systematically underpredicted number of old-age individuals. According to Gavrilov and Gavrilova (2011), as more data and better statistical methods have become available, “mortality deceleration” appear to be an artifact of mixing together several birth cohorts with different mortality levels and using cross-sectional instead of cohort data. From various data sources, we have annual data for realized and projected life expectancy. Mortality probabilities (and accordingly survival probabilities) are much less frequent. We suggest the following regression to predict survival probabilities for years in which they are not available. log[m(x, e0 )] = α + β e0 x + εx,t ,

(3)

β e0 = γ + θe0 + e0 ,

(4)

where

3

All right-hand side variables are observable which allows ordinary regression methods to be used. We suggest a two-stage estimation procedure. The first stage is an ordinary linear regression. In this stage, the ranking criterion for the results is out-of-sample absolute deviation between lifeexpectancy at birth life inputted to the model and life-expectancy at birth life predicted by the model. In the second stage, a simulated method of moments procedure provides exact estimates of life expectancy at birth.

2.1

Data

The World Health Organization Mortality Database provides data on five-year age-specific allcause mortality and life expectancy at birth by the member states in 1990, 2000, and 2010. Summary statistics are presented in Table 1. Average life expectancy has increased from 1990 to 2010, both measured as the average, the media, and the max across countries. The difference between the mean and the media also indicates negative skewness in the sample of countries. Figure 1 shows death rates for Japan, which have the most data on advanced age mortality. The figure shows how death rates increase log-linearly with age for all ages after early adulthood.

2.2

First-stage estimation results

The results of estimating Equations (3) and (4) are presented in Column 1 of Table 1. All point estimates are highly significant and the R2 is .79. Mortality during the first year of life is substantially higher than at immediately higher ages. A dummy variable is included for mortality for the first year of life log[m(x, e0 )] = α + β e0 x + δ1 1x=1 + εx,t ,

(5)

The results for this specification are presented in Column 2 of Table 1. All point estimates are highly significant and the R2 improves to .93. 4

As is apparent from Figure 1 and well documented in the literature, mortality rates are particularily high among teenagers and young adults and that for these age groups death rates deviate from log-linear relationship. For these age groups, a set of dummy variables are included. All point estimates are still highly significant and the R2 improves to .96. Though highly significant and negative, the estimated coefficient for the interaction between the slope and life expectancy at birth in the three first specifications is small. In the fourth specification, this interaction term is substituted with variables that allow the intercept and slope to be functions of life expectancy. All estimates are still highly significant and the R2 improves further to .98. In order to better match mortality in the first year, a quadratic term is added for infant mortality and a linear term for mortality of children between the ages of 1 and 5. The results for this specification is reported in Column 5. The R2 increases slightly to .99.

2.3

Second-stage estimation results

Based on the predictions of the model, age-specific death rates are functions of given life expectancy. With these age-specific death, rates life tables can be constructed and implied life expectancies computed. Figure 2 shows the difference between given life expectancy ei and predicted life expectancy e˜(ei ) for the latest specification estimated in the first stage. In the second stage, keeping all other estimates fixed, the intercept, αe0 , is re-estimated with the following functional form α ˜ e0 = λ0 + λ1 e0 + λ2 (e0 )2

(6)

in order to minimize deviations between given life expectancy ei and predicted life expectancy e˜(ei ) min

X

k˜ e(ei ) − ei k

i

The objective function was minimized with the following estimates for α ˜ e0 α ˜ e0 = −4.46 + 0.127e0 − 0.00091(e0 )2 5

(7)

Figure 3 shows the difference between given life expectancy ei and predicted life expectancy e˜(ei ) after the second stage estimation.

log[m(x, e0 )] = −5.426 − 0.057e0 + 0.088x + . . .   −1.151 + 0.287e0 − 0.003e20     5−x   (−1.151 + 0.287e0 − 0.003e20 ) + x5 (10.632 − 0.116e0 )  5    10−x   (10.632 − 0.116e0 ) + x−5 (1.002)  5 5     15−x (1.002) + x−10 (0.47) 5 5 ... + 20−x x−15   (0.47) + 5 (0.887)  5     25−x (0.887) + x−20 (0.774)   5 5    30−x x−25   (0.774) + 5 (0.443)  5     35−x (0.443) 5

if x = 1 if 1 < x ≤ 5 if 5 < x ≤ 10 if 10 < x ≤ 15

(8)

if 15 < x ≤ 20 if 20 < x ≤ 25 if 25 < x ≤ 30 if 30 < x ≤ 35

The resulting representative survival probabilities at different ages for different life expectancies at birth are plotted in Figure 4.

3

Conclusion

Across the world, longevity has increased substantially. Demographers project that longevity will continue increasing in the years to come. This raises a range of important economic questions. Representative sequences of mortality rates at one-year frequency is crucial for quantitatitve economic analysis of the effects of aging and comparisons across models. This note has presented a parsimonious method for economists to compute representative annual mortality rates as function of life expectancy, taking demographers’ projections of life expectancy at birth as given.

6

References Deaton, A. S. and C. Paxson (2004). Mortality, income, and income inequality over time in Britain and the United States. In Perspectives on the Economics of Aging, NBER Chapters, pp. 247–286. Gavrilov, L. A. and N. S. Gavrilova (2011). Mortality measurement at advanced ages: A study of the Social Security Administration death master file. North American Actuarial Journal 15 (3). Girosi, F. and G. King (2008). Demographic Forecasting. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Hollmann, F. W., T. J. Mulder, and J. E. Kallan (2000). Methodology and assumptions for the population projections of the United States: 1999 to 2100. U.S. Census Bureau Population Division Working Paper 38. Keilman, N. (1997). Ex-post errors in official population forecasts in industrialized countries. Journal of Official Statistics 13 (3), 245–277. Lee, R. D. and L. R. Carter (1992). Modeling and forecasting U.S. mortality. Journal of the American Statistical Association 87. Lee, R. D. and T. Miller (2001). Evaluating the performance of the Lee-Carter method for forecasting mortality. Demography 38 (4), 537–549. Li, N. and P. Gerland (2011). Modifying the Lee-Carter method to project mortality changes up to 2100. Annual Meeting of the Population Association of America.

7

Table 1: Summary statistics 1990 2000 2010

0

71.60 73.75 75.07 73.20 76.05 78.00 5.92 6.10 6.83 54.5 58.2 51.3 79.1 81.3 82.6 44 44 44

● ● ● ●

−2

● ●

● ●

● ●

−4

● ● ● ●

● ●

● ● ● ●

● ●

−6

● ●

● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ●

−8



● ●









● ●

● ●

−10

natrual logarithm of probability of dying between ages x and x + 1

mean median st.dev. min max n obs.

0

20

40

60

80

100

age

Figure 1: Natural logarithm of 1 - death rates: Japan

8

Table 2: First-stage regression results 1 Estimate (S.E.) (Intercept) -7.884* ( 0.064) γ 0.11* ( 0.007) θ -0.001* ( 0) δ0 . δ1

.

2 Estimate (S.E.) -8.594* ( 0.039) 0.12* ( 0.004) -0.001* ( 0) 4.437* ( 0.098) .

δ2

.

.

δ3

.

.

δ4

.

.

δ5

.

.

δ6

.

.

αeo

.

.

3 Estimate (S.E.) -9.534* ( 0.058) 0.133* ( 0.003) -0.001* ( 0) 5.327* ( 0.089) 2.361* ( 0.089) 1.002* ( 0.086) 0.47* ( 0.084) 0.887* ( 0.082) 0.774* ( 0.08) 0.443* ( 0.078) .

δ0eo

.

.

.

δ1eo

.

.

.

11.064* ( 0.578) 2.361* ( 0.059) 1.002* ( 0.058) 0.47* ( 0.056) 0.887* ( 0.055) 0.774* ( 0.054) 0.443* ( 0.052) -0.063* ( 0.002) -0.08* ( 0.008) .

δ0 o

.

.

.

.

N RM SE R2 adj R2 * p ≤ 0.05

968 1.054 0.791 0.791

968 0.597 0.933 0.933

968 0.455 0.961 0.961

968 0.305 0.983 0.983

(e )2

9

4 Estimate (S.E.) -5.032* ( 0.129) 0.088* ( 0.001) .

5 Estimate (S.E.) -5.426* ( 0.116) 0.088* ( 0) . -1.151 ( 4.724) 10.632* ( 0.511) 1.002* ( 0.051) 0.47* ( 0.05) 0.887* ( 0.048) 0.774* ( 0.047) 0.443* ( 0.046) -0.057* ( 0.002) 0.287* ( 0.139) -0.116* ( 0.007) -0.003* ( 0.001) 968 0.269 0.987 0.986

50

55

60

65

70

~ ei

75

80

85

90

95

45 degree line Predicted life expectancy at birth

50

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

ei

Figure 2: After first-stage estimation: given and predicted life expectancy at birth

10

50

55

60

65

70

~ ei

75

80

85

90

95

45 degree line Predicted life expectancy at birth

50

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

ei

Figure 3: After second-stage estimation: given and predicted life expectancy at birth

11

1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2

Survival probability

0.0

Life expectancy at birth: 90 Life expectancy at birth: 80 Life expectancy at birth: 70 Life expectancy at birth: 60 0

20

40

60

80

100

120

Age

Figure 4: After second-stage estimation: given and predicted life expectancy at birth

12

Demography and Capital Flows

Dec 30, 2013 - This allows for a more transparent economic analysis .... 1 shows death rates for Japan, which have the most data on advanced age mortality.

221KB Sizes 2 Downloads 276 Views

Recommend Documents

Capital Flows, Beliefs, and Capital Controls
April 28, 2016. Abstract ... crease of up to 4%, or 80 times the cost of business cycles. Controls ..... curate beliefs its financial wealth trends down. So, the mean ...

Fertility, Longevity, and Capital Flows
Jun 10, 2015 - among the group of emerging/developing countries. .... period 1960-2040, starting from complete autarky until 1980 when world ...... ios, it is informative to consider the bottom-right corner of each panel, which depicts the.

Fertility, Longevity, and Capital Flows
Global aging depresses the world interest rate. ▻ Triggers 'uphill' capital flows due to the different response of savings in developed and emerging economies.

Capital Flows, Crises and Externalities
Capital flows to emerging market economies create externalities that make the ... For contact information visit http: ... Capital. Outflows. Falling. Exchange Rates. Figure 2: Balance sheet crises and financial amplification in emerging economies. Th

Fertility, Longevity, and Capital Flows - Ensai
Jun 10, 2015 - very fast towards the developed world both in terms of fertility and ...... ios, it is informative to consider the bottom-right corner of each panel, ...

Exchange Rate Misalignment, Capital Flows, and Optimal Monetary ...
What determines the optimal monetary trade-off between internal objectives (inflation, and output gap) and external objectives (competitiveness and trade imbalances) when inef- ficient capital flows cause exchange rate misalignment and distort curren

Skill Flows: A Theory of Human Capital and ...
Jun 30, 2017 - comes from the fact that it admits a sharp analytical characterization of the ...... Proposition 5 delivers an analytic solution for the path of general ...

The IMF and the Liberalization of Capital Flows
Woods system in the 1970s and accelerated in the 1980s sought to remove government ... on this issue, which he shows emanated from the IMF's management. .... Indices on the degree of capital account liberalization (see text for details).

International Capital Flows and Liquidity Crises
One is a storage technology. (safe asset), which has zero net return: .... demand for direct investment at 9 ) # by an investor from country 4. Similarly, denote by. ;).

Exchange Rate Misalignment, Capital Flows, and Optimal Monetary ...
What determines the optimal monetary trade-off between internal objectives (inflation, and output gap) and external objectives (competitiveness and trade imbalances) when inef- ficient capital flows cause exchange rate misalignment and distort curren

Skill Flows: A Theory of Human Capital and ...
Oct 5, 2016 - the upward trends in workers' wages and in aggregate productivity: People gain skills in the course of ... quarterly output per person-hour in the non-farm business sector. ... [2016] combine micro and macro data to show that ...

Skill Flows: A Theory of Human Capital and ...
Nov 24, 2015 - on the first chapter of my doctoral thesis at New York University. .... I will now review some stylized facts that motivate and support the model. ... with unemployment.1 This line of research has consistently found that the damage fro

Capital Flows, Growth and the Financial System
At the beginning of period t, production takes place, and young domestic agents receive the wage w-. Since they do not ... using this capital and labor from the new generation of young agents. Af# ter production takes place banks sell ..... [10] Rodr

Capital flows and business cycles in Latin America ...
one of the best stories of fast recovery among the Latin American countries during the Depression. (Towmey, 1981). Partial evidence from key sector indicators in Table 2.3 reveals that this was the result of highly uneven performance among sectors. O

Excessive Volatility in Capital Flows: A Pigouvian ...
on borrowers and collapsing prices of collateral assets mutually reinforce ... general mechanism that involves asset price deflation. ... cisco Gallego et al. (2002) ...

The Cyclical Properties of Disaggregated Capital Flows
ment of Economics, Carnegie 205, 425 N. College Avenue, Claremont, CA ..... 15See also De Pace (forthcoming)'s technical appendix for a more detailed ...

The Composition of Capital Flows When Emerging ...
into the emerging markets vary over the business cycle? What drives this ..... returns-to-scale technology, taking factor and goods prices as given. 2 households ...

The Composition of Capital Flows When Emerging ...
2 Firm financing in a small open economy. Domestic households .... of Domestic Firms in the SOE. First, adjust dividends to account for secondary offerings. VD.

Demography and cultural evolution.pdf
Sign in. Loading… Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying.

demography pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. demography pdf.

Backus, Cooley and Henriksen: 'Demography and ...
Jan 8, 2014 - say from the US to Mexico — its flow addresses imbalances between local sources of funds. (savings) and uses .... We use an interval of one year to get more precise control over the effects of mortality on life expectancy. ... We docu

pdf-1834\demography-and-distribution-of-wolves-denali-national ...
... apps below to open or edit this item. pdf-1834\demography-and-distribution-of-wolves-denali ... rogress-report-l-david-mech-thomas-j-meier-john-w.pdf.