Are Firm Growth Rates R a n d o m ? Evidence from Japanese Small Firms Yukiko Saito^ and Tsutomu Watanabe^ ^ Fujitsu Research Insitute, 1-16-1 Kaigan, Minato-ku, Tokyo 105-0022, Japan saitoQfri.fuj itsu.com ^ Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University, Kunitachi, Tokyo 186-8603, Japan t s u t o m u . w Q s r v . c c . h i t - u . a c . j p

Summary. Anecdotal evidences suggest that a small number of firms continue to win until they finally acquire a big presence and monopolistic power in a market. To see whether such "winner-take-all" story is true or not, we look at the persistence of growth rates for Japanese small firms. Using a unique dataset covering half a million firms in each year of 1995-2003, we find the following. First, scale variables, such as total asset and sales, exhibit a divergence property: firms that have experienced positive growth in the preceding years are more likely to achieve positive growth again. Second, other variables that are more or less related to firm profitability exhibit a convergence property: firms with positive growth in the past are less likely to achieve positive growth again. These two evidences indicate that firm growth rates are not random but history dependent. Key words: Firm growth; Gibrat's Law; history dependence; winner-take-all; persistence of growth

1 Introduction It is often said that a small number of firms continue to win until they finally acquire a big presence and strong monopolistic power in a market. For example, "winner-take-all" is said to be an important phenomena observed in IT (information technology) related industries, in which technology-driven network externalities enable a small number of firms to acquire a dominant presence in markets. Also, at least partially due to developments in financial technology, more and more firms are now engaged in mergers and acquisitions, thereby contributing to the emergence of highly concentrated markets. Given this tendency, should we expect that each market will be monopolized in the near future? This is an important question to be addressed, partly be-

277

cause highly concentrated market structure might lead to less competition, and consequently to the deterioration of economic welfare. Previous studies on firm growth give us some hint to think about this issue. Famous Gibrat's Law tells us that firm size evolves according to a random walk, so that there is no reason to believe that big firms grow faster than smaller ones. If this is true, what we currently observe in markets is just an illusion or, at best, a very short-life phenomena. More importantly, many of recent empirical studies, which tend to report results against Gibrat's Law, typically find that big firms grow more slowly than small ones, with an implication that firm size tend to converge over time to a common long-run level (See Sutton (1997) for an extensive survey). This is clearly against the winner-take-all story. The purpose of this paper is to investigate whether firm growth rates are random or not. More specifically, we try to detect persistence in firm growth rates. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Sections 2 and 3 explain our empirical strategy and data. Section 4 presents empirical results.

2 Empirical Strategy The common model used to explain firms' growth rate is Axit = ßxit-i

-\-eit,

(1)

where xa is the logarithm of the size of firm i in period t, Axu is the growth rate, which is defined by Axu = xu — xu-i^ /3 is a parameter, and en is a disturbance. This equation can be rewritten as Axit = tit + ßeit-i

-f • •. + /3(H- ßf-^tn

+ ß{l + ßf-^Xio.

(2)

It is straightforward to see that xu follows a random walk if (1) /3 = 0 and (2) Cov(eit,eit-fc) = 0. P u t differently, we have Pr(Axit I Axit-i,

Axit-2,

Axit-3,

---) = Fi{Axit)

(3)

if these two conditions are satisfied. In words, firm i's growth rate in period t does not depend on its past performance. However, if either of the two conditions is violated, equation (3) does not hold any more, and firm i's growth rate in period t depends on its past performance. This is what we call history dependence. More specifically, we are interested in whether FriAxit

> 0 I Axit-i

> 0, Axit-2

> 0, • • •) = FviAxu

> 0)

(4)

FiiAxit

< 0 I Ax^t-l

< 0, Axit-2

< 0, • • 0 = FiiAxu

< 0)

(5)

hold or not. For example, if the conditional probability in equation (4) is smaller than the unconditional one, it implies "mean-reversion" or "convergence" : those firms with positive growth in the past are more likely to turn to

278

Fig. 1. Growth Rates of Total Assets in Two Consecutive Years

negative growth in period t. On the other hand, if the conditional probability is greater t h a n the unconditional one in equation (4), it implies ''trend movements" or "divergence": those firms with positive growth in the past are more likely to achieve positive growth again in period t, w^hich is consistent with the winner-take-all story. In what follow^s, we will compare the conditional and unconditional probabilities to see whether or not the d a t a supports such a story.

3 Data The d a t a we use are from the Credit Risk Database (CRD) collected by the C R D Association. T h e sample is well suited for our purposes; it consists of more t h a n half a million incorporated enterprises of small size (i.e., about tw^enty employees per firm) in each year and covers the nine years of 19952003. Basic B / S and P / L information, which is reported by firms to their banks each year, is available for those small firms.

4 Empirical Results 4.1 G r o w t h r a t e s in t w o c o n s e c u t i v e y e a r s Fig. 1 looks at the relationship between the growth rates of total assets in 2001 (Ax,oi) and those in 2002 (Ax,o2)- We classify firms into 21 categories depending on the amount of total assets, which is measured by the horizontal axis,

279

and calculate four conditional probabilities for each category: Pr(Aa::i02 ^ 0 I Axioi > 0), represented by the line with "-f"; Pr(Axi02 > 0 | Axioi < 0), represented by the Une with "*"; Pr(Axi02 < 0 | Axioi > 0), represented by the Une with "x"; Pr(Axi02 < 0 | Axjoi < 0), represented by the hne with " D". The vertical axix measures probabilities. It is seen that the line with "+" is almost always above the line with "*", implying that those firms with positive growth in 2001 are more likely to achieve positive growth again in 2002.^ On the other hand, the line with " D" is almost always above the line with "x", implying that those firms with negative growth in 2001 are more likely to have negative growth again in 2002. The divergence property observed in Fig. 1 is consistent with the "winnertake-all" story, but clearly not consistent with the results reported by the previous studies, which typically estimate ß in equation (1) under the assumption that Cov{tit, eit-k) — 0, and find that ß is slightly smaller than zero. To compare our finding with those of the previous studies, observe that, under the assumption of Cov(6it,eit-fc) = 0, equation (1) implies Cov(Ax«, Ax«_,) = ^ Ü ± ^ a ? ,

(6)

where a^ is the standard deviation of ^n. It is straightforward to see that Cov(Aa;if, Axit_fc) cannot be positive as long as /3 € (—1,0]. In this sense, our finding is against those of the previous studies. Our finding implies that the typical assumption adopted in the previous studies, Cov(€it, eit_fc) = 0, might not be appropriate, or their estimates of ß might be biased.^ 4.2 Growth rates in five consecutive years Table 1 extends the analysis to more than two years. The upper part of the table presents the unconditional and conditional probabilities for those firms with positive growth in 2000; namely, the second column shows the unconditional probability (Pr(Axioo ^ 0 ) ) and the third column shows the conditional probability Pr(Aa;ioo ^ 0 I Axigg > 0), and the fourth column shows the conditional probability Pr(Aa;ioo ^ 0 | Axjgg > 0, Axigs ^ 0)? ^-i^d so on. The lower part of the table presents similar probabilities for those firms with negative growth in 1999. Table 1 shows several important features. First, the conditional probability Pr(Aa:ioo ^ 0 I Ax^gg > 0) is slightly lower than the corresponding unconditional probability, and similarly, the conditional probability Pr(Axtoo < 0 I ^ If one looks at the two lines more closely, one finds t h a t they overlap with each other for those firms with smaller total assets. ^ Chesher (1979) is a notable exception in which ß is estimated allowing for the possibility of serial correlation of t h e disturbance term. Using 183 UK firms in 1960-1969, he finds t h a t t h e disturbance term is positively autocorrelated {E{€itj eit-k) > 0), while the estimate of /? is close to zero.

280

Table 1. Multi-year history dependence: Total asset Pr(-f) 0.41878 Error bar Pr(-) 0.58122 Error bar

Pr(+ 1 +) Pr(+ 1 ++) Pr(+ 1 + + +) Pr(+ 1 + + ++) 0.41665 0.00284

0.44522 0.00441

0.47158 0.00646

Pr(- 1 -) Pr(- 1 — ) Pr(- 1 0.57942 0.00261

0.60377 0.00341

) Pr(- 1

0.64643 0.00497

0.50012 0.00869

) 0.69962 0.00742

Axi99 < 0) is slightly higher than the corresponding unconditional probability. These results imply a convergence property, but the differences between the conditional and unconditional probabilities are not substantial, and in fact not statistically significant.^ Second, the conditional probability Pr(Axioo ^ 0 I Axtgg > 0, Ax^gs > 0) is higher than the corresponding unconditional probability, implying that those firms with positive growth in two consecutive years are more likely to achieve positive growth again in the third year. Similarly, we see that those firms with negative growth in two consecutive years are more likely to experience negative growth again in the third year. Third, the conditional probability of positive growth is higher for those firms experiencing positive growth for a longer period: namely, firms with three consecutive positive growth are more likely to achieve positive growth again than those with two consecutive positive growth, and similarly, firms with four consecutive positive growth are more likely to experience positive growth than those with three consecutive growth. The second and third findings strongly suggest that the data is consistent with the winner-take-all story, 4.3 Growth rates in terms of various measures Tables 2 and 3 repeat the same exercise as we did in Table 1, but now we use two different variables: firm sales and firm profits. Table 2 shows that firm sales exhibit a divergence property that is similar to what we observed for total assets: positive (negative) growth is more likely to occur for those firms with positive (negative) growth in the preceding years. On the other hand. Table ^ Error bars in table 1 are calculated as follows. Denote the total number of occurrences of the event Axu-i > 0 by ni. If the event Axu > 0 occurs totally independently of past events (in particular, independently of the event Axu-i > 0), the number of occurrences of Axu > 0 obeys a binomial distribution whose mean and variance are given by rii Pr(Axit > 0) and rii Pr(Arrit > 0)(1 - Pr(ArEit > 0)), where Pr(-) represents an unconditional sample mean. Then the error bar for Pr(+ I +) is defined by [Pr(Axit > 0)(1 - Pr(Axit > 0))/ni]^/^ Similarly, the error bar for Pr(+ | + + ) is given by [FiiAxu > 0 | Axu-i > 0)(1 - Pr(Axit | Axit-i > 0))/n2]^/^, where 712 represents the number of occurrences of the event Axit-i > 0 and Axit-2 > 0. Other error bars are calculated in a similar way.

281

Table 2. Multi-year history dependence: Firm sales

Pr(+) 0,44894 Error bar Pr(-) 0.55106 Error bar

Pr(+ 1 +) Pr(+ 1 ++) Pr(+ 1 4- 4- +) Pr(+ 1 + + ++) 0.44097 0.00329

0.48341 0.00546

Pr(- 1 - ) Pr(- 1 — ) Pr(- 1 0.54683 0.00240

0.55443 0.00290

0.58402 0.01061

0.53885 0.00770

)

Pr(- 1

) 0.67304 0.00672

0.60868 0.00436

Table 3. Multi-year history dependence: Firm profits Pr(-i-) 0.53415 Error bar Pr(-) 0.46585 Error bar

Pr(+ 1 +) Pr(+ 1 4-f) Pr(4- 1 + + +) Pr(+ 1 -h -h ++) 0.42148 0.00280

0.36042 0.00389

Pr(- 1 - ) Pr(- 1 — ) Pr(- 1 0.36140 0.00270

0.31090 0.00303

0.35099 0.01012

0.34043 0.00601

)

0.28990 0.00425

Pr(- 1

) 0.29349 0.00663

3 shows that firm profits exhibit a convergence property: positive (negative) growth is less likely to occur for those firms with positive (negative) growth in the preceding years. Such a convergence property is observed for other variables, such as ROA (return on assets), probability of defaults, interest payments, that are more or less related to firm profitability (Not reported here). These two contrasting evidences seem to suggest that it is possible for firms to grow in terms of scale variables (such as total asset or firm sales) if they want to so, but larger scale operation does not necessarily guarantee higher profitability.

Acknowledgement We would like to thank Hideki Takayasu and Mitsuru Iwamura for helpful comments and suggestions.

References 1. Chesher, A. 1979. "Testing t h e law of proportionate effect." Jom-nal of Industrial Economics 27: 403-411. 2. Sutton, J. 1997. "Gibrat's legacy." Journal of Economic Literature 35: 40-59.

282

Are Firm Growth Rates Random? Evidence from ... - Springer Link

network externalities enable a small number of firms to acquire a dominant ... (Ax,oi) and those in 2002 (Ax,o2)- We classify firms into 21 categories depend-.

293KB Sizes 0 Downloads 258 Views

Recommend Documents

Evidence for Cyclic Spell-Out - Springer Link
Jul 23, 2001 - embedding C0 as argued in Section 2.1, this allows one to test whether object ... descriptively head-final languages but also dominantly head-initial lan- ..... The Phonology-Syntax Connection, University of Chicago Press,.

Economic growth and biodiversity - Springer Link
Jul 30, 2011 - Efforts to preserve and enhance biodiversity add to the size and growth of the economy. We are losing biodiversity because of human ...

Conflict, Distribution and Population Growth - Springer Link
class or King maximizes the surplus, engender the choice of more efficient productive combinations and to a smaller population relative to egalitarian societies.

Conflict, Distribution and Population Growth - Springer Link
net rate of return of energy per unit of foraging time, therefore it focus its ... Malthus model of renewable resource use to explain natural depletion in Easter. Island. .... 4 foragers in two gangs of 2 foragers each: π3 ¼ [2(9)π(9) ю 4π(2)]/2

If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks, Then Almost ...
mately random walks implies that fluctuations in interest rates are associated with ... of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. ... Most of these models assume a representative consumer who participates in all .....

Random Multi-Overlap Structures and Cavity Fields in ... - Springer Link
1Department of Mathematics, Princeton University, Fine Hall, Washington Road, Princeton,. NJ 08544–1000 ... the spin variables, to be specified each time.

Random Multi-Overlap Structures and Cavity Fields in ... - Springer Link
NJ 08544–1000, USA; e-mail: [email protected]. 785 ... We will have in mind a lattice with a large bulk of N sites (cavity) and M additional spins (N is ...

Subtidal macrozoobenthos communities from northern ... - Springer Link
Nov 27, 2007 - EN) on northern Chile and South America in general was not as catastrophic as ..... P = 0.005). The SIMPER analysis revealed that the poly-.

Evidence against integration of spatial maps in ... - Springer Link
Sep 3, 2008 - ORIGINAL PAPER. Evidence against integration of spatial maps in humans: generality across real and virtual environments. Bradley R. Sturz · Kent D. Bodily · JeVrey S. Katz ·. Debbie M. Kelly. Received: 28 March 2008 / Revised: 2 Augu

Expert Judgment Versus Public Opinion – Evidence ... - Springer Link
Abstract. For centuries, there have been discussions as to whether only experts can judge the quality ..... ticipating country can make a call to a phone number corresponding to her favorite song. ...... Journal of Economics and Business 51:.

High Commitment Management in the UK: Evidence ... - Springer Link
from the 1990 UK Workplace Industrial Relations Survey and its sister survey, ... others, it is one among several models of good personnel management, its .... monthly (monthly pay), receive payment through a bank account (cashless pay), or ...

Evidence against integration of spatial maps in humans - Springer Link
Abstract A dynamic 3-D virtual environment was con- structed for humans as an open-field analogue of Blaisdell and Cook's (2005) pigeon foraging task to determine if humans, like pigeons, were capable of integrating separate spatial maps. Participant

Effects of hypophysectomy and growth hormone on ... - Springer Link
It is sug- gested that these changes arise primarily from modifi- cation of the synthesis of specific islet proteins. ..... These studies were supported by grants from.

Reconsidering Price's model of scientific growth: An ... - Springer Link
number of scientific journals and abstract journals during the 1665-2000 time interval. As Price .... rejected this model as it was considered too abstract and did not take into account ..... (Spanish translation as Hacia una ciencia de la ciencia.

Effects of hypophysectomy and growth hormone on ... - Springer Link
10% (v/v) inactivated calf serum (Wellcome, Beckenham, Kent,. UK) and was supplemented ..... support is gratefully acknowledged. References. 1. Hedeskov CJ ...

Effects of Copper Sulfate on Growth, Development, and ... - Springer Link
Aug 26, 2008 - later age classes (Vitt et al. 1990). Because of their sensi- .... using the ruler function (accurate to 0.01 mm) in Adobe. 558. Arch Environ Contam ...

Ownership Concentration and Firm Risk. Evidence from ... - Labex Refi
blockholder has on average a daily volatility of 3.1%, this implies that an extra ... shareholders and hence their voting power and risk exposure at the cost of ...... App endix. A provides definitions of th e volatility measure and of all indep ende

Wages and Firm Performance: Evidence from the 2008 ...
Other firms (control) also signed long-term contracts before the crisis, but their long- ... ably reflects an acceptable pay appreciation during the forecasted business environment .... are followed by higher stock market performance. ..... pounds in

Demand learning and firm dynamics: evidence from ...
We find strong support for the core prediction of the model: belief updating ... This is supported by the data: we find that both the absolute value of the mean.

Wages and Firm Performance: Evidence from the 2008 ...
labor markets during the crisis leaves firms with existing long-term wage contracts ..... and publishing company specializing in the employment field.8 IDS is the ..... skill occupations as jobs in the service sector as well as elementary and ..... [

Political Connections and Firm Value: Evidence from ...
defined based on publicly available information on educational backgrounds of all politicians and directors. .... or loss status of the candidate who shares an educational background with a director of the firm. Our study ..... we group the degrees i

Information Inside the Firm - Evidence From a ...
Haas School of Business. University of California ... market when they receive information that presents opportunities for profit. I use the ... This startup sells prediction market software to managers who hope to elicit information from employees .

Ownership Concentration and Firm Risk. Evidence from ... - Labex Refi
‡Department of Law, Accounting and Finance, Montpellier Business School, .... and introduce selected control variables that might affect volatility but would not ...... program of share distribution to employees (ESOP), stock volatility is smaller,

Are survival processing memory advantages based on ... - Springer Link
Published online: 8 February 2011. © Psychonomic Society, Inc. 2011 ... study investigated the specificity of this idea by comparing an ancestor-consistent ...