Comment on Claude Berrebi and Esteban F. Klor (2008): “Are Voters Sensitive to Terrorism? Direct Evidence from the Israeli Electorate”

Marek Hlavac* Georgetown University Georgetown Public Policy Institute October 2010

*

Candidate, Master of Public Policy (MPP), Georgetown University, Expected 2011 A.B. in Economics, summa cum laude, Princeton University, 2008

1

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1690344

In “Are Voters Sensitive to Terrorism? Direct Evidence from the Israeli Electorate,“ Claude Berrebi and Esteban F. Klor analyze the causal effects of terrorist attacks on the political preferences of the Israeli electorate. They find that, if a locality suffers a terrorist attack within three months of a parliamentary election, support for the right bloc of political parties increases, on average, by 1.35 percentage points. This magnitude is politically significant, given that the Israeli electorate is narrowly split. In left-leaning localities, interestingly, local terror fatalities lead to an increase in the relative support for the right bloc, but terror fatalities outside the locality increase support for the left bloc of parties. Terrorist attacks, Berrebi and Klor argue, can contribute to the ideological polarization of the electorate: Terrorism, they find, increases support for the right bloc in all the right-leaning localities, but decreases support for the right bloc in most left-leaning localities. Berrebi and Klor interpret their findings to be, for the most part, supportive of the policy voting hypothesis, according to which “parties benefit from the salience of issues to which they are generally viewed as attaching highest priority.” (Kiewiet, 1981) Berrebi and Klor’s article contributes to a growing body of research literature on the causes and effects of terrorism, defined by Sandler and Enders (2004) as “the pre-meditated use, or threat of use, of extra-normal violence to obtain a political objective through intimidation or fear directed at a large audience.” Sandlers and Enders (2004) provide a comprehensive review of the research literature on the causes and consequences of terrorism. Research on the causes of terrorism has often focused on the political and socio-economic determinants of terrorism (Russell and Miller, 1983; Krueger and Malečková, 2003; Krueger and Laitin, 2008; Piazza, 2006). Berrebi and Klor’s paper contributes to a burgeoning literature on the effects of terrorism: Previous research has studied, inter alia, whether terrorism helps achieve the terrorists’ political goals (Pape, 2003), its effects on states’ respect on human rights (Dreher et al., 2010), as well as

2

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1690344

on specific industries, such as tourism (Drakos and Kutan, 2003). Berrebi and Klor’s study analyzes the effect on terrorism on voter preferences and electoral outcomes – a crucial question, given terrorism’s explicit focus on achieving political objectives. In addition, the paper provides an important link between the relatively recent literature on the causes and consequences of terrorism, and a long strand of academic literature on electoral behavior (Bartels, 2008), pioneered by Lazarsfeld et al. (1944), Black (1948) and Downs (1957). The strengths of Berrebi and Klor’s paper are most apparent in its careful robustness tests. In particular, the authors test whether the results hold for alternative ways of including a variable for terrorist attacks (the number of fatalities suffered, the number of attacks, and a dummy for the occurrence of an attack), as well as for alternative definitions of the right and the left political blocs, and for variable time periods before a parliamentary election. The most important shortcoming of Berrebi and Klor’s paper lies in their treatment of possible reverse causality. The authors correctly point out that a naïve regression model would yield biased coefficients, since “terror attacks may influence the electorate’s preferences, but terrorism may also be a reaction to those preferences.” Their remedy, however, is unconvincing: They add to the analysis terror attacks’ “variation across space,” which they show to be exogenous to the electorate’s political preferences. They, however, estimate a fixed-effect linear regression model that does not resolve the endogeneity problem caused by terror attacks’ variation over time. Instead, the authors would be well-advised to estimate a two-stage leastsquares (2SLS) model, where they explicitly instrument for terrorist attacks by variables suggested by Berrebi and Lakdawalla (2007): These include, among others, the locality’s population, its area (in km2), the percentage of Jewish residents in the local population, and the distance to the closest terrorist home base. Instrumental variables approaches are a standard

3

econometric method to resolve problems of simultaneity (Wooldridge, 2009), and have been used widely in studies of civil and political violence (Miguel et al., 2004; Brunschweller and Bulte, 2009). Another potential problem arises in Berrebi and Klor’s demonstration that, rather than influencing the relative turnout of left- and right-leaning voters, terrorism affects the political preferences of the electorate. To test this hypothesis, the authors focus on localities with very high turnouts: those, in which the average turnout rate exceeds 85%. In these localities, the authors argue, “almost everybody votes” and, therefore, “any influence of terrorist on the relative support for the right bloc must be a consequence of voters changing their preferences, and not their turnout decisions.” It is, however, conceivable that, even at high turnout rates, some people may, in the wake of a terrorist attack, decide to either vote or refrain from going to the polls. Although Berrebi and Klor’s conjecture may sound plausible, they need to support their claim by further empirical evidence – for instance, from an individual-level panel survey of voters in highturnout localities. The authors could obtain this evidence either from existing research on voter behavior in Israel, or offer it as a suggestion for further research. A final concern involves over-controlling in the specification of the linear regression model: In their basic model, the authors include two variables that account for fatalities caused by terrorist attacks: TerrorFatalitiesi,t and TotalFatalitiest. TerrorFatalitiesi,t accounts for the number of fatalities in the examined locality. Berrebi and Klor interpret the coefficient on TotalFatalitiest (total number of terror fatalities in Israel) as the effect on political attitudes of fatalities in other localities. In multiple regression models, coefficients have a “partial effect” interpretation: What is the effect of an additional local or non-local fatality on the relative support for the right bloc, holding everything else equal? The number of local fatalities,

4

however, cannot increase without a corresponding rise in the total number of terror fatalities in Israel. The authors should therefore consider replacing TotalFatalitiest by OutsideFatalitiesi,t equal to TotalFatalitiest - TerrorFatalitiesi,t. The coefficient on TerrorFatalitiesi,t will then be clearly interpretable as the ceteris paribus effect of a local terror fatalities on the political support for the right bloc. If Berrebi and Klor’s findings hold up, they could have several policy implications: Counterterrorism policies that increase terrorism’s salience in the public mind may, they suggest, enable terrorists to have a greater effect on the political process. By contrast, policies that diminish the electorate’s sensitivity to terrorism may help lower the threat. In addition, the author’s work yield important clues about the objectives of terrorist groups: If terrorist attacks increase support for the political right (which, in Israel, favors aggressive counterterrorism measures), such attacks may not help achieve terrorists’ goals (Abrahms, 2006), terror groups may have multiple objectives (Kydd and Walter, 2006), or there may be a more complex interplay (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2006). Finally, policy-makers should be careful in applying lessons from this research to other countries. Additional research is needed to test whether Berrebi and Klor’s findings, based on evidence from Israel, extend to different settings. All in all, Berrebi and Klor’s is comprehensive in its focus on the support for political party blocs, as well as on larger issues such as political polarization; rigorous in its multiple robustness tests; and can yield important insights for researchers and policy-makers. If the authors successfully address the concerns outlined earlier in this report, they will have made a significant contribution to our understanding on the complex interplay between terrorism, voter preferences and electoral behavior.

5

REFERENCES Abrahms, Max. (2006). “Why Terrorism Does Not Work.” International Security, Vol. 31, 4278. Bartels, Larry M. (2008). “The Study of Electoral Behavior.” In The Oxford Handbook of American Elections and Political Behavior, ed. Jan E. Leighley. Berrebi, Claude and Esteban F. Klor. (2008). “Are Voters Sensitive to Terrorism? Direct Evidence from the Israeli Electorate,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 102, No. 3, 279301. Berrebi, Claude and Darius Lakdawalla. (2007). “How Does Terrorism Risk Vary Across Space and Time? An Analysis Based on the Israeli Experience.” Defense and Peace Economics, Vol. 18, 113-131. Black, Duncan. (1948). “On the Rationale of Group Decision-making,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 56, 23-34. Brunschweiller, Christa N. and Erwin H. Bulte. (2009). “Natural Resources and Violent Conflict: Resource Abundance, Resource Dependence and the Onset of Civil Wars,” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 61, No. 4, 651-674. Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan and Eric Dickson. (2006). “The Propaganda of the Deed: Terrorism, Counterterrorism and Mobilization.” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 51, 364-81. Downs, Anthony. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. Harper-Collins. Drakos, Konstantinos and Ali M. Kutan. (2003). “Regional Effects of Terrorism on Tourism in Three Mediterranean Countries,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 47, 621-641. Dreher, Axel, Martin Gassebner and Lars-H. Siemers. (2010). “Does Terrorism Threaten Human Rights? Evidence from Panel Data,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 53. Kiewiet, D. Roderick. (1981). “Policy-Oriented Voting in Response to Economic Issues.” American Political Science Review, Vol. 75, 448-459. Krueger, Alan B. and David D. Laitin. (2008). “Kto Kogo?: A Cross-Country Study of the Origins and Targets of Terrorism.” In Terrorism, Economic Development, and Political Openness, ed. Philip Keefer and Normal Loayza. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Krueger, Alan B. and Jitka Malečková. (2003). “Education, Poverty, and Terrorism: Is There a Causal Connection?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 17, 119-144.

6

Kydd, Andrew H. and Barbara F. Walter. (2006). “The Strategies of Terrorism.” Mimeo. University of Bergen, Department of Political Science. Lazarsfeld, Paul F., Bernard Berelson, and Hazel Gaudet. (1944). The People's Choice: How the Voter Makes Up His Mind in a Presidential Campaign. New York: Columbia University Press. Miguel, Edward, Sanker Satyanath and Ernest Sergenti. (2004). “Economic Shocks and Civil Conflict: An Instrumental Variables Approach,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 112, No. 4, 725-753. Pape, Robert A. (2003). “The Strategic Logic of Suicide Terrorism.” American Political Science Review, Vol. 97, 343-361. Piazza, James A. (2006). “Rooted in Poverty?: Terrorism, Poor Economic Development, and Social Cleavages.” Terrorism and Political Violence, Vol. 18, 159-177. Russell, Charles and Bowman Miller. (1983). “Profile of a Terrorist.” In Pespectives on Terrorism, Wilmington, DE: Scholarly Resources, Inc. Sandler, Todd and Walter Enders. (2004). “An Economic Perspective on Transnational Terrorism,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 20, 301-316. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (2009). Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 4th Edition, South-Western Cengage Learning: Mason, OH.

7

Are Voters Sensitive to Terrorism? Direct Evidence ... - SSRN papers

Candidate, Master of Public Policy (MPP), Georgetown University, Expected ... supportive of the policy voting hypothesis, according to which “parties benefit from ...

231KB Sizes 0 Downloads 224 Views

Recommend Documents

Is Advertising Informative? Evidence from ... - SSRN papers
Jan 23, 2012 - doctor-level prescription and advertising exposure data for statin ..... allows advertising to be persuasive, in the sense that both E[xat] > δa.

Are University Admissions Academically Fair? - SSRN papers
Jan 2, 2016 - High-profile universities often face public criticism for undermining ... moting social elitism or engineering through their admissions-process.

Evidence that Two‐Year‐Old Children are Sensitive to Information ...
Evidence that Two-Year-Old Children are. Sensitive to Information Presented in. Arguments. Thomas Castelain. Instituto de Investigaciones Psicoleogicas. Universidad de Costa Rica. Stéphane Bernard. Centre de Sciences Cognitives. Universitee de Neuch

budget procedures and fiscal performance: evidence ... - SSRN papers
Oct 2, 2016 - IESE Business School-University of Navarra - 1. BUDGET ... Pompeu Fabra and Public-Private Sector Research Center, IESE Business School.

Technology Shocks and Hours Revisited: Evidence ... - SSRN papers
Jun 11, 2017 - I exploit heterogeneous impulse responses at the household level due to limited stock market participation to provide novel evidence on the degree of nominal rigidities. A number of studies show that positive technology shocks reduce a

Evidence from Doing Business in China - SSRN papers
Affiliations: Sauder School of Business, The University of British Columbia. ... landscape, lifted U.S. firms' restrictions on doing business in China, such as: the ...

Blaming Youth - SSRN papers
Dec 14, 2002 - Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection ... T. MacArthur Foundation Research Network on Adolescent Development and.

law review - SSRN papers
Tlie present sentencing debate focuses on which decisionmaker is best .... minimum sentences even after a sentencing guideline system is in place to control ...

the path to convergence: intergenerational ... - SSRN papers
Apr 24, 2006 - THE PATH TO CONVERGENCE: INTERGENERATIONAL. OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY IN BRITAIN AND THE US. IN THREE ERAS*.

Optimism and Communication - SSRN papers
Oct 10, 2010 - Abstract. I examine how the communication incentive of an agent (sender) changes when the prior of the principal (receiver) about the agent's ...

yale law school - SSRN papers
YALE LAW SCHOOL. Public Law & Legal Theory. Research Paper Series by. Daniel C. Esty. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the.

Organizational Capital, Corporate Leadership, and ... - SSRN papers
Organizational Capital, Corporate Leadership, and Firm. Dynamics. Wouter Dessein and Andrea Prat. Columbia University*. September 21, 2017. Abstract. We argue that economists have studied the role of management from three perspec- tives: contingency

Negotiation, Organizations and Markets Research ... - SSRN papers
May 5, 2001 - Harvard Business School. Modularity after the Crash. Carliss Y. Baldwin. Kim B. Clark. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the.

directed search and firm size - SSRN papers
Standard directed search models predict that larger firms pay lower wages than smaller firms, ... 1 This is a revised version of a chapter of my Ph.D. dissertation.

All-Stage Strong Correlated Equilibrium - SSRN papers
Nov 15, 2009 - Fax: 972-3-640-9357. Email: [email protected]. Abstract. A strong ... Existing solution concepts assume that players receive simultane-.

Competition, Markups, and Predictable Returns - SSRN papers
business formation and markups forecast the equity premium. ... by markups, profit shares, and net business formation, which we find strong empirical support for ...

international r&d collaboration networks - SSRN papers
and efficiency of networks of R&D collaboration among three firms located in different countries. A conflict between stability and efficiency is likely to occur.

The Political Economy of - SSRN papers
Jul 21, 2017 - This evidence is consistent with the idea that with inelastic demand, competition entails narrower productive inefficiencies but also.

Bank Interest Rate Risk Management - SSRN papers
Apr 6, 2017 - Email: [email protected]. 1 ...... by the desire to increase current debt capacity, it is a useful benchmark to assess the quantitative relevance of ...

Recreating the South Sea Bubble - SSRN papers
Aug 28, 2013 - Discussion Paper No. 9652. September 2013. Centre for Economic Policy Research. 77 Bastwick Street, London EC1V 3PZ, UK. Tel: (44 20) ...

from institutions to financial development and growth - SSRN papers
Contract enforcement; Economic growth; Financial development; Financial .... Enforcement and other transac on costs. Ins tu ons. Growth. Property. Rights.

what to look for in a backtest - SSRN papers
Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory. Computational Research Division. WHAT TO LOOK FOR IN A ... If the data is publicly available, the researcher may use the “hold-out” as part of the IS. 2. Even if that's not the case, any ...... and Computer