Consumption Response to Investment Shocks under Financial Frictions Abeer Reza Department of Economics, Carleton University, C-870 Loeb, 1125 Colonel By Drive, Ottawa, K1S 5B6, Canada. E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract Financial frictions and variable capacity utilization can generate comovement after an investment shock. It is shown that restrictions on wealth effects, wage rigidities, or high Frisch labor supply elasticities are unnecessary. Keywords: financial frictions, investment shocks, comovement JEL classification: E2, E3 1. Introduction Recent evidence from estimated DSGE models (Justiniano et al., 2010, henceforth JMT) and Structural VAR (Fisher, 2006) suggest that shocks to investment technology account for the highest proportion of variation in output, hours and investment seen in post-war US data. A common shortfall for most rational expectations models, however, is that consumption falls on impact after an investment shock, contradicting its observed co-movement with investment, output and hours. In this paper, I show that financial frictions and capacity utilization in a new-Keynesian model can generate a positive consumption response on impact, without recourse to limiting wealth effects in preferences, rigidities in wages or a high Frisch elasticity of labor supply. Barro and King (1984) show that in the standard neoclassical model, temporary investment shocks increase the real rate of return from investment, inciting households to postpone consumption in favor of savings through the inter-temporal substitution channel, producing a negative co-movement between consumption and investment. Since then, economists have focused on

Preprint submitted to Economics Letters

June 20, 2011

three mechanisms in an attempt to overcome the limitations of the neoclassical model in generating business cycles from investment shocks - variable capacity utilization in production (Greenwood et al., 1998, henceforth GHH; Khan and Tsoukalas, 2011, henceforth KT), wage and price rigidities (JMT), and special preference structures that restrict wealth effects on labor supply (Furlanetto and Seneca, 2008). Successful attempts at generating a positive consumption response invariably rely on both capacity utilization and restrictions on wealth effects. In particular, KT shows that modeling the cost of capacity utilization in terms of increased depreciation, as opposed to other popular formulations, is important in generating a positive consumption response. Their results nonetheless are based on a Frisch labor supply elasticity higher than that suggested in the micro literature (Chetty et. al, 2011). In this paper, I propose financial frictions as a fourth mechanism in mitigating the consumption co-movement problem. The key result is that with capacity utilization and financial frictions, there is no need to restrict wealth effects, impose rigidities in wages, or assume a high labor supply elasticity to generate a positive consumption response on impact. 2. Model I consider the setup of Christensen and Dib (2008) who analyze a stickyprice DSGE model with financial frictions under nominal debt contract and find investment shocks to be the most important driver of output and investment. Consumption, however, still declines on impact. To their setup, I add habit formation in consumption, capacity utilization in production in the spirit of GHH and KT, and abstract from money. A representative household chooses a real consumption bundle of composite commodities, ct , hours of work, lt , and the level of nominal saving deposits, Dt , to maximize expected lifetime utility: # "  1−γ ∞ X c Υ e t t + lt1+ζ E0 βt h 1 − γ 1 + ζ c t−1 t=0 subject to a budget constraint: ct +

Dt d Dt−1 ≤ wt lt + Rt−1 Pt Pt 2

where et is a shock to consumption preference, wt is the wage rate, and Rtd is the gross nominal rate of interest earned on deposits. A continuum of entrepreneurs indexed by j ∈ (0, 1) own capital ktj , hire labor ltj and determine capacity utilization, ujt to produce a single intermediate good ytj , that is sold in a competitive market at a common real price pw t . These firms face a constant returns to scale production function ytj = ωtj ujt ktj



zt ltj

1−α

where ωtj ∈ (0, 1) R 1is jan idiosyncratic shock that is observed privately by the firm, such that 0 ωt dj = 1, and zt an aggregate technology shock common across all firms. At the end of each period, entrepreneurs purchase capital j kt+1 at price qt , funded through net worth nwtj and external financing eftj = j qt kt+1 − nwtj . A financial intermediary takes nominal deposits from households at a gross interest rate of Rtd and provides loans to entrepreneurs at gross real interest rate Rtl . If the idiosyncratic shock ωtj hitting the firm is below a threshold level ω ¯ , the firm declares bankruptcy. Bernanke et al. (1999) show that under the above asymmetric information setup, an optimal debt contract requires the intermediary to impose a variable loan premium on the cost of lending that is increasing on the borrowing firm’s ratio of asset to net worth. Aggregating across all firms, the supply of financing follows: ) ( ψ   l 1 q k t t+1 d (1) Et Rt+1 = Et Rt+1 nwt πt+1 where the loan premium elasticity ψ depends on micro parameters governing monitoring costs, the threshold level of idiosyncratic risk, etc. The financial intermediary has access to risk-free financing from the monetary authority, making the nominal interest rate, Rt the effective opportunity cost, implying Rt = Rtd through arbitrage. Firms choose capital, capacity utilization and labor inputs to maximize the sum of future profits, subject to the production function, the external financing constraint, and the cost of capital utilization. The later, following GHH, is modeled as a higher depreciation rate of capital, δ (u) , δ 0 (u) > 0. Aggregating across firms, the first order conditions for financing and capacity utilization are:

3

# " + q (1 − δ (u )) αϕt+1 kyt+1  l t+1 t t+1 Et Rt+1 = Et qt αϕt

(2)

yt 0 j = qt δ (ut ) kt ut

(3)

where ϕt is the shadow value of marginal cost. For any firm j surviving bankruptcy this period, the difference between the ex-post contribution from capital and the ex-ante financing cost of capital is added to next period’s net worth. Aggregating across firms, we get economy-wide net worth: "

αϕt kytt + qt (1 − δ (ut−1 ))



(





1 qt−1 kt − Et−1 Rt (qt−1 kt − nwt−1 ) nwt = ν qt−1 πt (4) where firms survive till the next period with probability ν to ensure that no firm is able to accumulate enough net worth to fully finance new capital acquisition without requiring external financing. Capital producers purchase a fraction of final goods from retailers and use them as investment goods to produce new capital using a linear technology, subject to an investment-specific technology shock, ξt , and a quadratic investment adjustment cost, and sell the new capital at price qt . Their decision rule gives: qt−1 kt nwt−1

  2  2 #  it χI it it+1 it+1 −1 + − 1 − χI −1 Et {qt ξt } = Et 1 + χI it−1 it−1 2 it−1 it it (5) where χI is a parameter measuring investment adjustment costs. The aggregate capital stock evolves according to: "



it

kt+1 = ξt it + (1 − δ (ut )) kt

(6)

A retail sector exists to motivate price rigidities through the following new-Keynesian Philips curve, expressed in log-deviations from steady-state: π ˆt = βEt π ˆt+1 +

(1 − βφ) (1 − φ) ϕˆt φ 4

(7)

)#

Aggregate final goods are distributed between consumption and investment. The monetary authority adjusts the nominal interest rate Rt in response to deviations in inflation and output according to a standard Taylor rule:  % Rt  πt %π yt y = exp (εR,t ) (8) R π y where R, π and y are steady-state values of the nominal risk-free interest rate, inflation and output respectively, and εR,t is an i.i.d. shock to monetary policy with zero mean. The remaining shocks in the model xt ∈ {et , zt , ξt } follow an autoregressive process: log (xt ) = ρx log (xt−1 ) + εx,t The calibration closely follows Christensen and Dib (2008) who use maximum likelihood to estimate their model on quarterly US data from 1979Q3 to 2004Q3. The elasticity of external financial premium, ψ is set to 0.042. The Frisch elasticity of labor supply, ζ1 , is calibrated to 0.1. This value is supported by microeconomic evidence (Card, 1994; Chetty et al., 2011), and is different from the usually higher value preferred in the business cycle literature. The second derivative of endogenous depreciation with respect to capacity utilization, δ 00 (u), is set to 0.01, which is comparable to the lower decile value of the equivalent parameter estimated by KT. The investment adjustment cost parameter, χI , is set to 5, compatible with the estimated findings from Smets and Wouters (2007). 3. Results Figure 1 shows the impulse responses to an investment shock for the benchmark model, a model without financial frictions, and one with constant capacity utilization. The key finding is that consumption is positive on impact only under the benchmark model, i.e. in the presence of both variable capacity utilization and financial frictions. A positive shock to the marginal efficiency of investment increases the level of new capital produced per unit of investment, reducing capital price. Firms balance increased output from higher capacity utilization with the cost of higher depreciation of installed capital. Since the value of installed capital falls on impact, depreciating it at a higher rate is less costly. Consequently, 5

Figure 1: Impulse response to investment shock, full model, model without financial frictions, and model without capacity utilization

6

capacity utilization is endogenously increased. This boosts output and raises marginal returns to capital. Inter-temporal substitution effects induce households to postpone consumption in favor of savings to take advantage of this temporary higher return on investment. In the presence of financial frictions, however, the reduction in the value of current capital holding lessens firms net worth. The optimal financial contract now require a higher loan premium to compensate for the increased riskiness of firms. This higher marginal cost of financing attenuates investment and savings, allowing consumption to rise on impact. To see the same argument from the household side, recall that the loan premium creates a pro-cyclical wedge between loan interest rates and deposit rates, which equals the policy rate through arbitrage. An investment shock elicits a positive response from investment, output and inflation in all cases. Consequently, in all cases, the monetary authority responds by raising the policy rate. However, since investment and output responses are abated in the presence of financial frictions, so too is the response in policy rates. From the household’s perspective, this translates to a moderated increase in the returns to savings, resulting in lower savings and a rise in consumption. If leisure is normal, an increase in household wealth following a positive shock would reduce labor supply, dampening output. This issue is identified by GHH, who, for ease of exposition, adopts preferences that completely turn off the wealth effect channel of labor supply. In this study, labor supply is fully elastic to wealth, but consumption response is sensitive to the calibration of ζ. To understand   why, consider the log linearized labor sup1 ˆ ˆ ply condition: lt = ζ wˆt + λt . Heuristically, eliminating wealth effects is ˆ t term. A lower Frisch elasticity of labor supply, or a akin to removing the λ higher calibration value for ζ regulates the wealth effect. Frisch elasticities higher than 2, common in the macro literature and inconsistent with micro evidence (Chetty et al., 2011), result in a negative consumption response in the benchmark calibration. In this sense, this model supports a Frisch parameter compatible with microeconometric evidence. 4. Conclusion This note demonstrates that in the presence of financial frictions and variable capacity utilization, the New Keynesian model is able to generate a positive consumption response on impact of investment shocks, overcoming 7

the Barro-King critique. This result is achieved without recourse to special preferences aimed at constraining wealth effects and with a Frisch labor supply elasticity consistent with microeconomic evidence. Acknowledgment I would like to thank Hashmat Khan and Huntley Schaller for helpful comments and suggestions. [1] Barro, R., King, R. 1984. Time-separable preferences and intertemporalsubstitution models of business cycles. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99(4), 817-839. [2] Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1999. The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In: Handbook of Macroeconomics. North-Holland, Amsterdam. [3] Card, D., 1994. Intertemporal labour supply: an assessment. NBER Working Papers 3602, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. [4] Chetty, R., Guren, A., Manoli, D., Weber, A., 2011. Are Micro and Macro Labor Supply Elasticities Consistent? A Review of Evidence on the Intensive and Extensive Margins. American Economic Review 101, 471-475. [5] Christensen, I., Dib, A., 2008. The financial accelerator in an estimated new Keynesian model. Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 155-178. [6] Fisher, J., 2006. The dynamic effects of neutral and investment-specific shocks. Journal of Political Economy 114, 413-451. [7] Furlanetto, F., Seneca, M., 2010. Investment-Specific technology shocks and consumption. Working paper 49, Central Bank of Iceland. [8] Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., Huffman, G., 1988. Investment, capacity utilization and the real business cycle. American Economic Review 78, 402-417. [9] Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G., Tambalotti, A., 2010. Investment shocks and the business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 57, 132-145. 8

[10] Khan, H., Tsoukalas, J., 2011. Investment shocks and the comovement problem. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 35, 115-130. [11] Smets, F., Wouters, R., 2007. Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: a Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review 97, 586-606.

9

Consumption Response to Investment Shocks under ...

Jun 20, 2011 - where ϕt is the shadow value of marginal cost. For any firm j surviving bankruptcy this period, the difference between the ex-post contribution from capital and the ex-ante financing cost of cap- ital is added to next period's net worth. Aggregating across firms, we get economy-wide net worth: nwt = ν. [{αϕt yt.

213KB Sizes 0 Downloads 191 Views

Recommend Documents

The response of consumption to income - ScienceDirect
In previous work we have argued that aggregate, post-war, United States data on consumption and income are well described by a model in which a fraction of ...

The response of consumption to income
poor data: Campbell and Mankiw (1990), for example, lack international data on ..... hard to generalize this approach to handle conditional heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation in the .... way that seasonal factors do not drive our results.

Monetary Policy Response to Oil Price Shocks
Aug 5, 2009 - Fax: +41—44—631—3901, Email: [email protected]. ...... to the New Keynesian Framework, Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press, 2008.

The response of consumption to income - Semantic Scholar
poor data: Campbell and Mankiw (1990), for example, lack international ...... Part of the explanation may be our different handling of seasonally unadjusted data.

Monetary Policy Response to Oil Price Shocks
Aug 5, 2009 - Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Monetary Policy Response to Oil Price Shocks. Jean-Marc Natal. Swiss National Bank.

Health shocks and consumption smoothing in rural ...
This paper estimates, using a large panel data set from rural Bangladesh, the effects of health shocks on ..... collected by a survey of village shopkeepers and this information was only used in special cases. These values are then deflated using the

Notes on consumption, investment and effective demand
of the idea of a demand schedule for 'saving' determining the rate of interest in .... writes, 'more or less corresponds to the expected yield on the newly created .... to the production of investment goods, real accumulation will be higher than it .

Optimal Investment under Credit Constraint
We characterize the optimal investment decision, the financing and ...... [6] Dixit, A. and R. Pindyck, 1994, Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton University.

Investment Shocks and the Comovement Problem
Problem. Hashmat Khan. John Tsoukalas. Carleton University University of Nottingham. Discussant: Panayiotis M. Pourpourides. Cardiff Business School ...

Notes on consumption, investment and effective demand
liable to vary as a result of changes in any of these data. ... Yet if this direct link between the two rates is broken, Wicksell continues, another, ..... investment will make possible the maintenance, at least in part, of the initial increase in ..

Investment-Specific Shocks and Cyclical Fluctuations in ...
Oct 5, 2007 - findings, however, are sensitive to the use of convex rather than linear hiring costs, and generates a countercyclical .... can see in Table 1, the separation rate displays a clearly phase shift in the direction of leading labor market

Investment-Specific Shocks, Business Cycles, and ...
(2010, 2011) find that investment shocks are the main driver of business cycle fluctuations in the US economy. ..... accounting for the labor market friction. ... We fix the volatility of the long-run shocks to be a small percentage ...... This impli

Risk-sensitive Consumption and Savings under ... - Acrobat Planet
Jun 20, 2009 - Hong Kong, and the Chinese University of Hong Kong for helpful ... Research Fund (GRF, formerly CERG) in Hong Kong for financial support.

Notes on consumption, investment and effective demand
been generally accepted for the analysis of trade cycles and other short- ... that of Ricardo and the 'classical school' proper, on the one hand, and, on the other, .... its profit; and when there is a like increase of stock in all the different trad

Average tax rates on consumption, investment, labor ...
et al. collect data on tax revenues from OECD (2005b) and income and expenditures data come from ... (gov) Operating surplus, net + consumption of fixed capital. C. Household final ...... Reserve Bank of Kansas City Working paper 06-16. 27 ...

Grain Yield Response Of Rice Cultivars Under ... - Semantic Scholar
when evaluated under controlled irrigation condition. ... irrigation condition and b) upland condition with .... cultivar performance for cultivar x location data.

Grain Yield Response Of Rice Cultivars Under ... - Semantic Scholar
The correlation, path analysis and drought indices viz., relative yield (RY) and ... correlation and the path analysis were calculated as per INDOSTAT package.

Investment and hiring behaviors under asymmetric ...
+ EZ { ∞. ∑ i=0 e−rτi (cZ(τi) + Iτi + h∆Hτi + f∆Fτi )} , where Z(t),K(t),L(t) evolves according to (2) (starting from Z), (3) and (5). Our goal is to find a. CIIC policy P∗ which yields the greatest possible value among all the feasi

Investment under Rational Inattention: Evidence from ...
component follow an autoregressive process each with reduced-form error terms that ... otherwise standard real business cycle model with investment adjustment ... Under this assumption, decision-makers must pay a fixed cost to acquire new ...