PHYSICAL REVIEW E 82, 056117 共2010兲

Agent dynamics in kinetic models of wealth exchange Arnab Chatterjee1,* and Parongama Sen2,†

1

CMSP Section, The Abdus Salam International Centre for Theoretical Physics, Strada Costiera 11, Trieste I-34014, Italy 2 Department of Physics, University of Calcutta, 92 Acharya Prafulla Chandra Road, Kolkata 700009, India 共Received 18 June 2010; revised manuscript received 5 October 2010; published 23 November 2010兲 We study the dynamics of individual agents in some kinetic models of wealth exchange, particularly the models with savings. For the model with uniform savings, agents perform simple random walks in the “wealth space.” On the other hand, we observe ballistic diffusion in the model with distributed savings. There is an associated skewness in the gain-loss distribution which explains the steady-state behavior in such models. We find that, in general, an agent gains while interacting with an agent with a larger saving propensity. DOI: 10.1103/PhysRevE.82.056117

PACS number共s兲: 89.65.Gh, 89.75.Fb, 45.50.⫺j, 05.40.Fb

I. INTRODUCTION

The distribution of wealth among individuals in an economy has been a very important area of research in economics for more than a century 关1–6兴. The same holds for income distribution in any society. Detailed analyses of the income distribution 关3–5兴 so far indicate that for large income m, P共m兲 ⬃ m−共1+␯兲 ,



[email protected]

1539-3755/2010/82共5兲/056117共6兲

II. GASLIKE MODELS

共1兲

where P denotes the number density of people with income or wealth m. The power law in income and wealth distribution is named after Pareto and the exponent ␯ is called the Pareto exponent. The tail of the income distribution indeed follows the above mentioned behavior and the value of the Pareto exponent ␯ is generally seen to vary between 1 and 3 关3,5–7兴. For any country, it is well known that typically less than 10% of the population possesses about 40% of the total wealth and they follow the above law, while the rest of the low income population follow a different distribution 关3,5–9兴. According to physicists, the regular patterns observed in the income 共and wealth兲 distribution are indicative of a natural law for the statistical properties of a many-body dynamical system representing the entire set of economic interactions in a society, analogous to those previously derived for gases and liquids. By viewing the economy as a thermodynamic system, one can identify the income distribution with the distribution of energy among the particles in a gas. This has led to several new attempts at explaining them; particularly, a class of kinetic exchange models has provided a simple mechanism for understanding the unequal accumulation of assets. These models are simple from the perspective of economics and implement the key factors in socioeconomic interactions that result in very different societies converging to similar forms of unequal distribution of resources 共see Refs. 关3,4兴 for a collection of large number of technical papers in this field兲. In this paper, we consider the dynamics of individual agents. We discuss the money distribution of agents, given a

*[email protected]

particular value of saving propensity. In models with distributed savings, we look at a tagged agent and compute the distribution of money gained or lost in each interaction. We project the gain-loss behavior into a walk in one dimension in a so-called “wealth space.” Our numerical simulations suggest evidence of ballistic diffusion.

In analogy to two-particle collision process which results in a change in their individual kinetic energy or momenta, income exchange models may be defined using two-agent interactions: two randomly selected agents exchange money by some predefined mechanism. The exchange process does not depend on previous exchanges; hence, it is a Markov process,



mi共t + 1兲 m j共t + 1兲

冊 冉 冊 =M

mi共t兲 , m j共t兲

共2兲

where mi共t兲 is the income of agent i at time t and the collision matrix M defines the exchange mechanism. In this class of models, one considers a system with N agents 共individuals or corporates兲 and total money M. This is a closed economic system where N and M are fixed 共microcanonical ensemble兲, which corresponds to no migration or production in the system where the only economic activity is confined to trading. Another way of looking at this is to consider slow rates of growth or decay. Thus, the microscopic time scale 共of trading兲 is much smaller in comparison to the time scale at which the economy experiences growth or collapse. In any trading, a pair of traders i and j exchange their money 关8–12兴 and locally conserve it, while nobody ends up with negative money 关mi共t兲 ⱖ 0, i.e., debt not allowed兴, mi共t + 1兲 = mi共t兲 + ⌬m;

m j共t + 1兲 = m j共t兲 − ⌬m.

共3兲

Time 共t兲 changes by one unit after each trading. The simplest casein introduced by Dragulescu and Yakovenko 共关9兴, DY model hereafter兲 considers a random fraction of total money to be shared. The steady-state 共t → ⬁兲 money follows a Gibbs distribution: P共m兲 = 共1 / T兲exp共−m / T兲; T = M / N. This result is robust and is independent of the topology of the 共undirected兲 exchange

056117-1

©2010 The American Physical Society

PHYSICAL REVIEW E 82, 056117 共2010兲

ARNAB CHATTERJEE AND PARONGAMA SEN

mi共t + 1兲 = ␭mi共t兲 + ⑀ij兵共1 − ␭兲关mi共t兲 + m j共t兲兴其,

共4兲

101 10

P(mk | λk)

space; it is regular lattice, fractal, or small world 关11兴. Savings is an important ingredient in a trading process 关13兴. A saving propensity factor ␭ was introduced in the random exchange model 关10兴, where each trader at time t saves a fraction ␭ of its money mi共t兲 and trades randomly with the rest,

10

-1

10

-2

10-3

m j共t + 1兲 = ␭m j共t兲 + 共1 − ⑀ij兲兵共1 − ␭兲关mi共t兲 + m j共t兲兴其, 共5兲

10-4

⑀ij being a random fraction, coming from the stochastic nature of the trading. In this model, introduced by Chakraborti and Chakrabarti 共关10兴, CC model hereafter兲, the steady-state distribution P共m兲 of money is decaying on both sides with the mostprobable money per agent shifting away from m = 0 共for ␭ = 0兲 to M / N as ␭ → 1. This model has been argued to resemble a gamma distribution 关14–16兴, while the exact form of the distribution for this model is still unknown. A very similar model was proposed by Angle 关17兴 several years back in sociology journals, the numerical simulations of which fit well to gamma distributions. In a real society or economy, saving ␭ is very inhomogeneous. The evolution of money in a corresponding model, introduced by Chatterjee, Chakrabarti, and Manna 共关18兴, CCM model hereafter兲 can be written as

10-5 10

共7兲 It looks similar to the CC model, except that ␭i and ␭ j, the saving propensities of agents i and j, are different. The agents have saving propensities, distributed randomly and independently as ⌳共␭兲, such that ⌳共␭兲 is nonvanishing as ␭ → 1; ␭i is quenched for each agent 共␭i are independent of trading or t兲. The actual asset distribution P共m兲 in such a model depends on the form of ⌳共␭兲, but for all of them the asymptotic form of the distribution will become Pareto-like 关Eq. 共1兲兴. For uniform distribution, ⌳共␭兲 = 1 and ␯ = 1. However, for distributions ⌳共␭兲 ⬀ 共1 − ␭兲␦ ,

共8兲

P共m兲 ⬃ m−共2+␦兲 关11,18,19兴. In the CCM model, agents with higher saving propensity tend to hold higher average wealth, which is justified by the fact that the saving propensity in the rich population is always high 关20兴. Analytical understanding of CCM model has been possible until now under certain approximations 关21兴, and mean-field theory 关19,22兴 suggests that the agent with saving ␭ possesses wealth m共␭兲 in the steady state, where m共␭兲 = C/共1 − ␭兲,

共9兲

with C ⬀ 1 / ln共N兲. The precise analytical formulation of the above models has been recently considered with success, and the results have been derived in most cases 关23兴. There have been recent efforts in analyzing the CCM model at a microscopic scale 关24兴. Variations of these models have been con-

-6

10-2

10-1

100

101

102

mk

FIG. 1. 共Color online兲 Distribution P共mk 兩 ␭k兲 of money mk for the tagged agent k with a particular value of savings ␭k in the CCM model with uniformly distributed savings 共␦ = 0兲. The data are shown for a system of N = 256 agents.

sidered in several manners to obtain similar 共e.g., for annealed case 关25兴兲 or different 共as on networks兲 results 关26,27兴. It has also been shown that the results are invariant even if one considers a canonical ensemble 关28兴. Some microeconomic formulations have also proved to be useful 关29兴.

mi共t + 1兲 = ␭imi共t兲 + ⑀ij关共1 − ␭i兲mi共t兲 + 共1 − ␭ j兲m j共t兲兴, 共6兲 m j共t + 1兲 = ␭ jm j共t兲 + 共1 − ⑀ij兲关共1 − ␭i兲mi共t兲 + 共1 − ␭ j兲m j共t兲兴.

0 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 0.95

0

III. STUDYING DYNAMICS OF AGENTS

In the DY and CC models, agents are homogeneous. DY model is nothing but a special case of the CC model where ␭ = 0. In these models, studying an individual agent and the whole system are equivalent. On the contrary, the presence of the distributed saving propensity 共quenched disorder兲 in CCM model gives it a rich structure and calls for a careful look at the local scale 共at the level of individuals兲 besides computing global quantities. In this study, we perform extensive numerical simulations with system of N agents, with uniform distribution ⌳共␭兲 = 1, bounded above by 1 − 1 / N. We look at the dynamics of a tagged agent k, having a saving propensity ␭k, in a pool of N agents distributed according to a quenched ⌳共␭兲. We try to see how the individual distributions P共mk 兩 ␭k兲 look like 共see Fig. 1兲. As reported elsewhere 关11,18,30,31兴, the agents with smaller values of savings ␭k barely have money of the order of average money in the market. On the other hand, agents with high saving propensity ␭k possess money comparable to the average money in the market, and in fact, for the richest agent, the distribution extends almost up to the total money M. A. Distribution of change in wealth

Upon trading with another agent l, the money of the tagged agent k changes by an amount ⌬mk = mk共t + 1兲 − mk共t兲 = − 关ml共t + 1兲 − ml共t兲兴. We compute the distributions D共⌬mk 兩 ␭k兲 in the steady state, given that agent k has a saving propensity ␭k 共Fig. 2兲. We

056117-2

PHYSICAL REVIEW E 82, 056117 共2010兲

AGENT DYNAMICS IN KINETIC MODELS OF WEALTH… 0 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 0.95

10

D(∆mk | λk)

2 101 10 0

10

-1

10

101 -0.3-0.2-0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3

-2

10

2×106

0.12

106



3

10

2

0.08

a(λk)

103

-106

0.04

-2×106 10 0

0 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50

10-3 -0.04

10-4 10-5

0

7

t

2×10

7

0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 0.95

-0.08

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

0

2

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

λk

∆mk

To investigate the dynamics at the microscopic level, one can conceive of a walk for the agents in the so-called wealth space, in which each agent walks a step forward when she gains and one step backward if she incurs a loss. The walks are correlated in the sense that when two agents interact, if one takes a step forward, the other has to move backward. On the other hand, two agents can interact irrespective of their positions in the wealth space unlike the Brownian particles. Once the system is in the steady state, we define x共t + 1兲 = x共t兲 + 1 if our tagged agent gains money, and x共t + 1兲 = x共t兲 − 1 if she loses. In other words, x共t兲 performs a walk in one dimension. Without loss of generality we start from origin 关x共0兲 = 0兴, and we insist t = 0 is well within the steady state. We investigate the properties of this walk by computing the mean displacement 具x共t兲典 and the mean-square displacement 具x2共t兲典 − 具x共t兲典2. Actually, one can also consider a walk for a tagged agent where the increments 共i.e., step lengths兲 are the money gained or lost at each step, but the exponential distribution obtained for such step lengths 共Fig. 2兲 indicates that it will be simple diffusionlike 关32兴. C. Results for the walk

For the CC model, for any value of the fixed saving propensity ␭, we obtain a conventional random walk in the

1011

0 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 0.95 10-5 t2

1010 109 108 2

B. Walk in the wealth space: Definition

sense 具x共t兲典 is zero and 具x2共t兲典 − 具x共t兲典2 ⬃ t. However, for the CCM model, results are quite different. It is found that 具x共t兲典 has a drift, 具x共t兲典 ⬃ a共␭k兲t. a共␭k兲 varies continuously with ␭k, taking positive to negative values as one goes from low to high values of savings ␭k 共see inset of Fig. 3兲, respectively. It is obvious that for some ␭ⴱk , there is no drift, a共␭ⴱk 兲 = 0. ␭ⴱk is estimated to be about 0.469 by interpolation method. On the other hand, 具x2典 − 具x典2 ⬃ t2 for all ␭k, which is a case of ballistic diffusion 共Fig. 4兲. The negative or positive drifts of the walks indicate that the probabilities of gain and loss are not equal for any agent in general. Plotting the fraction of times the tagged agent gains or loses in Fig. 5共a兲, it is indeed found that an agent with a smaller ␭ gains with more probability while the opposite happens for agents with larger ␭. Indeed, the intersection of the two curves is the point ␭ⴱk where the probabilities are equal and the corresponding walk should show 具x典 = 0. It is difficult, however, to detect numerically ␭ⴱk exactly, which

107 106

2

observe this distribution to have asymmetries both for small and large values of saving propensities ␭k. Total money remains constant in the steady state for any agent. An agent with a relatively higher ␭ incurs losses which are considerably small in magnitude. This immediately suggests that agents with larger savings must be having more exchanges where losses, however small, occur. The magnified portion of the distribution shows that it is really so 共shown in the inset of Fig. 2兲.

FIG. 3. 共Color online兲 Measures for the gain-loss walk: the inset shows 具x典 with time for different values of savings ␭k, showing the drifts. The slopes a共␭k兲 are also shown. The estimate of ␭ⴱk is approximately 0.469. The data are shown for a system of N = 256 agents.

-

FIG. 2. 共Color online兲 Distribution D共⌬mk 兩 ␭k兲 of money difference ⌬mk for the tagged agent k with a particular value of savings ␭k in the CCM model with uniformly distributed savings 共␦ = 0兲. The data are shown for a system of N = 256 agents. The inset shows that for higher ␭, probability of losses becomes larger in the region −0.2⬍ ⌬mk ⬍ 0.

10

5

104 10

3

10

2

10

1

10

2

10

3

4

5

10

10

6

10

7

10

t

FIG. 4. 共Color online兲 Measures for the gain-loss walk: time variation of 具x2典 − 具x典2 for different values of savings ␭k and a guide to t2. The data are shown for a system of N = 256 agents.

056117-3

PHYSICAL REVIEW E 82, 056117 共2010兲

ARNAB CHATTERJEE AND PARONGAMA SEN 0.1

b 0.52

0.53 0.51

0.51

0.5

0.5 0.49

0.49

0.48

0.48

0.05

λk=0.2 λk=0.4 λk=0.6 λk=0.8

λ Pg - Pl

0.52

<λ>

fraction of gain and loss

0.54

0.53

gain loss

a

0

0

-0.05

0.47 0.47

0.46

1

0.05 0 -0.05

-0.1

0.45

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8

0.1

Pg - Pl

0.55

-0.1

0.46 0

0.2

0.4 0.6 λk

0.8

10

0.2

0.4 0.6 λk

0.8

1

-0.4

FIG. 5. 共Color online兲 共a兲 Plot of probabilities of gain and loss for different values of savings propensity ␭k of the tagged agent. The data are shown for a system of N = 256 agents. 共b兲 The plot of the average value 具␭典 when a gain or loss is being incurred shown against ␭k of the tagged agent.

lies close to 0.47, and check whether an agent with ␭ⴱk behaves like a conventional random walker or shows ballistic diffusion. Simulations using values of ␭ even very close to 0.47 always show ballistic behavior. In order to explain the above results, we investigate at a finer level the walk when the tagged agent with ␭k interacts with another agent with saving ␭. First, we calculate the average 具␭典 when the tagged agents lose or gain and find that for a gain, one has to interact with an agent with a higher ␭ in general. This is shown in Fig. 5共b兲. In fact, the average value is very weakly dependent on ␭k and significantly greater or less than 0.5 for a gain or loss. This is contrary to the expectation that gain or loss does not depend on the saving propensities of the interacting agents. Having obtained evidence that gain or loss depends on the interacting agents’ saving propensities, we compute the probability of gain and loss, Pg and Pl, respectively, as a function of ␭ for the agent with saving ␭k. The data show that indeed an agent gains with higher probability while interacting with an agent with ␭ ⬎ ␭k and vice versa. In fact, the data for different ␭k collapse when Pg − Pl are plotted against a scaled variable y = 共␭ − ␭k兲 / 共1.5+ ␭k + ␭兲, as shown in Fig. 6, indicating a linear variation with y, i.e.,

-0.3

-0.2

␭ − ␭k . 1.5 + ␭k + ␭

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

y

FIG. 6. 共Color online兲 Data collapse for ␭k = 0.2, 0.4, 0.6, and 0.8 is shown for Pg − Pl versus the scaled variable y = 共␭ − ␭k兲 / 共1.5 + ␭k + ␭兲 for N = 256. The inset shows the unscaled data.

1 − 共1.5 + 2␭ⴱk 兲关ln共2.5 + ␭ⴱk 兲 − ln共1.5 + ␭ⴱk 兲兴 = 0,

共11兲

␭ⴱk ⯝ 0.4658,

which is consistent with solving which we get the earlier observations. It may be added here that, in principle, the probability of gain or of loss while two agents interact can be calculated from the money distribution. In the CCM model, when two agents with money m1 and m2 and saving propensities ␭1 and ␭2, respectively, interact, the difference in money before and after transaction for, say, the second agent is given by 关共1 − ␭1兲m1 − 共1 − ␭2兲m2兴 / 2. Therefore, for the second agent to lose, m2 must be greater than m⬘ = m1共1 − ␭1兲 / 共1 − ␭2兲 and the corresponding probability is given by



M

P共m1兩␭1兲dm1

0



M

m⬘

P共m2兩␭2兲dm2 .

共12兲

However, the exact form of the money distribution is not known 关28兴 for the CCM case. For the CC model, ␭ = ␭1 = ␭2 and letting M → ⬁, the above integral becomes





P共m1兩␭兲dm1

0

= Pg − Pl = const

-0.1







P共m2兩␭兲dm2

m1



P共m1兩␭兲关1 − ˜P共m1兩␭兲兴dm1 ,

共13兲

0

共10兲

We have checked that there is hardly any finite-size effect on the collapse in the sense that the similarly scaled data for N = 100 collapse exactly on those for N = 256. An agent with a high value of ␭ will interact with a higher probability with agents whose saving propensities are lesser, causing a loss of money. Therefore, in the wealth space it will have tendency to take more steps in the negative direction. This explains the negative drift for large ␭. It is possible to estimate the value of ␭ⴱk using Eq. 共10兲 utilizing the fact that the integrated value of Pg − Pl over all ␭ should be zero for ␭k = ␭ⴱk . This gives

where ˜P共m兲 = 兰m 0 P共m兲dm is the cumulative distribution of ˜ money. Since P = ⳵⳵mP , the right-hand side of Eq. 共13兲 is equal to 1/2 independent of the form of P共m 兩 ␭兲. Thus, in the CC case we find equal probability of gain or loss leading to a simple random walk. In the CCM, however, the results are expected to be dependent on ␭1, ␭2 as Eq. 共12兲 indicates. IV. DISCUSSIONS

The analogy with a gaslike many-body system has led to the formulation of the kinetic exchange models of markets. The random scatteringlike dynamics of money 共and wealth兲 in a closed trading market, in analogy with energy conserved exchange models, reveals interesting features. Self-

056117-4

PHYSICAL REVIEW E 82, 056117 共2010兲

AGENT DYNAMICS IN KINETIC MODELS OF WEALTH…

organization is a key emerging feature of these simple models when saving factors are introduced. These models produce asset distributions resembling those observed in reality and are quite well studied now 关11兴. These have prospective applications in other spheres of social science, as in application in policy making and taxation, and also physical sciences, possibly in designing desired energy spectrum for different types of chemical reactions. In this paper, we have looked at the dynamics of agents at the scale of individuals. We study the distribution of money for a tagged agent given a particular value of saving propensity. We also analyze the distribution of money differences in successive exchanges. We conceived of a walk in an abstract space performed by the agents in different kinetic gaslike models, which reveals the characteristics of gains and losses made by the agents. Specifically, considering only whether an agent gains or loses, a walk can be defined in the wealth space, which is a random walk for the CC model while for the CCM model it is found to be ballistic in nature for generic values of ␭. On studying the dynamics at a microscopic level, we find that an agent gains with a higher probability when interacting with another agent with a larger ␭. Thus, one would expect

that for ␭ = 0.5 there will be equal gains and losses which would give rise zero drift in the corresponding walk in the wealth space for the CCM model. The value of ␭ⴱk for which we do get such a result is quite close to this estimate. An accurate estimate of ␭ⴱk ⯝ 0.4658 is obtained by considering the scaling behavior of 共probabilities of兲 gains and losses. In the CCM model, our study leads to the discovery of the way gains and losses are dependent on the saving propensities of the agents, which cannot be arrived at using any existing results either analytical or numerical. Using Eq. 共9兲, one can calculate the average money exchanged between two agents which turns out to be independent of their saving propensities. Hence, the intriguing question that remains to be solved is why the probability of gain over loss depends on the savings of the interacting agents.

关1兴 V. Pareto, Cours d’Economie Politique 共F. Rouge, Lausanne, 1897兲. 关2兴 B. B. Mandelbrot, Int. Econom. Rev. 1, 79 共1960兲. 关3兴 Econophysics of Wealth Distributions, edited by A. Chatterjee, S. Yarlagadda, and B. K. Chakrabarti 共Springer Verlag, Milan, 2005兲. 关4兴 Econophysics and Sociophysics, edited by B. K. Chakrabarti, A. Chakraborti, and A. Chatterjee 共Wiley-VCH, Berlin, 2006兲. 关5兴 S. Sinha, A. Chatterjee, A. Chakraborti, and B. K. Chakrabarti, Econophysics: An Introduction 共Wiley-VCH, Berlin, 2010兲. 关6兴 V. M. Yakovenko and J. Barkley Rosser, Jr., Rev. Mod. Phys. 81, 1703 共2009兲. 关7兴 A. C. Silva and V. M. Yakovenko, Europhys. Lett. 69, 304 共2005兲; A. A. Drăgulescu and V. M. Yakovenko, Eur. Phys. J. B 20, 585 共2001兲; Physica A 299, 213 共2001兲; M. Levy and S. Solomon, ibid. 242, 90 共1997兲; S. Sinha, ibid. 359, 555 共2006兲; H. Aoyama, W. Souma, and Y. Fujiwara, ibid. 324, 352 共2003兲; T. Di Matteo, T. Aste, and S. T. Hyde, in The Physics of Complex Systems (New Advances and Perspectives), edited by F. Mallamace and H. E. Stanley 共IOS Press, Amsterdam, 2004兲, p. 435; F. Clementi and M. Gallegati, Physica A 350, 427 共2005兲; N. Ding and Y. Wang, Chin. Phys. Lett. 24, 2434 共2007兲. 关8兴 B. K. Chakrabarti and S. Marjit, Indian J. Phys., B 69, 681 共1995兲; S. Ispolatov, P. L. Krapivsky, and S. Redner, Eur. Phys. J. B 2, 267 共1998兲. 关9兴 A. A. Drăgulescu and V. M. Yakovenko, Eur. Phys. J. B 17, 723 共2000兲. 关10兴 A. Chakraborti and B. K. Chakrabarti, Eur. Phys. J. B 17, 167 共2000兲. 关11兴 A. Chatterjee and B. K. Chakrabarti, Eur. Phys. J. B 60, 135 共2007兲; A. Chatterjee, S. Sinha, and B. K. Chakrabarti, Curr.

Sci. 92, 1383 共2007兲. 关12兴 A. S. Chakrabarti and B. K. Chakrabarti, Econom. J. 4, 2010-4 共2010兲. 关13兴 P. A. Samuelson, Economics 共McGraw-Hill International, Auckland, 1980兲. 关14兴 M. Patriarca, A. Chakraborti, and K. Kaski, Phys. Rev. E 70, 016104 共2004兲. 关15兴 P. Repetowicz, S. Hutzler, and P. Richmond, Physica A 356, 641 共2005兲. 关16兴 M. Lallouache, A. Jedidi, and A. Chakraborti, Sci. Cult. 76, 478 共2010兲. 关17兴 J. Angle, Soc. Forces 65, 293 共1986兲; Physica A 367, 388 共2006兲. 关18兴 A. Chatterjee, B. K. Chakrabarti, and S. S. Manna, Physica A 335, 155 共2004兲; Phys. Scr., T T106, 36 共2003兲. 关19兴 P. K. Mohanty, Phys. Rev. E 74, 011117 共2006兲. 关20兴 K. E. Dynan, J. Skinner, and S. P. Zeldes, J. Polit. Econ. 112, 397 共2004兲. 关21兴 A. Chatterjee, B. K. Chakrabarti, and R. B. Stinchcombe, Phys. Rev. E 72, 026126 共2005兲. 关22兴 A. Kar Gupta, in Econophysics and Sociophysics, edited by B. K. Chakrabarti, A. Chakraborti, and A. Chatterjee 共WileyVCH, Berlin, 2006兲, p. 161. 关23兴 B. Düring and G. Toscani, Physica A 384, 493 共2007兲; B. Düring, D. Matthes, and G. Toscani, Phys. Rev. E 78, 056103 共2008兲; D. Matthes and G. Toscani, J. Stat. Phys. 130, 1087 共2008兲; Kinetic and Related Models 1, 1 共2008兲; V. Comincioli, L. Della Croce, and G. Toscani, ibid. 2, 135 共2009兲. 关24兴 A. Chatterjee, in Mathematical Modeling of Collective Behavior in Socio-Economic and Life Sciences, edited by G. Naldi et al. 共Birkhaüser, Boston, 2010兲, p. 31. 关25兴 A. Chatterjee and B. K. Chakrabarti, Physica A 382, 36

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

The authors thank B. K. Chakrabarti and S. S. Manna for some useful comments and discussions. A.C. was supported by the ComplexMarkets E.U. STREP project 516446 under Grant No. FP6-2003-NEST-PATH-1. P.S. was supported by DST Project No. SR/S2/CMP-56/2007.

056117-5

PHYSICAL REVIEW E 82, 056117 共2010兲

ARNAB CHATTERJEE AND PARONGAMA SEN 共2007兲. 关26兴 A. Chatterjee, Eur. Phys. J. B 67, 593 共2009兲. 关27兴 A. Chakraborty and S. S. Manna, Phys. Rev. E 81, 016111 共2010兲. 关28兴 U. Basu and P. K. Mohanty, Eur. Phys. J. B 65, 585 共2008兲. 关29兴 A. S. Chakrabarti and B. K. Chakrabarti, Physica A 388, 4151 共2009兲; 389, 3572 共2010兲.

关30兴 M. Patriarca et al., Econophysics of Wealth Distributions, edited by A. Chatterjee, S. Yarlagadda, and B. K. Chakrabarti 共Springer Verlag, Milan, 2005兲, p. 93. 关31兴 K. Bhattacharya et al., Econophysics of Wealth Distributions, edited by A. Chatterjee, S. Yarlagadda, and B. K. Chakrabarti 共Springer Verlag, Milan, 2005兲, p. 111. 关32兴 S. N. Majumdar, Physica A 389, 4299 共2010兲.

056117-6

Agent dynamics in kinetic models of wealth exchange

models with savings. For the model with uniform savings, agents perform simple random walks in the “wealth .... CCM model gives it a rich structure and calls for a careful look at the local ..... way gains and losses are dependent on the saving propensi- ties of the ... tives), edited by F. Mallamace and H. E. Stanley IOS Press,.

485KB Sizes 7 Downloads 289 Views

Recommend Documents

Kinetic exchange models for income and wealth ... - Springer Link
Dec 8, 2007 - small variation in the value of the power-law exponent that characterises the 'tail' of ... where P denotes the number density of people with in- come or wealth m and α, .... ticular, a class of kinetic exchange models have provided a

Kinetic models for wealth exchange on directed networks
Feb 14, 2009 - Kinetic models for wealth exchange on directed networks .... at the site i. ∑ ..... applications in other spheres of social science, as in ap-.

Real exchange rate dynamics in sticky wage models
c Graduate School of Economics, Kyoto University, Japan highlights. • Real exchange ... shocks driving the real exchange rate: shocks to nominal interest rates ...

Disorder induced phase transition in kinetic models of ...
simulations of the continuous version of the model indicate the existence of a universal continuous phase transition at p = pc below which a ... Mathematical formulations of such social behavior have helped us to understand how global consensus (i.e.

Models of Wage Dynamics - CiteSeerX
Dec 13, 2005 - Department of Economics. Concordia University .... expected output conditional on the worker is fit (¯YF ) or unfit (¯YU ). Notice that ¯YF >. ¯.

Models of Wage Dynamics - CiteSeerX
Dec 13, 2005 - interest rate. ... earning (and saving) in the first period. ... The earning growth rate is higher when A and w2 are higher, and when r and w1 are ...

Sources of Entropy in Representative Agent Models
distinguish them from additive power utility. With habits ..... Another consequence is an alternative route to long-horizon entropy: entropy for an infinite time ...

Models of Wage Dynamics - Semantic Scholar
Dec 13, 2005 - Therefore, defining mt ≡ {m1,m2, ..., mt} as the information5 available at time t, the optimal contract solves the history-contingent wage stream6 ...

Wealth Dynamics in a Bond Economy with ...
Feb 20, 2013 - The verification procedure consists of computing the following error ... We started with 100 grid points for the wealth share ω and increased this number until a sufficient level of ... permissible maximum memory. 8Model errors ...

Wealth dynamics on complex networks
Fax: +39-0577-23-4689. E-mail address: [email protected] (D. Garlaschelli). .... Random graphs, regular lattices and scale-free networks. The first point of ...

Kinetic market models with single commodity having ... - Springer Link
Jan 13, 2007 - In recent years, easy availability of data in electronic media has helped in the ... how the distribution of savings can be modified to re- produce the salient ..... B. Hayes, American Scientist, USA 90 (Sept.–Oct.), 400. (2002). 11.

Bluetooth Worms: Models, Dynamics, and Defense ... - CiteSeerX
layer interactions between Bluetooth devices in a network at the scale in our study .... worm attempts to infect the next device on the list. The probing process ...... For simplification, we do not model the social network that yields these buddy li

Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics
We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship ..... p = [c1/(c) + u)]e + [a/()AR + c)]m + [A/(bA + a)][u + (1 -.

Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics
We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms ... Massachusetts Institute of Technology ..... de/dm = 1 + l/fl = 1 1+.

Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and .... That development allows us to derive an analytical solution for the time path ...

theatre and film: the dynamics of exchange
The film derives its power from the visual representation of concepts and ..... successfully separate itself from theatrical assumptions until D.W. Griffith discovered ...

Kinetic Stabilization of Biopolymers in Single-Crystal ...
Department of Chemistry, Box 351700. UniVersity of Washington ... lactose solution and allowed to stand for 3-4 days at room temperature in a 24-well ... band (λex ) 470 nm) to prevent photobleaching.9 The data are comparable to those from ...

General aspects of interface bonding in kinetic sprayed coatings
Jun 27, 2008 - For soft/soft and hard/hard cases, the size variation of the thermal boost-up zone .... dynamic analysis of the particle bonding process, which.

ABOUT KINETIC SCHEMES BUILT IN ...
272-288. Mieussens L. (1999). Mod eles a vitesses discr etes et m ethodes num eriques pour l' equation de Boltzmann-BGK, chapter 3. Ph.D. Thesis of Bordeaux I University. Noh W.F. (1987). Errors for calculations of strong shocks using an artificial v

How to build and use agent-based models in social science
May 18, 1999 - 1 Computational modelling as a third way of building social science models. 2. 1.1 Building models ... networks, classifier systems, genetic algorithms. 1. Computational ..... Page 10 ... The most common algorithm is the genetic algori

kinetic data structures - Basch.org
Alas, this analysis completely breaks down in the case of line segments, as Lemma 3.1 no longer holds. Instead, we use another potential argument reminiscent of the one used independently by several authors 47, 51, 61] for proving upper bounds on the

kinetic data structures - Basch.org
of robustness), and the software system issue of combining existing kinetic data structures as black boxes .... here is only to give a good prototyping environment.

kinetic theory of gases pdf
Page 1 of 1. File: Kinetic theory ofgases pdf. Download now. Click here if your download doesn't start automatically. Page 1 of 1. kinetic theory of gases pdf.