A Dynamic Model of Price Signaling and Consumer Learning∗ Matthew Osborne†and Adam Hale Shapiro‡ March 7, 2012

Preliminary Draft: Please do not cite without the authors’ permission. Abstract We develop a model of consumer learning and price signaling where price and quality are optimally chosen by a monopolist. Prior to making a purchase, consumers infer the product’s quality given their beliefs about the distribution of quality conditional on price, and update their beliefs through a quasi-Bayesian learning process once the product’s quality is revealed. We simulate the optimal policy of a forward-looking monopolist under different assumptions about the strength of consumer beliefs, where consumers with stronger beliefs update more slowly than those with weak beliefs. We find that if consumers have strong beliefs, the equilibrium choices of price and quality display a type of cycling, where the firm produces a high-priced, high quality product for a many periods to increase consumer beliefs about quality, and then drops quality while keeping price high for a some time to exploit the slowness at which consumer beliefs update. If consumers have sufficiently weak beliefs, however, the firm will always choose to produce the high quality product and charge a high price. We also demonstrate that price signaling can generate downward rigidity in price response to cost shocks. ∗

The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bureau of Economic Analysis or the U.S. Department of Commerce. † Bureau of Economic Analysis ‡ Bureau of Economic Analysis

1

Key words:

1

Introduction

Consumers oftentimes have only imperfect information about product quality. Examples include experience goods such as computers, wine and physician services, but can also include infrequently purchased products such as automobiles and wedding services. Studies such as Judd and Riordan (1994) and Wolinsky (1983) have assessed the implications and conditions under which a product’s price may provide information to infer the product’s quality. These studies have assumed either a static or a two-period setting. In this study, we extend this line of research in two ways. First, we model the optimal price and quality choice of a forward-looking firm in an infinite horizon setting. Second, we model consumer learning about the distribution of quality conditional on price: given no prior information on quality and price, consumer beliefs about a firm’s quality may or may not be correct. However, over time consumers will observe realized price and quality, and will update their beliefs about a firm’s policy given their past experience. Such a setting may be important if a firm’s optimal strategy includes manipulating a consumers’ expectations about the relationship between price and quality. We examine the extent to which a firm can manipulate consumer expectations, and potentially exploit consumers, in such a dynamic setting. In our model, consumers have beliefs about the joint distribution of price and quality for the firm’s product. Prior to making a purchase, consumers do not observe the quality of the product, but make an inference about it using their beliefs. After purchase, the product’s quality is revealed and consumers update their beliefs through a quasi-Bayesian learning process. In each period, a forward-looking monopolist chooses the product’s price and quality, accounting for the fact that its choice will affect consumer beliefs and future profits. We investigate the firm’s optimal pricing and quality policy by solving the model numerically and simulating it. Our paper has two main findings, the first of which relates to how the firm can exploit consumer beliefs. We simulate the model under different assumptions about the strength of consumer beliefs, where consumers with stronger beliefs update more slowly than those with weak beliefs. We find that if consumers have strong beliefs, the equilibrium choices of price and quality display a type of cycling, where the firm produces a high-priced, high quality product for a many periods to increase consumer beliefs about quality, and then drops quality while keeping 1

price high for a some time to exploit the slowness at which consumer beliefs update. If consumers have sufficiently weak beliefs, however, the firm will always choose to produce the high quality product and charge a high price. This paper is related to a number of studies on price signaling, as well as studies on reputation for quality. Klein and Leffler (1981) and Shapiro (1983) examine the conditions under which firms do not “cheat” consumers by offering a quality that is less than contracted for. Both studies consider a forward-looking firm and find that prices are set at premium above cost in order to compensate for the firms initial investment in quality. Specifically, a large discounted future flow of profits can then be a better strategy than pocketing the short term gain of reducing quality and losing future customers. Similar to our study, these studies consider forward-looking firms, however they differ from ours in that they do not explicitly model the beliefs of consumers. These authors assume that once a firm cheats (by offering a low quality product at a high price) all consumers cease to purchase from the firm—a type of trigger strategy. More recent studies on reputation such as Board and Meyer-ter Vehn (2010) model quality as function of past investments in quality, implicitly allowing the firm to control consumers’ beliefs via the firm’s persistence in investment decisions. Our model is similar to these studies on firm reputation in the sense that beliefs about quality are modeled as state variables, however, we allow the firm to alter consumer beliefs through price signaling. Adding price signaling to a reputation model can change the model’s implications, which leads us to our second finding. We simulate the impact of an unexpected drop in production costs on the firm’s optimal price and quality. If there is no signaling, then it is optimal for the firm to drop its price, but maintain a high quality. However, under signaling, it may not always be optimal for the firm to reduce its price, as lowering the price may signal a lower quality product. Thus, price signaling can induce downward rigidity in prices. This type of downward rigidity would be less likely to occur in a model without signaling but with other types of reputation signals, such as branding.

2

2

Model

This section develops a model of consumer learning and price signaling where a monopolist chooses a price and quality level every period. We assume that quality, xt , can take on one of two values {xL , xH }, where xH > xL and that the firm can only choose a discrete number of prices: pt ∈ {p1 , ..., pK }. Consumers correctly believe that the joint distribution of pt and xt are discrete, and update those beliefs using a multinomial-dirichlet Bayesian updating process.

2.1

Demand

We assume there exists a continuous measure of consumers indexed by i, each with taste for quality vi ∼ U [0, v] and endowed with wealth wi ∼ U [0, w]. Under an additively linear direct utility function, it follows that consumer i’s indirect utility upon purchase of a product with vertical quality xt and price pt is: Ui = vi xt − pt ,

(1)

The more general case consists of the scenario where the consumer does not know the true quality of the product, xt , and thus must infer the quality based on her information set (that is, her beliefs). We assume that the consumer believes the relationship between price and quality takes the form: P rob(xt = xj , pt = pk ) = µjk ,

(2)

where j, k ∈ {H, L}. Therefore, upon observing the good’s price, pt , the consumer forms an expectation of its quality based on the conditional probability:  k

E[xt |pt = p ] =

µHk µHk + µLk



 H

x +

µLk µHk + µLk

 xL .

(3)

where µHk + µLk is the probability of observing price pk . Consumers’ beliefs about the unknown parameters, µjk , are modeled as Dirichlet: f (µjk ) = Dir(αHH , αHL , αLH , αLL ), 3

(4)

where αjk > 0. Note that under this assumption, αjk

E [µjk ] = P

j,k∈{H,L}

αjk

and  αjk µjk =P .1 E µHk + µLk α jk j∈{H,L} 

If consumers hypothetically live for an infinite amount of time, they will use all past information of prices and quality over the course of the good’s life to infer α = (αHH , αHL , αLH , αLL ). The information in period t can be summarized in the vector αt = (aHH,t , aHL,t , aLH,t , aLL,t ), where consumers believe that the distribution of α at period t is Dir(αt ). By the end of period t, consumers have observed both price and quality, and will update their beliefs using a multinomial-Dirichlet Bayesian updating process: ( αjk,t+1 =

αjk,t + 1 if xt = xj and pt = pk αjk,t otherwise

(5)

By updating their beliefs each period, consumers learn the relationship between price and quality. One problematic feature of assuming an infinitely lived consumer is that, in the limit, her beliefs about the relationship between price and quality become fixed. That is, α will eventually be learned with zero standard error. In this case, any alteration of the stochastic process of price and quality will not cause beliefs to update.2 To allow for beliefs to continue updating indefinitely, we propose that consumers recall the previous period’s information with error. In our multinomial-Dirichlet Bayesian updating problem, demand for the product will be a function of consumer beliefs about µ

1

jk Because the µjk ’s are Dirichlet, the random variables µHk +µ also follow a Dirichlet distribution Lk (see Null (2008) and citations therein). 2 We have solved and simulated a version of our model with infinitely-lived consumers, and we find that when consumers become sure enough of their beliefs, the firm will charge a high price but lower product quality, and beliefs will update so slowly the firm can maintain a low quality. In the limit, as consumers become completely sure of their beliefs, the firm can keep quality low and price high and consumers will continue to believe that ex-ante quality will be high.

4

quality conditional on price (see Equation (3)). We therefore assume that the consumers keep track of the conditional probabilities of observing xH given pt : P rob(xt = xH |pt = pk , αt ) =

αHk,t =α ˜ k,t . αHk,t + αLk,t

The memory error, which we denote νt , subsequently affects this conditional probability by introducing noise into the consumer’s belief about quality upon observing price. We assume that there are two error terms, νHt and νLt , each corresponding to conditioning on pt = pH or pt = pL , respectively. We assume that the νkt ’s are i.i.d. across time and k, and that they follow a discrete distribution, ( νkt =

ν with probability πν ν with probability 1 − πν

(6)

We further assume that consumers have limited memory in the sense that the consumer’s information set only includes the last Nk observations, where αHk,t + αL,k,t = Nk . In this sense, Nk determines the weight the consumer places on the observed current price in affecting her beliefs about quality. The modified Bayesian updating process in our overlapping generations type model is    α ˜ k,t+1 = l(pt , xt , α ˜ k,t ) =

 

Nk k α ˜ + Nk1+1 + NNk +1 νkt Nk +1 k,t Nk Nk α ˜ + Nk +1 νkt Nk +1 k,t

α ˜ k,t + νkt

if xt = xH and pt = pk if xt = xL and pt = pk otherwise

(7)

The intuition behind this quasi-Bayesian updating formula is as follows. We can interpret the αjk,t ’s as the number of times each quality and price combination has been observed. Consumers have a limited amount of memory, in the sense that they can only remember the past Nk observations for each value of pk . Every period the αjk ’s are perturbed by an error that approximately preserves the average conditional probability α ˜ k,t ; if the firm does not charge pk in period t, then E[˜ αk,t ] = E[˜ αk,t+1 ]. If the firm does k charge p , then an observation must be added to either the high quality or low quality k in this case bin, depending on the value of x that is chosen. The multiplication by NNk +1 keeps the total number of observations for pk fixed at Nk . Note that if the firm chooses 5

to produce the high quality good, for example, consumer beliefs about the probability of a high quality good given pk will increase on average by a factor of Nk1+1 , which is the same as how much the probability would go up under the standard Bayesian updating procedure. Note that the size of Nk will determine how quickly consumer beliefs adjust. If Nk is large, beliefs will adjust slowly in response to new information; if it is small, new information will receive greater weight. Thus, in the limit, there always exists uncertainty about the underlying parameter vector α. In every period, it is only necessary for consumers to track the state variable α ˜ t = (˜ αHt , α ˜ Lt ). It follows from (1) that consumer i will purchase the product if both E(xt |pt , α ˜ t ) − pt > 0 and pt < wi . Hence, the demand curve for each period that the firm faces is: ( D(pt , xt , α ˜ t) =

1−

pt w



1−

pt vE(xt |pt )

 if pt ≤ vE(xt |pt , α ˜ t ) and pt < w

0

otherwise

.

(8)

We define the mapping L : R4 → R2 as follows: α ˜ t+1 = L(xt , pt , α ˜ t ) = (l(xt , pt , αH,t ), l(xt , pt , αL,t ))

(9)

Equation (9) defines the evolution of beliefs in vector form, condition on period t price and quality.

2.2

Firm

A monopolist maximizes profits in a dynamic sense, in that it chooses price and quality keeping in mind how this joint decision alters consumers’ expectation of quality. We assume that the firm’s marginal cost, ct , is a stochastic vector (c0t , c1t , c2t ). Each draw of ct is i.i.d. across time with distribution Fc (·). The stochastic nature of cost can include a multitude of exogenous factors such process innovations, weather disruptions, or factory malfunctions. Let total current period profits be represented as π(pt , xt , α ˜ t , xt−1 , ct ) = D(pt , xt , α ˜ t )[pt −c0t −c1t xt ]−c2t xt −γ1{xt 6= xt−1 }. The cost c0t ≥ 0 reflects the marginal cost of producing a quality 0 product, while c1t ≥ 0 allows for higher quality products to have higher production costs. c2t can be interpreted as a fixed cost of producing a 6

higher quality product, and γ is an adjustment cost. The adjustment cost incorporates the idea that quality is not as easy to change as price: for example, creating a higher or lower quality product may involve retooling production plants. It follows that the firm will choose price and quality to maximize its discounted stream of profits:

max

[pt+i ,xt+i ]∞ i=0

E

"∞ X

# δ i π(pt+i , xt+i , α ˜ t+i , xt+i−1 , ct+i )|α ˜t ,

(10)

i=0

subject to the evolution of the state variable α ˜ t in equation (9). Specifically, the state variable α ˜ t will evolve according to how consumers update their beliefs upon the firm’s choices of price and quality. This can be intuited from writing the firm’s problem in the form of a Bellman equation: Z V (α, ˜ x− ) =

Z max{π(p, x, α, ˜ x− , c) + δ p,x

V (L(p, x, α), ˜ x)dFν (ν) }dFc (c).

(11)

where fε , fν , and fγ are the distributions of the respective shocks and x− represents the previous period’s quality choice. Existence of a fixed point rests on the fact that the per-period profit function is continuous and bounded in α ˜ (see Rust (1996)). The optimal choice of price and quality will come from the solution to the Bellman equation. Policy and value functions can be obtained from iterating Bellman equation at an initial guess. We describe our algorithm for solving for the value and policy functions in more detail in Section 3.1.

3 3.1

Numerical Simulations Simulation Setup and Numerical Methods

We solve for the firm’s optimal policy and value functions using value function iteration combined with policy function iteration (Judd 1998). Because our state variables are continuous, we solve for the value function on a grid of points and interpolate the value 7

function everywhere else using simplical interpolation (Weiser and Zarantonello 1988). Simplical interpolation is a generalization of linear interpolation to multiple dimensions. We describe the simplical interpolation algorithm in the Appendix. The details of the algorithm are as follows. Our problem has two continuous state variables, which are the probabilities people believe the product quality is high conditional on a high or low price, and last period’s quality choice, which directly affects profits through the adjustment cost. First, we split the continuous part of the state space into a finite numbers of grid points, and interpolate the value function in between points. We choose a regular 21 by 21 grid for interpolation. We solve for the value and policy functions at each (˜ αH , α ˜ L ) point on the 21 by 21 grid, for each value of xt−1 ; we index each such state point from i = 1, ..., Ns = 441, and denote each (˜ αH , α ˜ L , xt−1 ) combination as si . The value and policy function iteration then proceeds as follows. Indexing each iteration with n, at n = 1 we begin with a guess that the value function Vn is 0 at all points si . We then solve for the optimal policy function (xn (si , c), pn (si , c)) at each state space point, si , and possible cost draw c: (xn (si , c), pn (si , c)) = arg max{π(p, x, si , c) + δE Vn (L(p, x, si ))}

(12)

x,p

We then solve for the value function that would be obtained if these policies were fixed. Operationally, we iterate on the value function contraction mapping with fixed policy functions until convergence. Denoting a policy iteration by np , we start by setting V1p = Vn and update using the equation Vnpp +1 (si )

h

i

= Ec π(pn (si , c), xn (si , c), si , c) +

δE Vnpp (L(pn (si , c), xn (si , c), si ))

. (13)

We assume that the policy step has converged when maxi=1,Nsj kVnpp +1 (sji )−Vnpp (sji )k < p , where we choose p = 1e − 4. The policy iteration step in Equation (13) converges very quickly. Once the policy step converges, we set Vn = V p , and solve for the optimal policies at step n + 1 using Equation (12). The algorithm converges when maxi=1,Ns kVn+1 (si ) − Vn (si )k < v , where we set v = 1e − 4. We have found that this algorithm converges

8

much more quickly than standard value function iteration, where one would solve for the optimal policy every time one updated the value function.

3.2

Simulation Results Table 1: Simulation Parameters Variable δ v w xL xH c0 c1 c2 pL pH ν ν πν γ

Value 0.95 0.6 1 0.25 2 0.05 0 0.001 0.25 0.5 -0.001 0.001 0.5 0.003

Our parameter values are laid out in Table 1. In this preliminary version of the paper, we assume that costs are constant over time. In this section we solve two specifications of this model: one has Nk = 50 for k = L, H, and the other has Nk = 1000. We first discuss the model solution for Nk = 50. We plot the value function for this model in Figure 1 conditional on x = xL . The value function for x = xH looks very similar, but is higher by a factor of γ. The x and y axes in the figure correspond to values of the state variables α ˜ H and α ˜ L , which are the probabilities that consumers believe the product is 9

high quality conditional on observing pH or pL , respectively. The value function is weakly increasing in both these variables. Moreover, if α ˜ H is high, then the value function is flat in α ˜ L . The reason for this becomes apparent when one looks at the firm policy functions, which are shown in Figure 2. Notice that when α ˜ H is very low, consumers believe that a highly priced product is unlikely to be high quality, while a low priced product is more likely to be high quality. At these points it makes more sense for the firm to charge a low price, rather than a high price. However, when the beliefs about high quality given a high price are high enough, the firm always charges a high price. Hence, the value function at these state space points becomes insensitive to α ˜ L since the low 3 price does not occur. The optimal quality policy for the firm is to choose high quality almost all the time (there appears to be a single state space point where the low quality is chosen). Because of the short consumer memory, Nk = 50, consumer beliefs respond relatively quickly to new information and the firm suffers a decrease in its reputation if it lowers quality. This can also be seen in the simulation of the model, shown in Figure 3. We assume that initial beliefs are α ˜ H1 = 0.75 and α ˜ L1 = 0.25, and simulate the model for 10,000 periods. The firm always chooses the high price, high quality combination, and consumer beliefs about the probability of a high quality product given a high price converge to 1. Note that if we start consumers with beliefs where α ˜ H1 is low enough that the firm first charges a low price, then the firm will always charge a low price. α ˜ Ht will remain fixed at close to its initial value, and α ˜ Lt will rise. As can be seen from Figure 2, the firm continues to charge a low price if α ˜ Lt rises for a given value α ˜ Ht . Equilibrium behavior changes when Nk = 1000. At this setting, consumer beliefs update slowly in response to new information. The value function displays the same shape as for Nk = 50. However, the policy functions change, as can be seen in Figures 4 and 5. The firm pricing policy looks similar to the Nk = 50 case, but the quality policy looks different. If both α ˜ H and α ˜ L are close to zero, consumers believe that the product is low quality no matter what price is chosen. The firm then chooses the low price, high quality combination: it invests in quality and builds its reputation. If consumers believe 3

In unreported results, we have examined the sensitivity of the value functions and policy functions to w and v. For higher values of w relative to v, the policy functions are similar, except the threshold where the firm charges a high price shifts towards the α ˜ Lt axis. An overall increase in income simply shifts out the demand curve and makes the high price more attractice to the firm.

10

2.4 2.2

V

2.0 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.0 1.0

0.8 0.8

0.6

~ α Ht

0.6

0.4

0.4 0.2

0.2

~ α Lt

0.0 0.0

Figure 1: Value function for xt−1 = xL , Nk = 50

11

0.50

2.0

0.45 1.5 0.40

p

x 0.35 1.0 0.30 0.25 1.0

0.5 1.0 1.0

0.8

~ α Ht

0.4 0.2

0.2

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.4

1.0

0.8

0.8

0.6

~ α Ht

~ α Lt

0.0 0.0

0.6

0.4

0.4 0.2

0.2

~ α Lt

0.0 0.0

Figure 2: Policy functions for xt−1 = xL , Nk = 50 the high price means low quality, but the low price means high quality (low α ˜ H and high α ˜ L ), then the firm charges the low price and makes the low quality product. Here the firm is exploiting consumer beliefs, using the low price to signal high quality, but making a low quality product. This is not an optimal strategy in the Nk = 50 because beliefs respond quickly to new information, and the firm’s attempt to exploit consumers would lower its reputation in the near future. However, with Nk = 1000 beliefs update slowly, so the firm can get away with abusing the price signal for some periods. Note that if the firm follows this strategy, α ˜ L will decrease and the firm will eventually go back to making the high quality product. Something similar happens if α ˜ H is close to 1, when consumers are very sure that a high price signals a high quality product. The firm’s optimal strategy is to produce a low quality product, and to charge a high price for it. Again, over time α ˜ H will drop and the firm will move back to producing a high quality product. This optimal policy function leads to a type of cycling behavior in equilibrium, which can be seen in Figure 6. If we start the simulation with initial beliefs where consumers think that the high price implies a high quality product with sufficiently greater prob12

2.5

0.7

2.0

Quality

0.6 0.5

Price

1.5

0.4 0.3 0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

6000

8000

10000

Time

~ α H 0.85

0.15

0.80

0.10

0.75

0.05

~ α L

0.90

0.20

0.95

0.25

1.00

Time

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

0

2000

Time

4000 Time

Figure 3: Simulation Results, Nk = 50

13

ability than the low price, then the firm always charges the high price, pH . It produces the high quality product until α ˜ H gets close to 1, and the firm exploits consumer beliefs for a short period of time by producing the low quality product.4 When consumer beliefs about the firm’s quality fall far enough, it switches back to producing the high quality product. We note that putting in a positive adjustment cost for quality makes the cycling behavior more obvious in equilibrium: without it, the firm increases quality until it is just over the threshold where it should lower quality, and then quality bounces back and forth from period to period between high and low quality. In reality, it would be difficult for a firm to adjust quality that quickly, since that would require changing its factory, etc.5

4

In the Nk = 50 case, beliefs are significantly more responsive to changes in quality, making this type of strategy suboptimal. To show the difference between the two cases we simulated outcomes in the Nk = 50 case assuming that the firm chose the same price and quality in each period that it did in the Nk = 1000 case. In the Nk = 50 case, decreasing quality results in the α ˜ Ht dropping from close to 1 down to almost zero. In contrast, in the Nk = 1000 case, α ˜ Ht only drops to about 0.85. 5 If we start the simulation at beliefs where consumers think a low price is more likely to signal a high quality product than a high price, then the cycling still occurs but the low quality occurs most of the time, rather than the high quality. The firm charges the low price to signal high quality, but makes the low quality product. α ˜ Lt updates downwards, until it becomes optimal for the firm to build up consumer beliefs and to make the high quality product. The firm always charges the low price, except if one starts with both α ˜ H1 and α ˜ L1 being high. Then the initial price is high (and quality is low), but the price drops to low when consumers think a high price signals a low quality product with sufficiently high probability.

14

0.50

2.0

0.45 1.5 0.40

p

x 0.35 1.0 0.30 0.25 1.0

0.5 1.0 1.0

0.8

~ α Ht

0.4 0.2

0.2

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.4

1.0

0.8

0.8

0.6

~ α Ht

~ α Lt

0.6

0.4

0.4 0.2

0.0 0.0

0.2

~ α Lt

0.0 0.0

Figure 4: Policy functions for xt−1 = xL , Nk = 1000

0.50

2.0

0.45 1.5 0.40

p

x 0.35 1.0 0.30 0.25 1.0

0.5 1.0 1.0

0.8

~ α Ht

0.4 0.2

0.2

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.4

1.0

0.8

0.8

0.6

~ α Ht

~ α Lt

0.0 0.0

0.6

0.4

0.4 0.2

0.2 0.0 0.0

Figure 5: Policy functions for xt−1 = xH , Nk = 1000

15

~ α Lt

2.0

0.7

Quality

1.5

0.6

1.0

0.5

Price

0.5

0.4 0.3 0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

6000

8000

10000

Time

0.90 ~ α H 0.85

0.15

0.80

0.10

0.75

0.05

~ α L

0.20

0.95

0.25

1.00

Time

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

0

2000

Time

4000 Time

Figure 6: Simulation Results, Nk = 1000

16

3.3

Simulation of a permanent shock to the marginal cost of production

In this section we investigate the extent to which price signaling may induce price stickiness, in the sense that a high quality firm may not drop its price in response to a surprise cost shock, even though in the full information case dropping the price would be optimal. To do this, we take our model and re-solve it assuming that the marginal cost of production, c0 , is 0 rather than 0.05. If there is no price signaling, it is optimal for the firm to lower its price in response to a cost shock like this. We lay out the optimal prices, costs and profits for the full information case in Table 2. Note that there are no dynamics in this case, as we assume that consumers know product quality upon entering the market. Table 2: Optimal Price and Quality In Response to a Cost Shock, Full Information c0 = 0.05 c0 = 0 Optimal Price 0.5 0.25 Optimal Quality 2 2 Profits 0.129 0.146

To see what happens in the price signaling case, we show in Figure 7 the price and quality policy functions for the Nk = 50 case. Comparing the policy function to Figure 2,6 we can see that the firm will still sometimes charge the high price, but for a slightly smaller number of states than in the previous case. However, if we were to run the simulation in the previous section, we know that after a sufficient number of periods α ˜ Ht would rise to close to 1, while α ˜ Lt would remain fairly low (Figure 3). If c0 dropped unexpectedly at period 10,000, the firm’s optimal policy would be to keep the price high. Lowering the price in response to this cost shock would signal to consumers that the 6

In Figure 7 we condition on xt−1 = xH rather than xt−1 = xL as in Figure 2, because if a surprise cost shock occurs, the firm will be producing the high quality product. However, the pricing policy function for xt−1 = xH at c0 = 0.05 looks almost exactly the same as Figure 2.

17

product’s quality was low. We have also investigated the effect of a cost shock in the Nk = 1000 case. The results are similar to the Nk = 50 case. If α ˜ Ht is sufficiently high, and α ˜ Lt is sufficiently low, the firm will not drop the price in response to a cost shock. The type of quality cycling behavior we found before will still occur even after the cost decrease, because the quality policy function looks similar at the lower cost.

0.50

2.0

0.45 1.5 0.40

p

x 0.35 1.0 0.30 0.25 1.0

0.5 1.0 1.0

0.8

~ α Ht

0.4 0.2

0.2

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.4

1.0

0.8

0.8

0.6

~ α Ht

~ α Lt

0.0 0.0

0.6

0.4

0.4 0.2

0.2

~ α Lt

0.0 0.0

Figure 7: Policy functions for xt−1 = xH , Nk = 50

4

Conclusion

We develop a dynamic model of price signaling and consumer learning, and simulate the optimal strategy of a monopolist that endogenously chooses price and quality under different assumptions about consumer memory and costs. We find that if consumer memory is short and beliefs update quickly, the firm charges the high price and high quality, which is the optimal strategy in the full information case. However, if beliefs update slowly, the firm can exploit consumer beliefs by charging the high price and occasionally lowering product quality. We also look at the impact of a surprise cost shock on pricing and quality. We find that a cost shock which results in a decrease in 18

price in the full information case does not necessarily do this when there is price signaling. If cutting the price of the product would result in consumers inferring the product was low quality with sufficiently high probability, the firm will keep the price high to signal high quality. In this sense, price signaling can induce downward stickiness in prices. In this preliminary version of the paper, we examine a situation where the firm can only select between two prices and two quality values. We are currently investigating two extensions to the model to generalize our findings. First, we will extend the model with discrete prices to allow the firm to choose from more than two prices. We are also investigating a version of the model where prices are continuous, and a consumer’s expected quality conditional on price is linear in price. In this continuous price model, consumers update the coefficients of the linear function using a recursive regression.

19

References Board, S. and M. Meyer-ter Vehn (2010). Reputation for quality. Working paper. Judd, K. L. (1998). Numerical Methods in Economics. London, England: The MIT Press. Judd, K. L. and M. H. Riordan (1994). Price and quality in a new product monopoly. The Review of Economic Studies 61 (4), 773–789. Klein, B. and K. B. Leffler (1981). The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance. Journal of Political Economy 89 (4), 615–641. Null, B. (2008). The nested dirichlet distribution: Properties and applications. Working paper. Rust, J. (1996). Numerical dynamic programming in economics. In K. D. Amman, H. and J. Rust (Eds.), Handbook of Computational Economics. Elsevier, North Holland. Shapiro, C. (1983). Premiums for high quality products as returns to reputations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (4), 659–680. Weiser, A. and S. Zarantonello (1988). A note on piecewise linear and multilinear table interpolation in many dimensions. Mathematics of Computation 50, 189–196. Wolinsky, A. (1983). Prices as signals of product quality prices as signals of product quality. The Review of Economic Studies 50 (4), 647–658.

20

5

Appendix

5.1

Description of the Multilinear Interpolation Algorithm

We apply the algorithm in Weiser and Zarantonello (1988) to interpolate the value function over the 2 dimensional continuous part of the state space. The algorithm proceeds as follows. As we have described earlier, we split the two dimensional unit square into an Ng by Ng regular grid, where Ng = 21. First, given a vector (˜ αH , α ˜ L ), we figure out which grid points contain the vector: we find the integer i such that (i−1)/(Ng −1) ≤ α ˜ H ≤ i/(Ng − 1), and the integer j such that (j − 1)/(Ng − 1) ≤ α ˜ H ≤ j/(Ng − 1). We then scale the square up to a [0, 1] by [0, 1] square, transforming (˜ αH , α ˜ L ) to  (x1 , x2 ) =

    (i − 1) (j − 1) (Ng − 1) α ˜H − , (Ng − 1) α ˜L − . Ng − 1 Ng − 1

We also relabel the save value functions at the vertices of the square as Vn (l, m), where (l, m) ∈ {0, 1} × {0, 1}. We then figure out which simplex of the unit square contains (x1 , x2 ). To do this, we find a permutation of (1, 2), (p(1), p(2)) such that xp(1) ≤ xp(2) . The interpolated value function can then be constructed as a linear combination of Vn (l, m) at the vertices using the following algorithm: 1. Start with s0 = (1, 1) 2. Let Vˆ = Vn (s0 ) 3. Let i = 1 4. Let si = si−1 −ep(i) , where ep(i) is a 2-vector with 1 in position ep(i) and 0 everywhere else. 5. Let Vˆ = Vˆ + (1 − xp(i) )(Vn (si ) − Vn (si−1 )) 6. Increment i by 1 7. If i ≤ 2, go to step 4. Otherwise, return the interpolated value function Vˆ

21

Note that this algorithm can easily be extended to continuous state spaces with N > 2 dimensions. It can also be extended to include nonregular grids. For a nonregular grid, the only change is that we find the grid points containing (˜ αH , α ˜ L ), and scale up the grid points to the unit hypercube.

22

A Dynamic Model of Price Signaling and Consumer ...

A Dynamic Model of Price Signaling and Consumer. Learning∗. Matthew Osborne†and Adam Hale Shapiro‡. March 7, 2012. Preliminary Draft: Please do not cite without the authors' permission. Abstract. We develop a model of consumer learning and price signaling where price and quality are optimally chosen by a ...

480KB Sizes 1 Downloads 444 Views

Recommend Documents

A Dynamic Model of Price Signaling, Consumer ...
Nov 22, 2014 - consumers' beliefs about the product's quality by altering both the price and ... price and quality, accounting for the fact that its choice will affect ...

Consumer search and dynamic price dispersion ... - Wiley Online Library
price dispersion to establish the importance of consumer search. ... period, and thus we expect search to be related to changes in the ranking of firms' prices.

Consumer search and dynamic price dispersion: an application to ...
This article studies the role of imperfect information in explaining price dispersion. We use a new panel data set on the U.S. retail gasoline industry and propose ...

Complex Dynamics in a Simple Model of Signaling ...
Nov 15, 2007 - Each site receives k inputs. • Assign Boolean functions to each ... Dynamics. • All sites evolve according to its own rule. • 3 inputs: left. 3 inputs: ...

Price Signaling and the Strategic Bene ts of Price ...
We show that there is a unique equilibrium outcome passing Cho and. Kreps (1987) ... sign l out the qu lity of the goodF gonsistent with most ppli tionsD we will m inly .... i onomists h ve tr dition lly viewed pri e rigidities s o st les to mutu ll

Consumer Search and Price Competition
Nov 6, 2016 - Keywords : Consumer search; price advertisements; online shopping; Bertrand competition; product differentiation. 1 Introduction. We consider ...

Consumer Search and Price Competition
37Integrate equation (2) by parts and differentiate with respect to w, then h(w) = ∫. ¯v w−z∗ g(w − vi)dF(vi)+. (1 − G(z∗))f(w − z∗). The second term vanishes as z∗ → ¯z. 38If ¯z = ∞, then ∫. ¯v+z∗ w f(w − z∗)dH(w)nâ

“Consumer Search and Price Competition” A ...
Similar to the uniform example, Hi is not globally log-concave, because hi has a up- ward jump at z∗ i , but both Hi and 1 − Hi are log-concave above z∗ i . (3) Gumbel: suppose that Vi and −Zi are standard Gumbel distributions (i.e., Fi(vi) =

A Dynamic Theory of Random Price Discounts
... goods prices at many retailers exhibit a distinct pattern that might seem difficult to square .... Hence, measure zero of high-value buyers pay the sales price.

A Model of Directed Consumer Search
Apr 6, 2017 - the VI Conference on the Economics of Advertising and Marketing (Recanati School of ... E-mail: [email protected]. ... 1Or go through the hassle of ordering them online and returning them in case they don't fit.

Learning and Price Discovery in a Search Model
Aug 12, 2011 - Learning and Price Discovery in a Search Model: ... given the steady-state masses Sw, Dw, then Γw and Dw have the no-introspection property.

Learning and Price Discovery in a Search Model
Aug 12, 2011 - that is, the inflow of buyers who expect to trade equals the outflow of buyers with valuations v who trade. Moreover, as in the proof of Lemma 1,. Dw ∫v,θeVX[0,1] e-DwΦw(β^β(v,θ))/Sw. dΦw (v, θ) = Sw (1 − e-Dw/Sw ). Finally,

A Macroeconomic Model of Price Swings in the ...
Sep 25, 2017 - In the case of the United States, house prices displayed a very rapid appreciation during the period. 2000-06 before collapsing in 2007 and – in the view of many– contributing to the Great. Recession. Even though house prices have

A dynamic causal model for evoked and induced ...
Jul 30, 2011 - changes in spectral activity induced by other sources and exogenous. (e.g., stimulus) ..... of model alternatives, all one can do is “motivate model space carefully” .... The free-energy principle: a unified brain theory? Nat. Rev.

A Quantitative Model of Dynamic Customer ...
5.3 Who Buys ADSL? ... B.4 PSTN to ADSL Transition Sensitivity . ...... When contemplating the issue of computational tractability and speed, itrs interesting ..... seems left(skewed and this is confirmed by a DrAgostino test for skewness, so a ...

A Dynamic Model of Privatization with Endogenous Post-Privatization ...
Aug 21, 2008 - would imply minimal changes in post-privatization firm performance in the ..... G.3 Meanwhile, by entitling G to monitor, government ownership allows ...... “Rent Seeking and Government Ownership of Firms: An Application to ...

Symbolic Model Checking of Signaling Pathways ... - Semantic Scholar
sired temporal logic properties of the HMGB1 model. The. Boolean network modeling and Model Checking provide an alternative way and new insights into the study of the. HMGB1 signaling pathway in pancreatic cancer. Keywords: Model Checking, HMGB1, Sig

Symbolic Model Checking of Signaling Pathways ... - Semantic Scholar
ply Model Checking to the study of a biological system ... of hardware, digital circuits, and software designs. Given .... This is in accord with evidence from cancer.

A Dynamic Spatial Model of Rural-Urban ...
Jun 30, 2014 - The new economic geography models presented in Fujita et al (2001) are also related to our analysis. In their ...... Afghanistan. Bangladesh. Brazil. Chile. China. Dominican Republic. India. Indonesia. Korea, Rep. Malaysia. Mexico. Bhu

A Dynamic Model of Privatization with Endogenous Post-Privatization ...
Aug 21, 2008 - 4Since ownership in this model is defined as cash flow rights, this ..... to privatize the firm at ts or to postpone the privatization until the instant.

A Dynamic Model of Competitive Entry Response
incumbent and an entrant can invest in a new technology, and the entrant can also ... Key words: new product development; defensive strategy, Markov perfect ...

A Model of Dynamic Pricing with Seller Learning
They focus on the problem for individuals selling their own homes, while we study the ..... Therefore, the trade-off between the expected current ...... grid points.

Estimating a Dynamic Discrete Choice Model of Health ...
in the agenda of the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. Reaching .... of dynamic and static models highlights the importance of accounting ...... 15This approach has the advantage that it can be estimated using standard software.