Foreign Policy Analysis (2015) 11, 85–107

Democracy, Territory, and Armed Conflict, 1919–19951 JOHANN PARK Mississippi State University AND

PATRICK JAMES University of Southern California Democracy and territory are two of the most important factors that affect conflict and war. Yet no research design looks directly at a possible interaction between these two variables to influence occurrence of armed conflict. This study seeks to answer the following question: “How do two democracies behave when a contentious issue such as territory arises as the source of conflict between them?” Results based on Militarized Interstate Dispute data from 1920 to 1996 produce the conclusion that the pacifying effect of democracy stands up for both territorial dyads and nonterritorial ones in spite of the imperatives toward militarization created by territorial conflict. However, territory of high salience still appears to increase the likelihood of armed conflict between two democracies.

This study joins a growing literature on the triadic relationship among democracy, territorial issues,2 and armed conflict. We aim to compare and contrast the effects of democracy and territory and identify their interactive linkage in impacting upon international strife. The following question provides the focal point: “Is the pacifying effect of democracy muted by the conflict-generating effect of territory and vice versa?” In contrast to extant competing claims, we argue and find that both democracy and territory account for conflict processes, while recognizing that one does not nullify but may condition the other’s effect to a certain degree. Each of the preceding factors separately has drawn extensive scholarly attention on its own, with the pace of research on territory in particular picking up to match that of democracy over the last decade (Vasquez 2009; Lektzian, Prins, and Souva 2010).3 Democracy, on the one hand, is a well-established characteris1 Authors’ notes: Our special thanks are due to Michael Colaresi, Valentina Bali, and Cristina Bodea for their helpful comments on multiple occasions. We are also grateful to David Carter, Petra Hendrickson, Douglas Lemke, Sara Mitchell, Michael Mousseau, John Oneal, James Lee Ray, Bruce Russett, John Vasquez, and Brandon Valeriano for their helpful comments. Paul Huth and Todd Allee kindly shared their territorial claim data. Also, we thank Paul Hensel for making the ICOW data available online. 2 We define “issues” in line with Holsti (1991:18): “the stakes over which two or more parties contend”; see also Diehl (1992:333): “what states choose to fight over.” 3 Research on territory is expanding to include strategic behavior on the part of adversaries in a territorial context. Carter (2010), in an innovative treatment, establishes that a target state can be expected to take action to upgrade the defensive viability of territory coveted by a conflict initiator. This and other expectations in the context of territorial conflict are confirmed through data analysis and provide an example of how the range of territoryrelated propositions formulated and tested in the field of conflict processes is expanding rapidly.

Park, Johann and Patrick James. (2015) Democracy, Territory, and Armed Conflict, 1919–1995. Foreign Policy Analysis, doi: 10. 1111/fpa.12033 © 2013 International Studies Association

86

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict

tic that makes any given pair of states more likely to interact peacefully in the international system. The proposition that democracies very rarely fight each other often is referred to as the “closest thing we have to an empirical law in international relations” (Levy 1988:661–2). Numerous statistical studies have provided empirical evidence for the dyadic proposition about democracy,4 not only for war but also for lower levels of interstate conflict such as Militarized Interstate Disputes (MIDs) (e.g., Russett and Oneal 2001; Park 2013).5 Territory, on the other hand, is the “rising star” among candidate explanations for interstate conflict processes. Territory is regarded as a salient—maybe even the most salient—point of departure from which states go to fight and escalate violence to higher levels (e.g., Vasquez 1993, 2009; Hensel and Mitchell 2005; Senese and Vasquez 2008). It should be fruitful to explore a possible connection between democracy and territory, with the one being a most robust predictor of peace and the other being a most salient source of conflict. Two basic questions arise: “Does the dyadic democratic peace holds up even for a difficult issue like territory?” and “Do territorial issues produce militarized strife even for democratic dyads?”6 Recent critiques based on territorial explanations suggest that the democratic peace is epiphenomenal to territorial issues (e.g., James, Park, and Choi 2006; Gibler 2007). However, methodological limitations undercut the ability of these studies to make definitive inferences from the data at hand. By contrast, some proponents of the democratic peace have argued that democracies do not fight each other over territorial issues (e.g., Lake 1992; Kacowicz 1995; Bueno de Mesquita and Siverson 1997). This bold claim, however, has yet to be exposed to extensive, systematic empirical testing. One explanation does not have to be at odds with the other. Each could remain meaningful even in a context where the former is conditioned by the latter, and vice versa. Preceding caveats combine to encourage a study with the present overall objective: assess the interactive role of democracy and territory regarding conflict processes. This present study will look directly at a possible interaction between these two variables in relation to armed conflict. The research design builds on efforts to assess the possible contingent effects of democracy and contentious issues on armed conflict (Mitchell and Prins 1999; Ellis et al. 2010; Lektzian et al. 2010; Reed and Chiba 2010; Park and Colaresi 2014). We go beyond existing studies to develop interactive hypotheses and provide empirical analyses to test the two contrasting claims. Results based on MID data and Huth and Allee’s (2002) territorial claim data from 1919 to 1995 produce the conclusion that the pacifying effect of democracy stands up for both territorial dyads and nonterritorial ones in spite of the imperatives toward militarization created by territorial conflict. This paper will unfold as follows. The second section reviews existing studies. The third section works through theoretical explanations vis-a-vis possible interaction between democracy and territory to produce hypotheses. The fourth section focuses on the research design, including empirical models, data, and measurement. Data analysis appears in the fifth section. The sixth and 4 At the monadic level, however, democracies appear to be as war-prone as nondemocracies in general (Small and Singer 1976; Maoz and Abdolali 1989; Leeds and Davis 1999). Major dissenting expositions appear in Benoit (1996), Ray (2000), and Souva and Prins (2006). 5 MIDs are defined as instances in which at least one state took militarized action against another state in the form of a threat, display, or actual use of force (Jones, Bremer, and Singer 1996:195). 6 Senese and Vasquez (2008:268) make the following observation: “An interesting connection with the steps-towar research program is whether one of the reasons democratic states do not fight each other is because they do not have territorial disputes and tend not to use power politics to resolve the disputes they do have.” Interesting to ponder, in that context, is a recent finding that democratic states are more than twice as likely to negotiate high-salience issues (Ellis, Mitchell, and Prins 2010).

J OHANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AMES

89

that the absence of an expansionist bias is manifest in interdemocratic relations because an additional piece of territory only serves the interests of a small fraction of democratic society while possibly creating a distortion on the entire economy. Kacowicz (1995:265), acknowledging the removal of territorial issues as the key to peace, argues that “[democracies] are conservative powers satisfied with the territorial status quo within and across their borders.” His explanations include (i) democratic institutions that remove irredentist and nationalist claims and make governments strong domestically and (ii) democratic norms that promote consensus based on international law and mutual respect. Bueno de Mesquita and Siverson (1997) make an argument that parallels Lake (1992). Democracies concerned with the provision of public goods are less likely to use force over territorial issues because potential gain does not benefit a sufficient proportion of domestic constituencies. Is there evidence for the theorized negative relationship between democracy and territorial conflict? In the democratic peace scholarship, only scant empirical attention has been paid to this matter. An exception exists. Mitchell and Prins (1999) discover that territorial MIDs between fully established democracies (with a Polity score of 10) are extremely rare and even then tend to be minor. How many fully established democracies, however, have shared borders at any time? Mitchell and Prins report that more than 40% of MIDs involved territorial issues for democratic dyads that include at least one democracy that is less than fully institutionalized. What is unclear is how often territorial issues have arisen between democracies and lead to military conflict as compared to autocratic dyads. Huth and Allee (2002; see also Huth, Croco, and Appel 2011), creators of the territorial claim list to be used here, examine how democratic dyads settle territorial issues before reaching a military level. They divide the conflict process into three stages. At the first (status quo) stage, Huth and Allee’s multinomial logit models support the democratic peace. Democratic challengers are less likely to turn to force than to call for talks. At the second (negotiation) stage, findings are mixed. Democratic targets are more likely to make concessions in talks over disputed territory than nondemocratic targets, but democratic challengers are no more inclined to make concessions regardless of the target’s regime type. Both democratic challengers and targets appear less inclined to offer concessions when politically salient concerns with ethnic co-nationals are present within the disputed territory. At the third (military escalation) stage, with militarized hostility, both democratic targets and challengers are no less likely than nondemocratic challengers and targets to escalate. Although Huth and Allee reveal important conflict patterns for democratic countries in territorial disputes, yet to be explored are possible interactive effects for the two most important factors, democracy and territory, contingent on each other. Like James et al. (2006), Huth and Allee (2002) select on the dyads already involved in the claims over territory. The democratic peace may exist despite the salient presence of contentious territorial issues. However, it is unknown whether and how much the conflict-generating effect of territory is reduced by the democratic peace as well as whether and how much the democratic peace is weakened by territorial issues. Most recently, based on the Huth and Allee list, Senese and Vasquez (2008) offer a major advancement in their authoritative exposition on the “steps-towar.” They offer a developmental model with two main expectations: territorial claims are more likely to produce MID onset, and territorial MIDs are more likely to result in war. These propositions are confirmed for both an overall period of 1919–1995 and three subperiods corresponding to conventional designations of power structure. The powerful impact of territory is preserved in the presence of all standard control variables and through multiple statistical

90

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict

techniques. Democracy, however, is a control variable in the research design (Senese and Vasquez 2008:92, 103). Does democracy lessen the conflict-prone nature of territorial issues and to what extent? Conversely, do territorial issues weaken the pacific effect of democracy and to what degree? We seek answers to these interrelated questions and will test simultaneously whether the most widely accepted evidence of the democratic peace (that is, two democracies are less likely to experience a MID) and whether territorial conflict (that is, territorial claims tend to produce MIDs at a greater rate) hold up against each other at the level of militarized disputes. Hypotheses We propose a battery of interactive hypotheses on the triadic relationship among democracy, territory, and armed conflict. These hypotheses are developed from existing theorizing of the democratic peace and territorial conflict. Democratic Peace Hypotheses

Respective democratic peace explanations may produce different or similar expectations about the behavior of democracies when territorial issues are at stake. First, the most prevalent explanations focus on normative and institutional features unique to democracies. Democracies are both normatively and institutionally constrained from using force against other democracies (Ray 1995; Russett and Oneal 2001). These constraint-based explanations of the democratic peace do not differentiate the democratic resolution mechanism according to issue type. This may suggest the democratic peace exists regardless of issue type and even in the presence of territorial disagreements. Hypothesis 1: Joint democracy will reduce the probability of MID onset in the presence of territorial claims to a degree similar to other contexts. Variants of the institutional democratic peace explanation are able to produce more nuanced hypotheses with respect to salient issues such as territory. Prominent among variants of the institutional explanation is a model that focuses on the “informational properties” of democracy (Fearon 1994; Schultz 1999; Lektzian and Souva 2009). Democratic institutions help to reveal reliable information in a dispute due to the accountability and transparency generated by their political processes. The credible information flow between democracies makes it easier for them to identify a settlement ex-ante rather than incur the risks and costs related to use of force. Therefore, disputes between two democracies are less inclined to militarization. The salient nature of territorial disputes may make this pattern more apparent. The peace-inducing effect of democracies should be strengthened as the issues under contention get more salient. The credible information flow between democracies is a function of the general public’s attention to international disputes and crises. Given the salience of territorial issues as discussed later, the pacifying effect of democracy may be even more evident in contention over territory. Territorial issues between two democracies could increase the likelihood of armed conflict between them. Compared to autocrats, however, democrats are quite susceptible to public scrutiny and therefore should have even less incentive to bluff and misrepresent resolve with respect to a salient issue like territory. By contrast, for two autocracies, the inability to generate audience costs means that the very salience of territorial issues will make such dyads even more conflictual. This leads us to expect that the gap in conflict propensities between democratic and nondemocratic dyads will be wider for territorial disputes than nonterritorial ones.

J OHANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AMES

89

that the absence of an expansionist bias is manifest in interdemocratic relations because an additional piece of territory only serves the interests of a small fraction of democratic society while possibly creating a distortion on the entire economy. Kacowicz (1995:265), acknowledging the removal of territorial issues as the key to peace, argues that “[democracies] are conservative powers satisfied with the territorial status quo within and across their borders.” His explanations include (i) democratic institutions that remove irredentist and nationalist claims and make governments strong domestically and (ii) democratic norms that promote consensus based on international law and mutual respect. Bueno de Mesquita and Siverson (1997) make an argument that parallels Lake (1992). Democracies concerned with the provision of public goods are less likely to use force over territorial issues because potential gain does not benefit a sufficient proportion of domestic constituencies. Is there evidence for the theorized negative relationship between democracy and territorial conflict? In the democratic peace scholarship, only scant empirical attention has been paid to this matter. An exception exists. Mitchell and Prins (1999) discover that territorial MIDs between fully established democracies (with a Polity score of 10) are extremely rare and even then tend to be minor. How many fully established democracies, however, have shared borders at any time? Mitchell and Prins report that more than 40% of MIDs involved territorial issues for democratic dyads that include at least one democracy that is less than fully institutionalized. What is unclear is how often territorial issues have arisen between democracies and lead to military conflict as compared to autocratic dyads. Huth and Allee (2002; see also Huth, Croco, and Appel 2011), creators of the territorial claim list to be used here, examine how democratic dyads settle territorial issues before reaching a military level. They divide the conflict process into three stages. At the first (status quo) stage, Huth and Allee’s multinomial logit models support the democratic peace. Democratic challengers are less likely to turn to force than to call for talks. At the second (negotiation) stage, findings are mixed. Democratic targets are more likely to make concessions in talks over disputed territory than nondemocratic targets, but democratic challengers are no more inclined to make concessions regardless of the target’s regime type. Both democratic challengers and targets appear less inclined to offer concessions when politically salient concerns with ethnic co-nationals are present within the disputed territory. At the third (military escalation) stage, with militarized hostility, both democratic targets and challengers are no less likely than nondemocratic challengers and targets to escalate. Although Huth and Allee reveal important conflict patterns for democratic countries in territorial disputes, yet to be explored are possible interactive effects for the two most important factors, democracy and territory, contingent on each other. Like James et al. (2006), Huth and Allee (2002) select on the dyads already involved in the claims over territory. The democratic peace may exist despite the salient presence of contentious territorial issues. However, it is unknown whether and how much the conflict-generating effect of territory is reduced by the democratic peace as well as whether and how much the democratic peace is weakened by territorial issues. Most recently, based on the Huth and Allee list, Senese and Vasquez (2008) offer a major advancement in their authoritative exposition on the “steps-towar.” They offer a developmental model with two main expectations: territorial claims are more likely to produce MID onset, and territorial MIDs are more likely to result in war. These propositions are confirmed for both an overall period of 1919–1995 and three subperiods corresponding to conventional designations of power structure. The powerful impact of territory is preserved in the presence of all standard control variables and through multiple statistical

90

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict

techniques. Democracy, however, is a control variable in the research design (Senese and Vasquez 2008:92, 103). Does democracy lessen the conflict-prone nature of territorial issues and to what extent? Conversely, do territorial issues weaken the pacific effect of democracy and to what degree? We seek answers to these interrelated questions and will test simultaneously whether the most widely accepted evidence of the democratic peace (that is, two democracies are less likely to experience a MID) and whether territorial conflict (that is, territorial claims tend to produce MIDs at a greater rate) hold up against each other at the level of militarized disputes. Hypotheses We propose a battery of interactive hypotheses on the triadic relationship among democracy, territory, and armed conflict. These hypotheses are developed from existing theorizing of the democratic peace and territorial conflict. Democratic Peace Hypotheses

Respective democratic peace explanations may produce different or similar expectations about the behavior of democracies when territorial issues are at stake. First, the most prevalent explanations focus on normative and institutional features unique to democracies. Democracies are both normatively and institutionally constrained from using force against other democracies (Ray 1995; Russett and Oneal 2001). These constraint-based explanations of the democratic peace do not differentiate the democratic resolution mechanism according to issue type. This may suggest the democratic peace exists regardless of issue type and even in the presence of territorial disagreements. Hypothesis 1: Joint democracy will reduce the probability of MID onset in the presence of territorial claims to a degree similar to other contexts. Variants of the institutional democratic peace explanation are able to produce more nuanced hypotheses with respect to salient issues such as territory. Prominent among variants of the institutional explanation is a model that focuses on the “informational properties” of democracy (Fearon 1994; Schultz 1999; Lektzian and Souva 2009). Democratic institutions help to reveal reliable information in a dispute due to the accountability and transparency generated by their political processes. The credible information flow between democracies makes it easier for them to identify a settlement ex-ante rather than incur the risks and costs related to use of force. Therefore, disputes between two democracies are less inclined to militarization. The salient nature of territorial disputes may make this pattern more apparent. The peace-inducing effect of democracies should be strengthened as the issues under contention get more salient. The credible information flow between democracies is a function of the general public’s attention to international disputes and crises. Given the salience of territorial issues as discussed later, the pacifying effect of democracy may be even more evident in contention over territory. Territorial issues between two democracies could increase the likelihood of armed conflict between them. Compared to autocrats, however, democrats are quite susceptible to public scrutiny and therefore should have even less incentive to bluff and misrepresent resolve with respect to a salient issue like territory. By contrast, for two autocracies, the inability to generate audience costs means that the very salience of territorial issues will make such dyads even more conflictual. This leads us to expect that the gap in conflict propensities between democratic and nondemocratic dyads will be wider for territorial disputes than nonterritorial ones.

J O HANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AM ES

101

TABLE 4. Probit Models of MID Onset for ICOW Dyads Model 1 DEMOCRACY SALIENCE DEMOCRACY 9 SALIENCE Capability Ratio Contiguity Distance Major Power Alliance Previous MIDs Peace Years Peace Years2 Peace Years3 Constant N Log Pseudo L Pseudo R2 BIC

0.201 (0.092)** 0.027 (0.015)*

0.044 0.034 0.007 0.050 0.039 0.035 0.048 0.001 0.000 1.222 7,210 1602.613 .120 3311.825

(0.023)* (0.134) (0.055) (0.091) (0.067) (0.008)**** (0.007)**** (0.000)**** (0.000)*** (0.409)***

Model 2

Model 3

0.225 (0.088)** 0.028 (0.014)**

0.790 (0.231)**** 0.019 (0.014) 0.075 (0.029)**

0.055 (0.019)*** 0.034 (0.008)***

0.058 (0.019)***

0.034 0.049 0.001 0.000 1.246 7,210 1603.661 .120 3278.387

(0.008)**** (0.007)**** (0.000)**** (0.000)**** (0.167)****

0.034 0.049 0.001 0.000 1.178 7,210 1600.884 .121 3281.717

(0.008)**** (0.007)**** (0.000)**** (0.000)**** (0.165)****

(Notes. BIC, Bayesian information criteria; MID, Militarized Interstate Dispute. *p < .1, **p < .05, ***p < .01, and ****p < .001 (two-tailed). Robust standard errors, adjusted for clustering on dyad, are in parentheses.)

the importance of each claim on a 0–12 scale (see Hensel et al. 2008). We also create a multiplicative interaction term for DEMOCRACY and SALIENCE (that is, DEMOCRACY 9 SALIENCE) to assess how they interact in impacting upon armed conflict (Table 4). We first estimate the net independent effects of DEMOCRACY and SALIENCE. As expected, both measures affect the probability of MID onset significantly. Not surprisingly, the geopolitical controls, such as contiguity, distance, major power status, and alliance, are insignificant in this limited sample of dyads with issue claims. Since both the BIC and Wald test prefer the reduced model without these insignificant controls, we exclude them in the interactive model (that is, Model 2). Taking these insignificant variables out of the model improves the significance level for SALIENCE from the .1 to .05 level. In Model 3, a significant interaction is found between DEMOCRACY and SALIENCE—the estimated coefficient for the interaction term is .075 with a pvalue of .011. The positive coefficient indicates that the pacifying effect of DEMOCRACY decreases over the level of issue salience. A MID is less likely to occur between two issue claimants if they are democracies rather than autocracies, but this pacific democratic relationship ceases to be the case when their issue is highly salient. The negative coefficient of DEMOCRACY becomes insignificant at the salience score of 9 and even its sign is reversed at 11 as captured in Figure 3A. This result holds also in terms of predicted probability as shown in Figure 3C. The difference in conflict propensity between democratic dyads and nondemocratic dyads disappears when an issue involved is highly salient. DEMOCRACY abates conflict by a factor of about 3.7 for low issue salience (that is, SALIENCE = 3), whereas the equivalent factorial change becomes insubstantial (a factor of 1.25) for high issue salience (that is, SALIENCE = 9). Figure 3B describes the impact of SALIENCE conditional upon DEMOCRACY. SALIENCE only significantly increases conflict propensity for dyads of democratic claimants, whereas it does not have a significant impact for nondemocratic counterparts. For nondemocratic dyads, the negative coefficient for SALIENCE

92

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict

Hypothesis 4: Territorial claims will increase the rate of MID onset between two democracies. Further, the pacifying effect of democracy may be significantly reduced to the extent that: Hypothesis 5: Joint democracy does not decrease the probability of MID onset in the context of territorial claims. Gibler’s (2007) stable border thesis makes an even stronger case, as reviewed previously: democracy has no independent impact on military conflict because territorial issues explain both conflict and democracy. Hypothesis 6: Joint democracy does not decrease the probability of MID onset controlling for territorial issues.. Territorial issues should be a hard case (or least likely case) for the democratic peace thesis in view of the explanation based on competing territorial claims. But some proponents argue that democracies do not initiate fighting over territorial issues, since the stakes from those conflicts are not large enough to distribute over a wide range of democratic constituencies (Bueno de Mesquita et al. 2003). We suspend judgment on this. If territorial issue specification is a difficult test, favorable results should provide strong support to the democratic peace thesis, that is, what Levy (2002) labels the Sinatra inference—if the democratic peace theory can make it with territorial issues, it can make it with any other issues. Research Design Our temporal domain spans 1919–1995, during which both measures for democracy and territorial claims are available. We examine all dyads rather than only dyads with territorial claims. The use of all dyads also enables us to not only avoid the possible problems caused by the selected sample (Geddes 1990; Senese and Vasquez 2003) but also examine the interactive effects of democracy and territory and assess the statistical uncertainty for such contingent effects. In our main analysis, we also do not limit our evidence to only politically relevant dyads defined as those contiguous or consisting of at least one major power because of theoretical and empirical problems associated with a limited sample. First, nothing in the theorizing suggests that the democratic peace and territorial conflict should be limited to this subset (Gowa 2011). Second, the criteria for politically relevant dyads do not fully identify dyads at risk of armed conflict (Lemke and Reed 2001; Gowa 2011). Rather, we employ major power status, contiguity, and geographic distance as independent variables rather than criteria for sample selection. However, as a robustness check, we also examine politically relevant dyads and discuss the results in the analysis section. We used EUGene (v.3.2) to generate the basic template of our data set (Bennett and Stam 2000). Our dependent variable is MID onset, coded 1 if there was a new onset of a MID in a given dyad year (otherwise 0) according to the MID data set (v.3.1) of the COW (Correlates of War) project. As Bennett and Stam recommend, we exclude ongoing MID years and “joiner” dyad years unless a new direct onset of a MID occurs within the dyad. We turn to discussion of variables and their measurements. We have hypothesized some possible interactions between territory and democracy in impacting upon the likelihood of armed conflict. TERRITORY is a dummy variable that indicates whether a dyad in a given year experiences a territorial disagreement.

J OHANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AMES

93

To identify the dyads involved in territorial claims, we use the list from Huth and Allee (2002). It identifies 348 distinct interstate territorial claims, worldwide from 1919 to 1995. In some cases, the same dyads have been involved in multiple territorial claims. Huth and Allee’s list does not include claims regarding maritime boundaries.10 Since our units of analysis are all dyad years from the interstate system (N = 496,442 for 1919–1995), we code 1 if a dyad is involved in at least one territorial claim in a given year, otherwise 0. DEMOCRACY is also a dichotomous variable. While this dichotomy does cause a loss of information, as will become apparent, measurement loss is minimal because the vast majority of states are either highly democratic or autocratic. As Alvarez, Cheibub, Limongi, and Przeworski (1996:21–22) observe, “while democracy can be more or less advanced, one cannot be half democratic: there is a natural zero point.” This variable is operationalized by subtracting the Polity IV index (Marshall and Jaggers 2002) of a state’s authoritarian characteristics (that is, 0 to 10) from its institutionalized democratic characteristics (that is, 0 to 10). Then, we code 1 if both states in a dyad have 7 or more as a score, otherwise 0 (Jaggers and Gurr 1995). Based on the standard statistical model of conflict (e.g., Bremer 1992; Russett and Oneal 2001; Senese and Vasquez 2003), six control variables are introduced that may influence states’ decisions to use force for settlement. All of the controls except for peace years are operationalized through EUGene software. First, we include a control for geographic influence on militarized conflict. Neighboring countries should have more opportunities and issues over which to fight militarily. Most importantly for this present study, neighboring countries tend to have more territorial claims and their claims may be even more salient (Vasquez 1995; Gibler 2007). Thus, we need to control for this factor to attain the unbiased net effect of territory as well as the interactive effect with democracy. “Contiguity” is coded 1 if two states are contiguous by land or separated by <150 miles of water. In order to fully account for the effect of geography, we also employ distance between two countries. “Distance” between two states is measured as the natural logarithm of the great circle distance in miles between the capitals of the two states (or cities for the largest countries such as the United States). We expect that the more distance between two countries, the less chance they experience military conflict because of geographical constraints in exercising force over long distance.11 Second, the effect of distance to constrain militarized options may be less for the major powers with land, sea, or air capability to exercise military power from far away. Many empirical studies have found that major powers are more conflict-prone than minor powers (e.g., Bremer 1980). Following these studies, we employ a variable that identifies whether a dyad includes at least one major power state (“major power”). Such a case is coded 1 and otherwise 0. We expect that a dyad consisting of only minor powers is less likely to engage in militarized attempts. Third, previous research also shows that, the greater the difference in capabilities between two states, the lower the likelihood they will be involved in a MID (Kugler and Lemke 1996). Therefore, the capability ratio for each dyad is included. We use the Composite Index of National Capability of the COW project that averages each country’s global shares of capabilities across six components: 10 “The data set is restricted to disputes over shared land borders, shared river boundaries, claims to sovereignty over offshore islands or islands in shared rivers, or a few military base cases that raise issues of sovereignty over territory” (Paul Huth, email communication, July 2, 2009). 11 Some would argue against inclusion of geographic proximity controls that could exclude most current, important territorial claims between neighbors and produce disproportionate effects on the sample from seemingly low-salience cases and old colonial cases. We consider this point and find that excluding the geographic controls does not alter our conclusions on either the net or interactive effects of democracy and territory.

94

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict

energy consumption, iron and steel production, military expenditure, military personnel, total population, and urban population (Singer, Bremer, and Stuckey 1972). We measure the relative capabilities as a natural logarithm of the higher/ lower ratio between states A and B. We call this variable “capability ratio.” Fourth, it generally is thought that allies are less likely to fight each other because they share common security interests (and also political and economic interests). Evidence supports this proposition (e.g., Bremer 1992; Russett and Oneal 2001). For this reason, a dichotomous variable is coded 1 for any dyad sharing an alliance (that is, defense pact, neutrality, or entente) and zero otherwise based on the formal alliance data set of the COW Project.12 This variable is labeled “alliance.” Fifth, previous studies make the case that dyads highly subject to recurring militarization should be controlled in testing the democratic peace against contentious issues (Rasler and Thompson 2001; Ellis et al. 2010; Lektzian et al. 2010). We measure the number of previous MIDs between states in a given dyad and label this as “previous MIDs.” Sixth, and finally, since the data set is structured in the form of a cross-sectional time series, there may be time dependence that may compromise our hypothesis testing. Thus, we opt for the method of peace-year correction to test and correct the possible temporal dependence. However, we do not use Beck, Katz, and Tucker’s (1998) cubic splines because of arbitrariness about setting knots. Rather, as suggested by Carter and Signorino (2010), we use cubic polynomials of peace years (that is, t, t2, and t3). Carter and Signorino’s Monte Carlo study shows this method can perform as well as cubic splines and even better if knots are misspecified. As is standard for the conflict model (Russett and Oneal 2001; Gartzke 2007; Choi 2011; Dafoe 2011; Park 2013), we employ 1-year lag structure to address the possible endogeneity between conflict and independent variables. Results All Dyads

Panel A of Table 1 reports descriptive statistics for our dependent and independent variables. In Panel B, dyads are classified into four cells based on regime type and territorial claim: (i) democratic dyads with territorial claims, (ii) democratic dyads without territorial claims, (iii) nondemocratic dyads with territorial claims, and (iv) nondemocratic dyads without territorial claims. Each cell contains the number of dyad years falling in that category. As shown, democratic dyads appear to have territorial claims no less frequently than nondemocratic dyads.13 Among democratic dyad years, 1.26% involve territorial disputes (466/ 36,896), while 0.86% of nondemocratic dyadic years do so (3,952/459,547). Similarly, 10.55% of territorial claim dyad years involve democratic dyads (466/ 4,418), while 7.40% of nonterritorial claim dyad years contain democratic dyads (36,430/492,025). Panel B also provides real-world examples for each interactive combination. Table 2 reports probit regression results for both net and interactive effects of TERRITORY and DEMOCRACY on MID onset for all dyads from 1919 to 1995. Briefly, the control variables appear to have statistically significant effects in the expected directions on MID onset across all models. As for the net effects 12 Following Leeds (2003), we also consider two states allied if and only if they have a mutual defense pact. Inclusion of this alternative measure did not change the results. 13 This result and the subsequent findings about the effect of democracy on MIDs are consistent with Kinsella and Russett (2002). They find the effect of democracy to be greater for preventing escalation of low-level disputes into MIDs than for the initiation of low level disputes.

J OHANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AMES

95

TABLE 1. Descriptive Statistics (1919–1995) (A) Independent and Dependent Variables Variable

Mean

SD

Min.

Max.

MID Onset (1920–1996)* DEMOCRACY TERRITORY Capability Ratio (Logged) Contiguity Distance (Logged) Major Power Alliance Previous MIDs Peace Years

0.003 0.074 0.009 2.394 0.032 8.239 0.085 0.071 0.082 21.814

0.0580571 0.262292 0.0939155 1.867581 0.1757473 0.7985807 0.2791646 0.256625 0.7129804 24.74007

0 0 0 0 0 1.609 0 0 0 0

1 1 1 11.866 1 9.421 1 1 30 347

(B) Cross-Tabulation of Democracy and Territory Democratic Dyad Years Territorial Claim Years

No Territorial Claim Years

Sum



466 (10.55%) (1.26%) Canada/United States (1973–1990) Japan/South Korea (1960, 1988–1995) 36,430 (7.40%) (98.74%) Colombia/Venezuela (1968–1995) Gambia/New Zealand (1965–1993) 36,896 (7.43%) (100%)

Nondemocratic Dyad Years 3,952 (89.45%) (0.86%) United States/Spain (1923–1931, 1938–1970) Portugal/Indonesia (1975–95) 455,595 (92.60%) (99.14%) United States/Portugal (1926–1975) Malaysia/Singapore (1965–1979) 459,547 (92.57%) (100%)

Sum 4,418 (100%) (0.89%)

492,025 (100%) (99.11%)

496,443 (100%)

(Notes. MID, Militarized Interstate Dispute. *Because we employed the 1-year lag structure, we predict MIDs that had occurred from 1920 to 1996 period with the information on the independent variables for the 1919–1995 period. † The number in each cell represents dyad years falling into that cell. In each cell, the percentage in the left parenthesis refers to its proportion against the row total, while the percentage in the right parenthesis refers to its proportion against the column total.)

(Model 1), both DEMOCRACY and TERRITORY have a significant and independent impact on MID onset. Democratic dyads are less likely to engage in a MID than nondemocratic dyads, whereas territorial dyads are more likely to experience a MID than nonterritorial dyads. The pacifying effect of DEMOCRACY is confirmed despite the presence of the direct measure of territorial issues (that is, TERRITORY). This finding weakens Gibler’s (2007) critique that the democracy– peace relationship observed without considering territorial threat is spurious. The presumed contingent effects of DEMOCRACY and TERRITORY are examined in Model 2. The multiplicative interactive term for DEMOCRACY and TERRITORY is statistically significant with a negative sign at the .05 level. This suggests that the pacifying effect of DEMOCRACY increases in the context of territorial claims,14 whereas the conflict-inducing effect of TERRITORY decreases 14 This finding is consistent with some of the arguments made by democratic peace proponents. Huth and Allee (2002; see also Gartzke 1998) argue that the democratic peace is about conflict management rather than dispute occurrence, since all the variants explain behaviors in terms of “when some disagreements occur between democracies.” In effect, the probability of a MID per se is extremely low in the dyadic sense (Spiro 1994; King and Zeng 2001). Thus, the real pacifying effect of democracy will be conspicuous when democracies have conflicting interests to manage over certain issues.

96

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict TABLE 2. Probit Models of MID Onset, All Dyads (1920–1996)† Model 1

DEMOCRACY TERRITORY DEMOCRACY 9 TERRITORY Capability Ratio Contiguity Distance Major Power Alliance Previous MIDs Peace Years Peace Years2 Peace Years3 Initial Democracy Constant N Log-Pseudo-L Pseudo-R2 BIC

Model 2

0.469 (0.087)**** 0.595 (0.061)****

0.386 (0.081)**** 0.625 (0.060)**** 0.410 (0.204)**

0.055 0.811 0.180 0.819 0.093 0.068 0.022 0.000 0.000

0.054 0.807 0.182 0.818 0.094 0.068 0.022 0.000 0.000

(0.011)**** (0.056)**** (0.020)**** (0.047)**** (0.051)* (0.010)**** (0.003)**** (0.000)*** (0.000)***

1.372 (0.158)**** 496,443 7154.429 .363 14466.240

(0.011)**** (0.056)**** (0.020)**** (0.047)**** (0.051)* (0.010)**** (0.003)**** (0.000)**** (0.000)***

1.367 (0.158)**** 496,443 7148.222 .363 14466.943

Model 3 0.387 (0.081)**** 0.632 (0.062)**** 0.266 (0.254) 0.055 0.807 0.183 0.822 0.094 0.067 0.022 0.000 0.000 0.212 1.362 496,443 7146.999 .364 14477.610

(0.011)**** (0.056)**** (0.020)**** (0.048)**** (0.051)* (0.010)**** (0.003)*** (0.000)*** (0.000)*** (0.283) (0.159)****

(Notes. BIC, Bayesian information criteria; MID, Militarized Interstate Dispute. *p < .1, **p < .05, ***p < .01, and ****p < .001 (two-tailed). Robust standard errors, adjusted for clustering on dyad, are in parentheses. † Because we employed the 1-year lag structure, we predict MIDs that had occurred from 1920 to 1996 with the information on the independent variables for 1919–1995.)

in the context of democratic dyads. As for DEMOCRACY, its negative coefficient is greater for territorial dyads ( .796 = .386 + .410) than nonterritorial dyads ( .386) as described in Figure 1A-a. This heightened effect of DEMOCRACY is also apparent in terms of predicted probability.15 As described in Figure 1A-b, the vertical distance that denotes the difference in predicted probability of conflict between democratic dyads and nondemocratic dyads is greater for territorial dyads than nonterritorial dyads. Substantively, democratic dyads are about four times less likely to experience an MID than nondemocratic dyads in the absence of territorial claims—that is, a decrease by a factor of 4. Note that DEMOCRACY decreases the probability of MID onset by a factor of 11.3 in the presence of territorial claims. With respect to the effect of territorial issues, which is central to the territorial explanation, territorial issues increase the likelihood of armed conflict for nondemocratic dyads. This, however, is not the case with democratic dyads. DEMOCRACY appears to significantly weaken the effect of TERRITORY. As shown in Figure 1B-a, the estimated negative coefficient of TERRITORY is only significant for nondemocratic dyads. In terms of predicted probability, the difference in predicted probability of conflict between territorial dyads and nonterritorial dyads is much larger for nondemocratic dyads than for democratic dyads as described in Figure 1B-b. Substantively, territorial claims increase the likelihood of MID onset by a factor of 7.8 for nondemocratic dyads. In sum, the findings suggest two things: (i) the pacifying effect of joint democracy holds regardless of the presence of territorial claims, but the effect gets stronger in a territorial context; (ii) the conflict-generating effect of territorial 15 For all the analyses of predicted probabilities and relative risks, we have used CLARIFY (Tomz, Wittenberg, and King 2003). We set all continuous control variables at their median and dummy control variables at their modal category.

J OHANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AMES

97

A Contingent Effect of DEMOCRACY .006

a Change in Coefficient

b Change in Probability

Coeff. of Democracy | Terr. Claim

Difference in Coefficient

-1.2

-1

-.8

-.6

-.4

-.2

0

.2

0

Probability of MID .002 .004

Coeff. of Democracy | No Terr. Claim

Coefficient of Democracy Mean Coefficient.

Nondem. Dyad

Nondem. Dyad Dem. Dyad No Territorial Claim

95% Confidence Interval

Mean Probability.

Dem. Dyad Territorial Claim 95% Confidence Interval

B Contingent Effect of TERRITORY .006

a Change in Coefficient

b Change in Probability

Probability of MID .004 .002

Coeff. of Territory | Nondem. Dyad

Coeff. of Territory | Dem. Dyad

Difference in Coefficient

Terr. Claim

-.5

0

.5

1

Coefficient of Territory Mean Coefficient

95% Confidence Interval

1.5

0

No terr. Claim -1

Nondemocratic Dyad Mean Probability

Terr. Claim No Terr. Claim Democratic Dyad 95% Confidence Interval

FIG 1. Contingent Effects of (A) DEMOCRACY and (B) TERRITORY, All Dyads (Notes. (a) The dot in the first row marks the estimated coefficient for DEMOCRACY (TERRITORY) when TERRITORY (DEMOCRACY) is set at 0. The dot in the second row is for the estimated coefficient of DEMOCRACY (TERRITORY) when TERRITORY (DEMOCRACY) is set at 1. The third row denotes the difference in coefficient for DEMOCRACY (TERRITORY) across the value of TERRITORY (DEMOCRACY). The horizontal bars represent the confidence intervals for the estimated coefficients. (b) Each dot denotes the estimated probability point of Militarized Interstate Dispute (MID) onset for a given combination of DEMOCRACY and TERRITORY. Each vertical bar represents the confidence interval for a given point estimate.)

issues holds only for nondemocratic dyads. These results support the selectorate theory hypothesis (H3) that, unlike nondemocratic dyads, democratic dyads are not likely to use force for territorial issues. In Model 3, we control for the regime type of the claimants at the start of territorial claims (that is, initial democracy). Hensel, Goertz, and Diehl (2000:1179) find significantly fewer rivalry relationships than expected for pairs of states that start off as democracies. The resulting expectation in the present context is that the existence of democracy in a dyad from the outset of a territorial claim should have a pacifying effect. As it turns out, DEMOCRACY is statistically significant for both nonterritorial dyads with the coefficient of .387 and p-value < .001 and for territorial dyads with the coefficient of .654 (that is, .3874103 + .2664173) and p-value of .003. Yet, the interactive term (that is, DEMOCRACY 9 TERRITORY) is not statistically significant, suggesting that the pacifying effect of democracy does not meaningfully vary by the absence and presence of a territorial claim between two states. This also suggests that the conflict-generating effect of territorial claims does not vary by the regime type of dyads. Territorial claims increase the likelihood of an MID both for democratic dyads and for nondemocratic dyads. The insignificant result for the interaction of DEMOCRACY and TERRITORY is inconsistent with our previous result. However, tests do not support the

98

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict TABLE 3. Probit Models of MID Onset, Relevant Dyads (1920–1996)† Model 1

DEMOCRACY TERRITORY DEMOCRACY 9 TERRITORY Capability Ratio Contiguity Distance Major Power Alliance Previous MIDs Peace Years Peace Years2 Peace Years3 Initial Democracy Constant N Log Pseudo L Pseudo R2 BIC

Model 2

0.435 (0.072)**** 0.531 (0.053)****

0.410 (0.077)**** 0.538 (0.054)**** 0.119 (0.171)

0.076 0.506 0.039 0.297 0.084 0.060 0.029 0.000 0.000

0.076 0.507 0.040 0.298 0.083 0.060 0.029 0.000 0.000

(0.012)**** (0.058)**** (0.024)* (0.057)**** (0.049)* (0.008)**** (0.004)**** (0.000)**** (0.000)***

1.681 (0.171)**** 59,298 5402.075 .223 10936.033

(0.012)**** (0.058)**** (0.024)* (0.057)**** (0.049)* (0.008)**** (0.004)*** (0.000)**** (0.000)***

1.679 (0.171)**** 59,298 5401.606 .223 10946.085

Model 3 0.410 (0.077)**** 0.538 (0.056)**** 0.127 (0.195) 0.076 0.507 0.040 0.298 0.083 0.060 0.029 0.000 0.000 0.127 1.679 59,298 5401.601 .223 10957.067

(0.012)**** (0.058)**** (0.024)* (0.058)**** (0.049)* (0.008)**** (0.004)*** (0.000)**** (0.000)*** (0.199) (0.173)****

(Notes. BIC, Bayesian information criteria; MID, Militarized Interstate Dispute. *p < .1, **p < .05, ***p < .01, and ****p < .001 (two-tailed). Robust standard errors, adjusted for clustering on dyad, are in parentheses. † Because we employed the 1-year lag structure, we predict MIDs that had occurred from 1920 to 1996 with the information on the independent variables for 1919–1995.)

specification of Model 3 that includes initial democracy. First, a Wald test result (test statistic = .57 with p-value of .45) fails to reject the null hypothesis that the effect of initial democracy is equal to 0. This result is consistent with the insignificant coefficient estimated for initial democracy in Model 3. Second, the model fit statistic based on the Bayesian information criteria (BIC) strongly supports Model 2 excluding initial democracy over Model 3 including it (see the last row in Table 2).16 Politically Relevant Dyads

Some argue for use of politically relevant dyads as having a reasonable chance of disagreements and conflicts despite the weaknesses of this alternative noted above. Yet, to examine whether territorial issues make any change for the wellconfirmed effect of joint democracy among conflict-ridden dyads, we conduct a robustness check for this subset of dyads (Table 3).17 Briefly, many results are similar to the ones reported in the previous analysis, but one important qualification occurs. In any case, the results do not suggest that the democratic peace is bounded by or epiphenomenal to territorial issues as some critics have argued (e.g., James et al. 2006; Gibler 2007). First, each of DEMOCRACY and TERRITORY remains an important independent predictor of conflict controlling for the other (Model 1). Second, the effect of DEMOCRACY is estimated to be larger for territorial dyads than nonterritorial dyads (Model 2 and Figure 2A). However, this difference in coefficient is not statistically significant as shown in Model 2 (see also the third row in Figure 2A), suggesting 16 The lower the BIC, the better the fit. An absolute difference of over 10 in BIC is the rule of thumb for the strength of evidence favoring one model over the other. 17 We define politically relevant dyads as those in which two states are within 400 miles of water and at least one country holds a major power status according to the COW project’s designation.

J OHANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AMES

99

A Interactive Coefficients for DEMOCRACY

Coeff. of Democracy | No Terr. Claim

Coeff. of Democracy | Terr. Claim

Difference in Coefficient

-1

-.8

-.6

-.4

-.2

0

.2

.4

Coefficient of Democracy Mean Coefficient.

95% Confidence Interval

B Interactive Coefficients for TERRITORY

Coeff. of Territory | Nondem. Dyad

Coeff. of Territory | Dem. Dyad

Difference in Coefficient

-.6

-.4

-.2

0

.2

.4

.6

.8

1

Coefficient of Territory Mean Coefficient

95% Confidence Interval

FIG 2. Contingent Effects of (A) DEMOCRACY and (B) TERRITORY, Relevant Dyads

DEMOCRACY reduces armed conflict indifferently for territorial dyads and nonterritorial dyads. Similarly, the effect of territorial claims appears to be weaker for democratic dyads than nondemocratic dyads (the first and second rows in Figure 2B). But, the estimated difference is not statistically significant (the third row in Figure 2B), suggesting that DEMOCRACY does not lessen the conflict-generating effect of TERRITORY among politically relevant dyads. This may be because territorial disputes between two countries that are politically relevant are more salient than those between presumably irrelevant dyads. The salience of issues at stake seems to be the key to the variation in how democracies manage those issues. We address this point in the next section. Democracy and Issue Salience

Territorial claims do not all have equal importance (see Hensel 2001). As such, our previous analyses found that, in the sample of all dyads, TERRITORY is not

100

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict

a significant predictor of conflict for democratic dyads unlike nondemocratic counterparts and that DEMOCRACY has a larger conflict-reducing effect for territorial dyads than nonterritorial dyads. However, among politically relevant dyads, TERRITORY generates armed conflict for democratic dyads as much as nondemocratic dyads, while DEMOCRACY abates conflict, to a similar degree, for both territorial dyads and nonterritorial dyads. These results seem to support the selectorate theory rather than the information theory because the former predicts that the more salient an issue is, the less the pacific effect of DEMOCRACY becomes, whereas the latter predicts the opposite. Notwithstanding, one can infer differently from the preceding results. Politically relevant dyads are conflict-ridden. Many of them may have nonterritorial but salient issues. Within the sample of relevant dyads, territorial dyads may not be particularly contentious as compared to nonterritorial dyads. Thus, it may not be clear whether our previous results really support the selectorate theory— democracies devalue territorial issues—over the information model—democracy is increasingly a conflict managing (rather than disagreement-inhibiting) factor when a salient issue arises. It is important to consider issue salience if it is really true that territorial disputes of democratic dyads tend to be minor as some skeptics suggest. However, two difficulties arise. First, Huth and Allee’s (2002) data set does not include a measure for salience, although it does identify types of territorial claims according to whether or not economic, strategic, ethnic, or no explicitly identified values are entailed.18 Second, even if such a measure were available, it is not easy to include salience in this present study whose aim is to assess the interactive effect of DEMOCRACY and TERRITORY. For that purpose, the universe of our data must include dyads without territorial claims as well as those with territorial claims. It would be ideal to categorize all dyads into those with no issues, those with low-salience issues, and those with high-salience issues. However, currently there is no such overarching data available. Although not tailored to our present purposes, the ICOW project has collected still valuable information on three kinds of contentious issues: maritime, river, and territorial claims and their salience (Hensel, Mitchell, Sowers, and Thyne 2008). This information allows us to test the two contrasting expectations from the information model and the selectorate theory on how the effect of DEMOCRACY on armed conflict varies by the salience of issues at stake. Using the ICOW claims data, we identify dyad years in which dyads are involved in territorial, river, and/or maritime claims in our data set with an expanded time period (1816–2001). All other dyad years in our data are excluded from the analyses. The ICOW project identifies (i) 192 dyadic territorial claims in the Western Hemisphere and Western Europe from 1816 to 2001; (ii) 82 dyadic river claims in the Western Hemisphere, Western Europe, and Middle East from 1900 to 2001; and (iii) 143 dyadic maritime claims in the Western Hemisphere and Europe from 1900 to 2001. It is possible that the same dyad is involved in multiple claims in a given year. In those cases, we include only observations that have the highest salience score in a given dyad year to avoid violating the independence assumption across observations (Bennett and Stam 2000; Park and Colaresi 2014). We include ICOW’s salience index (SALIENCE) that measures 18 We ran a robustness check, differentiating types of territorial claims since certain types of territorial disputes may have more salient effect and the impact of democracy may be contingent upon certain salient types of territorial claims. Territorial claims can be categorized as having either no identified value or having economic, strategic, ethnic values, or some combination of those values (Huth and Allee 2002). We first assessed the net effects that different types of territorial claims have on MIDs. Then we compared these net effects to identify which types of territorial claims have the most effects on MIDs. Using the lincom command in Stata, we found that while all kinds of territorial claims increase the probability of a MID, in general, none of these issues have a significantly larger impact than the other types.

J O HANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AM ES

101

TABLE 4. Probit Models of MID Onset for ICOW Dyads Model 1 DEMOCRACY SALIENCE DEMOCRACY 9 SALIENCE Capability Ratio Contiguity Distance Major Power Alliance Previous MIDs Peace Years Peace Years2 Peace Years3 Constant N Log Pseudo L Pseudo R2 BIC

0.201 (0.092)** 0.027 (0.015)*

0.044 0.034 0.007 0.050 0.039 0.035 0.048 0.001 0.000 1.222 7,210 1602.613 .120 3311.825

(0.023)* (0.134) (0.055) (0.091) (0.067) (0.008)**** (0.007)**** (0.000)**** (0.000)*** (0.409)***

Model 2

Model 3

0.225 (0.088)** 0.028 (0.014)**

0.790 (0.231)**** 0.019 (0.014) 0.075 (0.029)**

0.055 (0.019)*** 0.034 (0.008)***

0.058 (0.019)***

0.034 0.049 0.001 0.000 1.246 7,210 1603.661 .120 3278.387

(0.008)**** (0.007)**** (0.000)**** (0.000)**** (0.167)****

0.034 0.049 0.001 0.000 1.178 7,210 1600.884 .121 3281.717

(0.008)**** (0.007)**** (0.000)**** (0.000)**** (0.165)****

(Notes. BIC, Bayesian information criteria; MID, Militarized Interstate Dispute. *p < .1, **p < .05, ***p < .01, and ****p < .001 (two-tailed). Robust standard errors, adjusted for clustering on dyad, are in parentheses.)

the importance of each claim on a 0–12 scale (see Hensel et al. 2008). We also create a multiplicative interaction term for DEMOCRACY and SALIENCE (that is, DEMOCRACY 9 SALIENCE) to assess how they interact in impacting upon armed conflict (Table 4). We first estimate the net independent effects of DEMOCRACY and SALIENCE. As expected, both measures affect the probability of MID onset significantly. Not surprisingly, the geopolitical controls, such as contiguity, distance, major power status, and alliance, are insignificant in this limited sample of dyads with issue claims. Since both the BIC and Wald test prefer the reduced model without these insignificant controls, we exclude them in the interactive model (that is, Model 2). Taking these insignificant variables out of the model improves the significance level for SALIENCE from the .1 to .05 level. In Model 3, a significant interaction is found between DEMOCRACY and SALIENCE—the estimated coefficient for the interaction term is .075 with a pvalue of .011. The positive coefficient indicates that the pacifying effect of DEMOCRACY decreases over the level of issue salience. A MID is less likely to occur between two issue claimants if they are democracies rather than autocracies, but this pacific democratic relationship ceases to be the case when their issue is highly salient. The negative coefficient of DEMOCRACY becomes insignificant at the salience score of 9 and even its sign is reversed at 11 as captured in Figure 3A. This result holds also in terms of predicted probability as shown in Figure 3C. The difference in conflict propensity between democratic dyads and nondemocratic dyads disappears when an issue involved is highly salient. DEMOCRACY abates conflict by a factor of about 3.7 for low issue salience (that is, SALIENCE = 3), whereas the equivalent factorial change becomes insubstantial (a factor of 1.25) for high issue salience (that is, SALIENCE = 9). Figure 3B describes the impact of SALIENCE conditional upon DEMOCRACY. SALIENCE only significantly increases conflict propensity for dyads of democratic claimants, whereas it does not have a significant impact for nondemocratic counterparts. For nondemocratic dyads, the negative coefficient for SALIENCE

102

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict B Change in Coefficient (SALIENCE)

.5

A Change in Coefficient (DEMOCRACY)

-.5

Coeff. of Salience | Dem. Dyad

Difference in Coefficient -1

Coeff. of Democracy

0

Coeff. of Salience | Nondem. Dyad

Mean Coefficient

95% Confidence Interval

95% Confidence Interval

-1.5

Mean Coefficient

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

-.05

0

.05

Issue Salience

.1

.15

.2

Coefficient of Salience

.1

.12

C Predicted Probabilities of MID Onset Contingent upon DEMOCRACY and SALIENCE

Democracy

.06 0

.02

.04

Prob. of MID

.08

Nondemocracy

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

Issue Salience

FIG 3. Contingent Effects of DEMOCRACY and SALIENCE, ICOW Dyads (Notes. (A) The dots and vertical bars represent the mean coefficients for DEMOCRACY and their 95% confidence intervals across the levels of SALIENCE. (B) The dot and horizontal bar in the first (second) row mark the mean coefficient for issue salience and its 95% confidence interval for nondemocratic (democratic dyads). The third row is for the difference in coefficient for SALIENCE across dyadic regime types. (C) The solid line traces the mean probabilities of MID onset for democratic dyads with their 95% confidence intervals across the levels of SALIENCE. The dashed line is for nondemocratic dyads.)

is relatively small and its 95% confidence interval includes 0 in the first row of Figure 3B. This result also is visible in the plot of predicted probabilities (that is, Figure 3C). The dashed middle line that traces the mean probabilities of MID for democratic dyads across the levels of SALIENCE is positively steeper than the solid middle line for nondemocratic dyads. For democratic dyads, moving from the minimum to maximum salience score heightens the likelihood of conflict by about 13 times (that is, 13 factorial change). By contrast, the equivalent change in issue salience only results in a 1.6 factorial increase in the probability of MID onset for nondemocratic dyads. Taken together, these results support the selectorate theory that democracies are no less willing to use force against each other when the issue at stake is highly salient (Bueno de Mesquita et al. 2003). Unlike the expectation implied by the information perspective, the audience cost presumably heightened by high issue salience does not strengthen the pacifying impact of democracy. Indeed, considering issue salience is important in assessing how democracies handle their contentious issues as Ellis et al. (2010) suggest. Based on the ICOW data sets, they find that, the more salient an issue, the more democratic dyads

J O HANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AM ES

103

are likely to engage in settlement efforts by bilateral negotiations or military means. Conclusion Democracy matters in international conflict processes, based on the results obtained here for MIDs, even in the presence of territorial issues. To summarize, we found that armed conflicts are less likely between democratic dyads than nondemocratic dyads even in the presence of territorial claims, and such difference in conflict proclivities becomes wider. Yet territorial issues, which reign supreme in the steps-to-war explanation (Vasquez 2009), do result in more MIDs even for democratic dyads that are politically relevant. The results show the extraordinary power of democratic institutions to influence conflict processes even under the most challenging conditions. It is especially interesting that the pacifying effect of joint democracy is greater for territorial disagreements in the sense that the gap in conflict propensities between democratic dyads and nondemocratic ones is wider for territorial than for nonterritorial disputes. This result should be assessed with caution in that, because of data availability, the nonterritorial dyads in our sample do not differentiate dyads with other serious issues from those that are relatively conflict-free. New directions for research are suggested by these interesting results in the nexus of democracy and territory and their qualifications regarding politically relevant dyads. All of the data analyses should be replicated when, as noted above, the ICOW data set that attempts to identify several outstanding issues at stake in interstate relations is complete (that is, available on a worldwide basis). Further tests for robustness of results are in order. For example, additional economic variables (e.g., Mousseau 2009:55–57) could be added to the research design. Also, probing a subset of difficult disagreements could produce results more favorable to an issue-based approach. The presence of rivalry in one research design, for example, attenuated the impact of joint democracy in dampening dispute escalation (Lektzian et al. 2010). Will the democratic peace thesis, which performs so well in the present research design, hold up under further testing that includes a wider range of issue variables and their interactions? Another question concerns salience and (in)tangible issues in relation to conflict escalation and management. Further analysis of democracy and territory in combination should take that into account. It could be revealing to probe further into how, once they are involved in MIDs, territorial issues affect democratic dyads regarding escalation into a full-scale war, using a research design similar to Senese (1997), Reed (2000), or Senese and Vasquez (2003). The same can be said about the nascent research program that brings together territory, democracy, and rivalry (Lektzian et al. 2010). Potential causal processes embedded in statistical findings deserve closer inspection through case studies. This is relevant to contemporary and future conflict management as well. For instance, what can be expected among Canada, Russia, the United States and other states if climate change produces new sea routes in the high Arctic? At the other end of the earth, sovereignty in Antarctica continues to produce controversy. And at many points in between, such as Gibraltar vis-a-vis Spain and Britain, tension either is intermittent or ongoing. Thus, it would be interesting to look at “deviant” territorial claims—those that do not go to MIDs and interdemocratic MIDs that do not go to war—in a case study format. Consider the especially interesting and somewhat anomalous case of jointly democratic Ecuador and Peru, identified by Hensel et al. (2000:1186), for its MIDs in 1981, 1984, and 1991.19 These MIDs came significantly after both states 19

For more detailed treatments of this case, see Elbow (1996), St. John (1996), and Palmer (1997).

104

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict

had transitioned into democracy; each scores 7 or above from 1980 to 1992. Why did these MIDs occur in spite of democratization? Elbow (1996:103) points to the compelling role of the “iconography of lost territories,” particularly in Ecuador. The territorial conflict with Ecuador seemed to have gone away with the Rio Protocol of 1942 (St. John 1996:78). Yet, according to Elbow (1996), state and society combined in Ecuador to keep the idea of territorial revisionism alive through a focus on perceived historical injustice from the prior settlement. A causal mechanism of this kind, it almost goes without saying, cannot be studied with ease through a large N approach, even with useful data such as that of MID or ICOW. Instead, it makes sense to identify anomalies for comparative analysis through process tracing in order to understand why unexpected events sometimes occur, which in turn may help to verify why many other things happen as expected vis-a-vis the interaction of democracy with territory in relation to MIDs. In closing, it is hoped that the present study will encourage efforts to look further into the combination of territory and democracy as key variables in the explanation of international conflict processes. References ALVAREZ, MICHAEL, JOSE ANTONIO CHEIBUB, FERNANDO LIMONGI, AND ADAM PRZEWORSKI. (1996) Classifying Political Regimes. Studies in Comparative International Development 31: 3–36. BECK, NATHANIEL, JONATHAN KATZ, AND RICHARD TUCKER. (1998) Taking Time Seriously: Time-SeriesCross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable. American Journal of Political Science 42: 1260–1288. BENNETT, D. SCOTT, AND ALLAN STAM. (2000) Eugene: A Conceptual Manual. International Interactions 26: 179–204. BENOIT, KENNETH. (1996) Democracies Really Are More Pacific (in General): Reexamining Regime Type and War Involvement. Journal of Conflict Resolution 40: 636–657. BREMER, STUART. (1980) National Capabilities and War Proneness. In The Correlates of War II: Testing Some Realpolitik Models, edited by J. David Singer. New York: Free Press. BREMER, STUART A. (1992) Dangerous Dyads: Conditions Affecting the Likelihood of Interstate War, 1816–1965. Journal of Conflict Resolution 36: 309–341. BUENO DE MESQUITA, BRUCE, AND RANDOLPH SIVERSON. (1997) Institutions and the Issues of Conflict: A Further Test. Paper Presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago. BUENO DE MESQUITA, BUENO, ALASTAIR SMITH, RANDOLPH M. SIVERSON, AND JAMES D. MORROW. (2003) The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. CARTER, DAVID B. (2010) The Strategy of Territorial Conflict. American Journal of Political Science 54: 969–987. CARTER, DAVID B., AND CURTIS S. SIGNORINO. (2010) Back to the Future: Modeling Time Dependence in Binary Data. Political Analysis 18: 271–292. CHOI, SEUNG-WHAN. (2011) Re-Evaluating Capitalist and Democratic Peace Models. International Studies Quarterly 49: 407–422. DAFOE, ALLAN. (2011) Statistical Critiques of the Democratic Peace: Caveat Emptor. American Journal of Political Science 55: 247–262. DIEHL, PAUL F. (1992) What Are They Fighting For? The Importance of Issues in International Conflict Research. Journal of Peace Research 29: 333–344. ELBOW, GARY S. (1996) Territorial Loss and National Image: The Case of Ecuador. Yearbook: Conference of Latin Americanist Geographers 22: 93–105. ELLIS, GLYNN, SARA MITCHELL, AND BRANDON PRINS. (2010) How Democracies Keep the Peace: Contextual Factors That Influence Conflict Management Strategies. Foreign Policy Analysis 6: 373– 398. FEARON, JAMES D. (1994) Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes. The American Political Science Review 88: 577–592. GARTZKE, ERIK. (1998) Kant We All Just Get Along? Motive, Opportunity, and the Origins of the Democratic Peace. American Journal of Political Science 42: 1–27. GARTZKE, ERIK. (2007) The Capitalist Peace. American Journal of Political Science 51: 166–191.

J O HANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AM ES

105

GEDDES, BARBARA. (1990) How the Cases You Choose Affect the Answers You Get: Selection Bias in Comparative Politics. Political Analysis 2: 131–150. GIBLER, DOUGLAS M. (2007) Bordering on Peace: Democracy, Territorial Issues, and Conflict. International Studies Quarterly 51: 509–532. GOWA, JOANNE. (2011) The Democratic Peace After the Cold War. Economics & Politics 23: 153–171. HENSEL, PAUL R. (2001) Contentious Issues and World Politics: The Management of Territorial Claims in the Americas, 1816–1992. International Studies Quarterly 45: 81–109. HENSEL, PAUL R., GARY GOERTZ, AND PAUL DIEHL. (2000) The Democratic Peace and Rivalries. Journal of Politics 62: 1173–1188. HENSEL, PAUL R., AND SARA MC LAUGHLIN MITCHELL. (2005) Issue Indivisibility and Territorial Claims. GeoJournal 64: 275–285. HENSEL, PAUL R., SARA MCLAUGHLIN MITCHELL, THOMAS E. SOWERS II, AND CLAYTON L. THYNE. (2008) Bones of Contention: Comparing Territorial, Maritime and River Issues. Journal of Conflict Resolution 52: 117–143. HOLSTI, KALEVI JAAKKO. (1991) Peace and War: Armed Conflicts and International Order, 1648–1989. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. HUTH, PAUL K. (1998) Standing Your Ground: Territorial Disputes and International Conflict. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. HUTH, PAUL K. (2000) Territory: Why Are Territorial Disputes between States a Central Cause of International Conflict? In What Do We Know about War?, edited by John A. Vasquez. Boston: Rowman & Littlefield. HUTH, PAUL K., AND TODD L. ALLEE. (2002) The Democratic Peace and Territorial Conflict in the Twentieth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. HUTH, PAUL K., SARAH E. CROCO, AND BENJAMIN J. APPEL. (2011) Does International Law Promote the Peaceful Settlement of International Disputes? Evidence from the Study of Territorial Conflicts Since 1945. American Political Science Review 105: 415–436. JAGGERS, KEITH, AND TEDD ROBERT GURR. (1995) Tracking Democracy’s Third Wave with the Polity III Data. Journal of Peace Research 32: 469–482. JAMES, PATRICK, JOHANN PARK, AND SEUNG-WHAN CHOI. (2006) Democracy and Conflict Management: Territorial Claims in the Western Hemisphere Revisited. International Studies Quarterly 50: 803– 817. JONES, DANIEL M., STUART A. BREMER, AND J. DAVID SINGER. (1996) Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816– 1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns. Conflict Management and Peace Science 15: 163–213. KACOWICZ, ARIE M. (1995) Explaining Zones of Peace: Democracies as Satisfied Powers? Journal of Peace Research 32: 265–276. KEOHANE, ROBERT O. (1984) After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. KING, GARY, AND LANGCHE ZENG. (2001) Explaining Rare Events in International Relations. International Organization 55: 693–715. KINSELLA, DAVID, AND BRUCE RUSSETT. (2002) Conflict Emergence and Escalation in Interactive International Dyads. Journal of Politics 64: 1045–1068. KRASNER, STEPHEN D. (1982) Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables. International Organization 36: 185–205. KUGLER, JACEK, AND DOUGLAS LEMKE. (1996) Parity and War: Evaluations and Extensions of the War Ledger. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. LAKE, DAVID. (1992) Powerful Pacifists: Democratic States and War. The American Political Science Review 86: 24–37. LEEDS, BRETT ASHLEY. (2003) Alliance Reliability in Times of War: Explaining State Decisions to Violate Treaties. International Organization 57: 801–827. LEEDS, BRETT ASHLEY, AND DAVID R. DAVIS. (1999) Beneath the Surface: Regime Type and International Interaction, 1953–78. Journal of Conflict Resolution 36: 5–21. LEKTZIAN, DAVID, BRANDON C. PRINS, AND MARK SOUVA. (2010) Territory, River, and Maritime Claims in the Western Hemisphere: Regime Type, Rivalry, and MIDs from 1901 to 2000. International Studies Quarterly 54: 1073–1098. LEKTZIAN, DAVID, AND MARK SOUVA. (2009) A Comparative Theory Test of Democratic Peace Arguments, 1946–2000. Journal of Peace Research 45: 613–631. LEMKE, DOUGLAS, AND WILLIAM REED. (2001) The Relevance of Politically Relevant Dyads. Journal of Conflict Resolution 45: 126–144. LEVY, JACK S. (1988) Domestic Politics and War. The Journal of Interdisciplinary History 18: 653–673.

106

Democracy, Territory, and Conflict

LEVY, JACK S. (2002) Qualitative Methods in International Relations. In Millennial Reflections on International Studies, edited by Michael Brecher and Frank P. Harvey. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. MAOZ, ZEEV, AND NASRIN ABDOLALI. (1989) Regime Types and International Conflict, 1816–1976. Journal of Conflict Resolution 33: 3–35. MARSHALL, MONTY G., AND KEITH JAGGERS. (2002) Polity IV Project: Dataset Users Manual. College Park: University of Maryland. MITCHELL, SARA MC LAUGHLIN, AND BRANDON PRINS. (1999) Beyond Territorial Contiguity: Issues at Stake in Democratic Militarized Disputes. International Studies Quarterly 43: 169–183. MOUSSEAU, MICHAEL. (2009) The Social Market Roots of Democratic Peace. International Security 33: 52–86. MURPHY, ALEXANDER. (1990) Historical Justifications for Territorial Claims. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 80: 531–648. NORTH, DOUGLASS C. (1981) Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton. PALMER, DAVID SCOTT. (1997) Peru-Ecuador Border Conflict: Missed Opportunities, Misplaced Nationalism, and Multilateral Peacekeeping. Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs 39: 109–148. PARK, JOHANN. (2013) Forward to the Future: The Democratic Peace After the Cold War. Conflict Management and Peace Science 30: 178–194. PARK, JOHANN, AND MICHAEL COLARESI. (2014) Safe Across the Border: The Continued Significance of the Democratic Peace When Controlling for Stable Borders. International Studies Quarterly (forthcoming). RASLER, KAREN, AND WILLIAM R. THOMPSON. (2001) Rivalries and the Democratic Peace in the Major Power Subsystem. Journal of Peace Research 38: 659–683. RAY, JAMES LEE. (1995) Democracy and International Conflict: An Evaluation of the Democratic Peace Proposition. Columbia: University of South Carolina Press. RAY, JAMES LEE. (2000) Democracy: On the Level(s): Does Democracy Correlate with Peace. In What Do We Know About War?, edited by John A. Vasquez. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield. REED, WILLIAM. (2000) A Unified Statistical Model of Conflict Onset and Escalation. American Journal of Political Science 44: 84–93. REED, WILLIAM, AND DAINA CHIBA. (2010) Decomposing the Relationship Between Contiguity and Militarized Conflict. American Journal of Political Science 54: 61–73. RUSSETT, BRUCE M., AND JOHN R. ONEAL. (2001) Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations. New York: Norton. SCHULTZ, KENNETH A. (1999) Do Democratic Institutions Constrain or Inform? Contrasting Two Institutional Perspectives on Democracy and War. International Organization 53: 233–266. SENESE, PAUL D. (1997) Between Dispute and War: The Effect of Joint Democracy on Interstate Conflict Escalation. The Journal of Politics 59: 1–27. SENESE, PAUL D., AND JOHN A. VASQUEZ. (2003) A Unified Explanation of Territorial Conflict: Testing the Impact of Sampling Bias, 1919–1992. International Studies Quarterly 47: 275–298. SENESE, PAUL D., AND JOHN A. VASQUEZ. (2005) Assessing the Steps to War. British Journal of Political Science 35: 607–633. SENESE, PAUL D., AND JOHN A. VASQUEZ. (2008) The Steps to War: An Empirical Study. Princeton: Princeton University Press. SIMMONS, BETH. (2005) Rules over Real Estate: Trade, Territorial Conflict and International Borders as Institutions. Journal of Conflict Resolution 49: 823–848. SINGER, J. DAVID, STUART BREMER, AND JOHN STUCKEY. (1972) Capability Distribution, Uncertainty, and Major Power War. In Peace, War and Numbers, edited by Bruce M. Russett. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications. SMALL, MELVIN, AND J. DAVID SINGER. (1976) The War Proneness of Democratic Regimes. Jerusalem Journal of International Relations 1: 50–69. SOUVA, MARK, AND BRANDON PRINS. (2006) The Liberal Peace Revisited: Democracy, Dependence, and Development in Militarized Interstate Dispute Initiation, 1950–1999. International Interactions 32: 183–200. SPIRO, DAVID E. (1994) The Insignificance of the Liberal Peace. International Security 19: 50–86. ST. JOHN, RONALD BRUCE. (1996) Conflict in the Cordillera del C ondor: The Ecuador-Peru Dispute. IBRU Boundary and Security Bulletin 4: 78–85. TOMZ, MICHAEL, JASON WITTENBERG, AND GARY KING. (2003) CLARIFY: Software for Interpreting and Presenting Statistical Results. Journal of Statistical Software 8 (1). Available at http://www.jstat soft.org/v08/i01/paper.

J O HANN P ARK

AND

P ATRICK J AM ES

107

VASQUEZ, JOHN A. (1993) The War Puzzle. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. VASQUEZ, JOHN A. (1995) Why Do Neighbors Fight? Proximity, Interaction, or Territoriality. Journal of Peace Research 32: 277–293. VASQUEZ, JOHN A. (2009) The War Puzzle Revisited. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. WENDT, ALEXANDER. (1992) Anarchy is What States Make of It: The Social Construction of Power Politics. International Organization 46: 391–425.

Democracy, Territory, and Armed Conflict, 1919–

of territorial conflict are confirmed through data analysis and provide an example of how the range of territory- related propositions ...... United States/Spain. (1923–1931, 1938–1970). Portugal/Indonesia. (1975–95). 4,418 (100%) (0.89%). No Territorial. Claim Years. 36,430 (7.40%). (98.74%). Colombia/Venezuela.

250KB Sizes 0 Downloads 186 Views

Recommend Documents

Democracy, Territory, and Armed Conflict ... - Wiley Online Library
Results based on Militarized Inter- state Dispute data from 1920 to 1996 produce the conclusion that the pacifying effect of democracy stands up for both territorial dyads and non- territorial ones in spite of the imperatives toward militarization cr

Democracy and Conflict Management: Territorial ...
democratic adversaries' strategies to manage and even settle territorial conflicts. Hensel finds (1) that not all ... through settlement attempts by resorting to peaceful means or armed force, and escalates to further ... explanations center on the a

Illicit Crops and Armed Conflict as Constraints on ...
toward hiding new coca fields (in remote sites and among other crops) in the ..... provided information from Peru and from European Union policy meetings. 66.

Political Openness and Armed Conflict: Evidence from ...
Thus, I classify the following parties as having paramilltary links: Movimiento Colombia Viva, Partido Colombia Democratica, Partido Convergencia Ciudadana,. Movimiento Alas-Equipo Colombia, Movimiento Apertura Liberal, Movimiento Convergencia Popula

Review of "Democracy and Moral Conflict"
Jan 31, 2013 - Essays in Philosophy is a biannual journal published by Pacific University Library | ISSN 1526-0569 | http://commons.pacificu.edu/eip/. Recommended Citation. Ross, Steven (2013) "Review of "Democracy and Moral Conflict"," Essays in Phi

Review of "Democracy and Moral Conflict"
Hunter College and The Graduate Center/CUNY. Follow this and additional .... pluralism not involves respecting the plurality of live options in moral theory among reasonable persons, it also calls us to engage our differences…It is precisely ...

pdf-1856\armed-conflict-the-lessons-of-modern-warfare-by ...
Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. pdf-1856\armed-conflict-the-lessons-of-modern-warfare-by-brian-steed-2003-01-01-by-brian-steed.pdf.

Armed-With-Cameras.pdf
Read On the internet and Download Ebook Mastering Flash With Fujifilm X Cameras. Download Tony Phillips ebook file for. free and this book pdf present at Tuesday 5th of November 2013 06:47:01 AM, Get several Ebooks from our on the internet. library r

Conflict management as a mediator between conflict and workplace ...
1. Conflict management as a mediator between conflict and workplace bullying: implementation of the Dual. Concern Theory. Elfi Baillien, Inge Neyens, Hans De Witte. Research Group for Stress, Health and Well-being. KULeuven - Belgium ...

Deweyan Democracy and
people profoundly disagree about philosophical, theological, and moral basics, ultimate ends, and the good life. ... All that is asserted is that the epistemic obstacles to reasoned agreement across a population about Big Questions are ...... Democra

Electoral-Systems-And-Democracy-A-Journal-Of-Democracy-Book.pdf
... Andrew Reynolds, David Samuels,. Richard Snyder, Richard Soudriette, R. Kent Weaver. This publication consists of detailed information of , as well as other about . Our solutions was launched with a wish to work as. a complete on the internet ele

nature territory - NT Field Naturalists
Estimating the financial risks of Andropogon gayanus to greenhouse gas abatement projects in northern Australia. Environmental Research Letters 8: 025018. Boyden J, Joyce K, Boggs G, Wurm P. 2013. Object-based mapping of native vegetation and para gr

Mobility and Conflict - Munin - UiT
We also contribute to the literature on conflict and rent seeking (e.g. Grossman (1991),. Hirshleifer (1995), Azam (1995), Azam (2001), Esteban and Ray (1999), ...

nature territory - NT Field Naturalists
The larva of the Emperor Moth Syntherata melvilla is one of the Top End's longer and fattest caterpillars. ..... Research that informs application of the IUCN Red List criteria can also be used to guide actions that ... well be the most popular trave

ARMED CELL 7.pdf
essay on Architecture). mayakov-plus-sky.blogspot.com. Physical edition of 100. Free. ARMED CELL 7 was first distributed at the East Bay Poetry Summit, ...

ARMED-FORCES-MEDICAL-COLLEGE-RECRUITMENT.compressed ...
ARMED-FORCES-MEDICAL-COLLEGE-RECRUITMENT.compressed.pdf. ARMED-FORCES-MEDICAL-COLLEGE-RECRUITMENT.compressed.pdf. Open.

Armed Blue Gunvolt.pdf
The target is the “Cybernetic Chanting Mind (Cyber Diva)”. そのプログラムコアの破壊だ. Sono puroguramu koa no hakai da. The destruction of its program core.

Conflict and Health
Mar 14, 2008 - Email: Voravit Suwanvanichkij - [email protected]. Abstract. Decades of neglect ..... Shan Relief and Development Committee (SRDC): Deserted Fields: The Destruction of ... 2006/06/09/ixnews.html]. June 9, 2006. 10.

Mobility and Conflict - Munin - UiT
of social cleavages affects the nature and frequency of political conflict, but existing literature does not provide a ..... We interpret conflict as any kind of political activism undertaken by. 13We could have .... Define functions f(π) ≡ π + Ï

Conflict and Health - Springer Link
Mar 14, 2008 - cle.php?art_id=5804]. May 30, 2006. 21. Tin Tad Clinic: Proposal for a Village-Based Health Care. Project at Ban Mai Ton Hoong, Fang District, ...