A generalized Tullock contest Subhasish M. Chowdhurya and Roman M. Sheremetab a

School of Economics, Centre for Competition Policy, and Centre for Behavioral and

Experimental Social Science, University of East Anglia, Norwich NR4 7TJ, UK.  b

Argyros School of Business and Economics, Chapman University, One University Drive, Orange, CA 92866, U.S.A.

March 2010

Abstract We construct a generalized Tullock contest under complete information where contingent upon winning or losing, the payoff of a player is a linear function of prizes, own effort, and the effort of the rival. This structure nests a number of existing contests in the literature and can be used to analyze new types of contests. We characterize the unique symmetric equilibrium and show that small parameter modifications may lead to substantially different types of contests and hence different equilibrium effort levels.

JEL Classifications: C72, D72, D74 Keywords: rent-seeking, contest, spillover Corresponding author: Subhasish M. Chowdhury; E-mail: [email protected]

1. Introduction Contests are economic or social interactions in which two or more players expend costly resources in order to win a prize. The resources expended by players determine their probability of winning a prize. In this article we construct a generalized Tullock contest under complete information. We consider a simple two-player contest where, contingent upon winning or losing, a player receives different prizes. Players’ outcome-contingent payoffs are linear functions of prizes, own effort, and the effort of the rival.1 This structure nests a number of existing contests in the literature and can be used to analyze new types of contests. We characterize the unique symmetric equilibrium and show that small parameter modifications may lead to substantially different types of contests and hence different equilibrium effort levels. The rent-seeking contest literature originated with Tullock (1980). In this model, player ’s probability of winning is and . The function,

,

,

/

, where

and

are the efforts of players

, that maps efforts into probabilities of winning is called the

contest success function (CSF). The most popular versions of the Tullock CSF are the lottery ( = 1) and the all-pay auction (

∞).2 There are several reasons why Tullock’s CSF is widely

employed. First, a number of studies have provided axiomatic justification for it (Skaperdas 1996; Clark and Riis 1998). Second, Baye and Hoppe (2003) have identified conditions under which a variety of rent-seeking contests, innovation tournaments, and patent-race games are strategically equivalent to the Tullock contest. Economists often use modified payoffs in the Tullock contest in order to address specific research questions. For example, Skaperdas and Gan (1995) restrict the losing payoff to study the effect of risk aversion in a “limited liability” contest. Cohen and Sela (2005) restrict the winning payoff to show that in certain contests a weaker contestant can win with higher probability than a

2

stronger contestant. Many other studies use modified payoffs in the Tullock contest, a short list of example includes Chung (1996), Alexeev and Leitzel (1996), Lee and Kang (1998), Amegashie (1999), Glazer and Konrad (1999), Garfinkel and Skaperdas (2000), Grossman and Mendoza (2001), Öncüler and Croson (2005), and Matros and Armanios (2009). In this article we propose a generalized Tullock contest in which payoffs are linear functions of prizes, own effort, and the effort of the rival. Our model nests a number of the existing contests in the literature and also provides a framework for studying new contests. One of the main motivations for introducing a generalized structure is the fact that in many real life contests payoffs are endogenous, i.e., payoffs depend both on the individual and on the rival's effort. For example, in innovation contests one firm’s R&D effort may provide information spillovers that benefit its rival (D’Aspremont and Jacquemin 1988; Kamien et al. 1992). In a patent race the expenditure of a rival can decrease the patent value for the winner, creating a negative spillover (Alexeev and Leitzel 1996). Negative spillovers are often observed in military conflicts between countries (Garfinkel and Skaperdas 2000) or in biological survival contests (Baker 1996). Another example where spillovers are important is litigation (Farmer and Pecorino 1999; Baye et al. 2005). Depending on the litigation system, losers have to compensate winners for a portion of their legal expenditures or up to the amount actually spent by the loser. These create either negative or positive spillover effects of one party’s expenditure on another. Baye et al. (2010) model the spillovers in terms of an all-pay auction contest. We explicitly model such spillovers in the context of a Tullock lottery contest.3

3

2. Theoretical model We consider a two-player contest with two prizes. The players are denoted by and . 0 and the losing prize as

Both players value the winning prize as

winning the prize provides higher valuation than losing, i.e., 0 and

expend irreversible and costly efforts

. We assume that

. Players simultaneously

0. The probability of player winning the

contest is described by a Tullock lottery CSF: /      if   1/2                     if  

,

0 0

(1)

Contingent upon winning or losing, the payoff for player is a linear function of prizes, own effort, and the effort of the rival:            with probability                        with probability  1

, where

,

are cost parameters, and

,

, ,

(2)

are spillover parameters. To ensure that a player

has no incentive to expend infinite effort, we impose conditions that a player’s own effort has a negative direct impact on his winning payoff and a non-positive direct impact on his losing 0 and

payoff, that is,

0.

We define the contest described by (1) and (2) as Γ , , Ω , where Ω

, ,

,

,

,

is the parameter space. All parameters in Ω along with the CSF are

common knowledge for both players. The players are assumed to be risk neutral; therefore, for a given effort pair

,

, the expected payoff for player in contest Γ , , Ω is:

,

(3)

4

where

,

0,0 . For

setting

0, the expected payoff is ,

,

, and

/2. By

, expression (3) can be

rewritten as: ,

(4) ,

Player ’s best response is derived by maximizing Differentiating equation (4) with respect to

with respect to

.

yields the following first order condition:

,

(5)

The second order condition is: ,

(6)

From the second order condition (6) it is easy to verify that the payoff function for player is concave as long as: (7) If (7) holds then first order condition is necessary and sufficient for maximizing player ’s payoff. Consequently by solving (5) for receive the best response function of

and by substituting back the values of

in terms of the effort choice of

and , we

: (8)

if

/

function (8) depends on

; and ,

0, otherwise.4 It is clear that the best response

, the difference between

and

, and the spread between the

winning and the losing prize valuations. By simultaneously solving best response functions (8), and accounting for symmetric Nash equilibrium we obtain the unique equilibrium in which player and expend efforts of 5

(9) The expected equilibrium payoff in the symmetric equilibrium is given by: (10) Both the non-negative equilibrium effort condition and the second order condition hold if 0. Furthermore, to ensure that both players are willing to expend

3

positive efforts in equilibrium the equilibrium payoff has to be greater than or equal to the payoff of losing, i.e.,

0 and it means that the unit

. This condition translates into

cost of winning has to be lower than the unit spillover benefit from losing.

3. Existing contests in the literature 3.1. Contests without spillovers In the standard contest defined by Tullock (1980), both players have the same valuation for the prize and despite the outcome of the contest the efforts of both players are lost. In such a case,

0,

for player is equilibrium with

1, and the other parameters in Ω are zero. The best response function (Figure 1). The unique equilibrium is the symmetric /4. [Figure 1 is about here]

Skaperdas and Gan (1995) examine a ‘limited liability’ case in which the loser’s payoff is independent of the efforts expended. The authors motivate this example by stating that contestants may be entrepreneurs who borrow money to spend on research and development and thus are not legally responsible in case of loss. The loser of such a contest is unable to repay the loan and goes bankrupt. In such a case,

0,

1, and the other parameters in Ω are zero.

6

The best response function for player is

(Figure 1). Under the /3.

symmetric equilibrium we have

Garfinkel and Skaperdas (2000) consider a case in which two players compete to win a war. In this game player and have resource endowments of

and

which they can use to

win the contest. The winner receives the sum of resources minus the sum of efforts expended by both players. It is also assumed that war destroys a fraction 1 Thus, the needed restrictions are

, and the other parameters in Ω

,

are zero. The best response function is 2 ). Although

and

0,1 of the total payoff.

(Figure 1, where

can be different, the equilibrium efforts for players and are the same, /4.

i.e.,

3.2. Contests with spillovers A simple linear version of the Chung (1996) contest with positive spillovers can be captured by Γ , ,

, 0,

1, 1, , 0 , where

0,1 is the degree of spillover. The / 1

corresponding best response function is equilibrium efforts are

/4 1

and the symmetric

. Similarly, a contest of Alexeev and Leitzel

(1996), where the value of the winning prize decreases with the total effort expenditures, can be captured by Γ , ,

, 0, 1, 1, 1,0 . The resulting best response function is

and the symmetric equilibrium efforts are

/5.

Baye et al. (2005) examine and compare several litigation systems under the all-pay auction CSF. We use the Tullock lottery CSF in Baye et al. (2005) structure by restricting

7

0,

1

,

,

1

, and

, where α

0,1 and

0,1 .

Interestingly enough, when we restrict the parameters to match their model, the best response / is independent of the value of . Note that when

function

1 (i.e., the

case of American, Marshall, and Quayle systems of litigation), the best response function as well as the symmetric equilibrium turns out to be qualitatively equivalent to that in Tullock (1980). Similarly, the two-player versions of other contests by Farmer and Pecorino (1998), Lee and Kang (1998), Amegashie (1999), Glazer and Konrad (1999), Garfinkel and Skaperdas (2000), Grossman and Mendoza (2001), and Matros and Armanios (2009) can be obtained from our generalized contest by placing appropriate parameter restrictions.

4. New contests 4.1. Contests without spillovers In a standard Tullock contest the unit cost of losing is the same as the unit cost of winning. However, in many real life situations we observe that the winner of the contest pays less than the loser. A prominent example is the government procurement auction for defense weapons. Different companies make costly investments to produce prototypes and the government shares the prototype’s production cost with only the winner.5 In these cases, the winner of the contest faces lower marginal cost than the loser. Rightfully, this contest can be 0,

called a ‘lazy winner’ contest. We can capture this by setting

0 and other

parameters in Ω to zero. Therefore, the payoff for player is given by ,

         with probability                             with probability  1

8

, ,

(11)

/

The resulting best response function is /

symmetric equilibrium effort levels are

3

and the

.

4.2. Contests with spillovers Next, we consider an ‘input spillover’ contest where the effort expended by player j partially benefits player and vice versa. This case can be interpreted as the input spillover effect in R&D innovation (Kamien et al., 1992). In our model we assume that the winner (loser) of the contest receives a benefit proportional to the loser’s (winner’s) effort. After setting 1, and

0 the payoff function of ‘input spillover’ contest takes the form: ,

where

         with probability                  with probability  1

 

0,

0, and

,

         ,

(12)

4. [Figure 2 is about here]

Note that the best response function, dramatically with / 4

and

, changes

. The symmetric equilibrium effort of this contest is given by . Hence, a player expends more (less) effort with an increase in the

spillover benefit from winning (losing). Figure 2 displays best response functions and resulting equilibria for different values of 

and

. As we move left to right,

decreases, and

the total effort expended also decreases. This has a simple intuition: if the positive externality gained by losing increases relative to that of winning then the players will spend less effort to win the contest. This case resembles R&D contests in countries where property rights are not

9

protected by the government and the spillover in case of losing is very large. Therefore, there is a strong incentive to free ride on the effort of the others.

5. Discussion In this article we construct a generalized Tullock contest under complete information. We show how different existing contests in the literature can be nested under this generalized structure. We also characterize the unique symmetric equilibrium and show that small parameter modifications may lead to substantially different equilibrium effort levels. Finally, we introduce and characterize two new contests to the literature. Our results can be applied to the fields of labor economics, law and economics, industrial organization, public economics, and political economy. By applying certain parameter restrictions to our model one can also imitate the rentseeking contests, patent races, military combats, or legal conflicts. There are a number of interesting extensions of our analysis. For example, one can use our generalized structure to meet a given objective of a contest designer. This objective varies between contests. In sports or social benefit programs the designer may want to maximize the total expenditures of effort, whereas in rent-seeking or electoral contests the designer may want to minimize them. For a given objective, one can appropriately set the parameters of our model so that the desired outcome is achieved. Other extensions include contests with more than two players, the effects of risk aversion and incomplete information. Finally, it would be interesting to test empirically the predictions of our generalized contest model. In particular, our analysis demonstrates that small parameter modifications may lead to substantially different equilibrium effort levels. To test these predictions, one could design an experiment similar to Sheremeta (2010a, 2010b). We leave these questions for future research.

10

Acknowledgements We have benefitted from the helpful comments of Kyung Hwan Baik, Tim Cason, Dan Kovenock, Sanghack Lee, Stephen Martin, two anonymous referees, and an associate editor, as well as seminar participants at Indian Statistical Institute - Calcutta, Kookmin University, Purdue University, and the participants at the Fall 2008 Midwest Economic Theory Meetings. Any remaining errors are ours.

Endnotes 1

Contests are characterized by three attributes such as prizes, players, and the efforts of the

players (Konrad 2009). 2

In a first-price all-pay auction the winner is the player who expends the most effort (Baye et al.

1996). 3

Chung (1996) is among the first to consider spillover/externality of rival’s efforts in a contest

framework. Our generalized model differs substantially from Chung’s model. First, Chung (1996) uses strictly non-linear spillovers, whereas the current model considers linear spillovers. Second, Chung’s model incorporates strictly endogenous prizes and strictly positive spillovers from winning (i.e., the winning prize is a strictly increasing and concave function of the total effort), whereas the current model captures both positive and negative spillovers from winning and from losing. Moreover, the current model captures the cases where the prizes are exogenous, or a function of only one of the player's efforts. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out the differences.

11

4

Note that the restriction (7) is weaker than the restriction needed for (8) to be well defined.

Hence, when the best response is positive then solving the best response functions will lead us to an equilibrium. 5

See Kaplan et al. (2002) for a detailed discussion. Matros and Armanios (2009) also study a

very similar contest.

References Alexeev, M., & Leitzel, J. (1996). Rent shrinking. Southern Economic Journal, 62, 620-626. Baker, R. (1996). Sperm wars: The science of sex. New York: Basic Books. Baye, M., Kovenock, D., & de-Vries, C.G. (1996). The all-pay auction with complete information. Economic Theory, 8, 291-305. Baye, M., Kovenock, D., & de-Vries, C.G. (2005). Comparative analysis of litigation systems: an auction-theoretic approach. Economic Journal, 115, 583-601. Baye, M., Kovenock, D., & de-Vries, C.G. (2010). Contests with rank-order spillovers. Economic Theory, forthcoming. Baye, M.R., & Hoppe H.C. (2003). The strategic equivalence of rent-seeking, innovation, and patent-race games. Games and Economic Behavior, 44, 217-226. Chung, T.Y. (1996). Rent-seeking contest when the prize increases with aggregate efforts. Public Choice, 87, 55-66. Clark, D.J., Riis, C. (1998). Contest success functions: an extension. Economic Theory, 11, 201204. Cohen, C., & Sela, A. (2005). Manipulations in contests. Economics Letters, 86, 135-139. D’Aspremont C., & Jacquemin, A. (1988). Cooperative and noncooperative R&D in duopoly with spillovers. American Economic Review, 78, 1133-1137.

12

Farmer, A., & Pecorino, P. (1999). Legal expenditure as a rent-seeking game. Public Choice, 100, 271-288. Garfinkel, M.R., & Skaperdas, S. (2000). Conflict without misperceptions or incomplete information - how the future matters. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44, 793-807. Glazer, A., & Konrad, K. (1999). Taxation of rent-seeking activities. Journal of Public Economics, 72, 61-72. Grossman, H.I., & Mendoza, J. (2001). Butter and guns: complementarity between economic and military competition. Economics of Governance, 2, 25–33. Kamien, M., Muller, E., & Zang, I. (1992). Research joint ventures and R&D cartels. American Economic Review, 82, 1293-1306. Kaplan, T., Luski, I., Sela, A., & Wettstein, D. (2002). All-pay auctions with variable rewards. Journal of Industrial Economics, 4, 417–430. Konrad, K.A. (2009). Strategy and dynamics in contests. Oxford University Press. Lee, S., & Kang, J. (1998). Collective contests with externalities. European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 727– 738.

Matros, A., & Armanios, D. (2009). Tullock's contest with reimbursements. Public Choice, 141, 49–63. Öncüler, A., & Croson, R. (2005). Rent-seeking for a risky rent: A model and experimental investigation. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 17, 403-429. Sheremeta, R.M. (2010a). Contest design: An experimental investigation. Economic Inquiry, forthcoming. Sheremeta, R.M. (2010b). Experimental comparison of multi-stage and one-stage contests. Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 731–747.

13

Skaperdas, S. (1992). Cooperation, conflict, and power in the absence of property rights. American Economic Review, 82, 720-739. Skaperdas, S. (1996). Contest success functions. Economic Theory, 7, 283-290. Skaperdas, S., & Gan, L. (1995). Risk aversion in contests. Economic Journal, 105, 951-62. Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, Gordon Tullock, (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press, 97-112.

Figures Figure 1 – Best response functions and resulting equilibria (W = 1) xi 1

xi 1

xi 1

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0

0

0 0

0.2

0.4 0.6 0.8 Tullock (1980)

0

1

xj

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Skaperdas and Gan (1995)

0

1

xj

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Garfinkel and Skaperdas (2000)

1

xj

Figure 2 – Best response functions for ‘input spillover’ contest (W = 1) xi 1

xi 1

xi 1

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0

0

0 0

0.2

0.4

0.6 0.8 1  1 and  2  0

1

xj

0

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1  0.5 and  2  0.5

14

1

xj

0

0.2

0.4 0.6 0.8 1  0 and  2  1

1

xj

A generalized Tullock contest

Depending on the litigation system, losers have to compensate winners for a portion of their legal ... By simultaneously solving best response functions (8), and accounting for symmetric. Nash equilibrium we obtain the ... In a standard Tullock contest the unit cost of losing is the same as the unit cost of winning. However, in ...

227KB Sizes 1 Downloads 256 Views

Recommend Documents

A GENERALIZED VECTOR-VALUED TOTAL ...
Digital Signal Processing Group. Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú. Lima, Peru. Brendt Wohlberg. ∗. T-5 Applied Mathematics and Plasma Physics.

A generalized quantum nonlinear oscillator
electrons in pure crystals and also for the virtual-crystal approximation in the treatment of .... solvable non-Hermitian potentials within the framework of PDMSE.

Jana Vignana Vedika National Short Film Contest, JVV Contest 2018 ...
Jana Vignana Vedika National Short Film Contest, JVV Contest 2018 Application.pdf. Jana Vignana Vedika National Short Film Contest, JVV Contest 2018 Application.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying Jana Vignana Vedika Nationa

A generalized inquisitive semantics.
the definition of inquisitive semantics can be easily reformulated in such a way ... Recall that a P-index (or a P-valuation) is a map from P to {0, 1}, and we.

A Generalized Complementary Intersection Method ...
The contribution of this paper ... and stochastic collocation method. However, the ... Contributed by the Design Automation Committee of ASME for publication in.

A generalized inquisitive semantics.
the definition of inquisitive semantics can be easily reformulated in such a way ..... The second weak distribution law is ..... mative content in the classical way.

Contest Rule Book
6. E. Contest Categories. 7. F. Important Notices for Contestants. 7. G. Program Materials. 7. II. Rules For All Categories. A. General Rules for All Categories. 8 ..... Inc., 1962. B. Required Written Material. For All Entries. Rule 12: Written Mate

In-Club Contest Agenda
Mar 8, 2011 - Contact Us: President會長: Genna Fu ... VPE教育副會長: Jeff Chen 0921-535790 [email protected]. VPM會員副會長: Year ...

Generalized and Doubly Generalized LDPC Codes ...
The developed analytical tool is then exploited to design capacity ... error floor than capacity approaching LDPC and GLDPC codes, at the cost of increased.

Essay Contest Form.pdf
Page 1 of 1. Page 1 of 1. Essay Contest Form.pdf. Essay Contest Form.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying Essay Contest Form.pdf.

REGOLAMENTO STORYPHOTO COMMUNITY PHOTO CONTEST ...
Monthly, direttamente dal proprio cellulare o dal proprio computer, non sono ... eventuale titolo dell'opera, indicazione dei dati Exif dello scatto fotografico e data, mail, ... STORYPHOTO COMMUNITY PHOTO CONTEST CALENDAR OK.pdf.

humorous speech contest -
ideas, logic, original thought. 15. 12-14 10-11 ... EFFECTIVENESS refers to your subjective judgement of how the speech came across. What was the purpose or ...

THE ORGANIZATION IQUIRY [Gordon Tullock].pdf
THE ORGANIZATION IQUIRY [Gordon Tullock].pdf. THE ORGANIZATION IQUIRY [Gordon Tullock].pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying ...

A Combinatorial Multiple Winner Contest with Package ...
preferences, Networks, Endogenous coalition formation, Asymmetric valuations .... problem under complete information whereas Moldovanu and Sela (2001, 2006) consider incomplete information. ... In follow up studies Clark and Riis (1998b) consider a n

Multidimensional generalized coherent states
Dec 10, 2002 - Generalized coherent states were presented recently for systems with one degree ... We thus obtain a property that we call evolution stability (temporal ...... The su(1, 1) symmetry has to be explored in a different way from the previo

NL_EN - WEDSTRIJDREGLEMENT_ CONTEST OF RULES.pdf ...
Page 1 of 6. WEDSTRIJDREGLEMENT. Viking Bar te Gent – Win een blokpakket in de pop-up store. LEES DEZE ACTIEVOORWAARDEN ZORGVULDIG.

State Mathematics Algebra II Contest
May 3, 2001 - In the xy-plane, how many lines whose x-intercept is a positive prime number and whose y-intercept is a positive integer pass through the point ...

Essay Contest Form.pdf
Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Essay Contest Form.pdf. Essay Contest Form.pdf. Open

A Note on Multi-winner Contest Mechanisms ∗
Feb 11, 2014 - becomes equivalent to another popular mechanism suggested by Berry (1993) ... Centre for Behavioural and Experimental Social Science,.

Evaluating Oral Interpretation Events: A Contest and ...
years as a forensic coach I've noticed four major values emerging for those students dedicated to preparing and ... Coast College; Costa Mesa, California 92626.

A Generalized Links and Text Properties Based Forum ...
Digital Forensics Lab. Cryptography ... information on the software used to create them. Cai et al. .... 1) Signature Generation and Signature Based Clustering:.

GENERALIZED COMMUTATOR FORMULAS ...
To do this, we need to modify conjugation calculus which is used in the literature ...... and N.A. Vavilov, Decomposition of transvections: A theme with variations.

Generalized Anxiety Disorder
1997). Three classes of drugs are commonly used to treat .... of school phobia. Journal of ..... Paradoxical anxiety enhancement due to relaxation training. Journal of ..... Auto- nomic characteristics of generalized anxiety disorder and worry.